MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
AAEC 3315 Agricultural Price Theory
Advertisements

MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell
Price Discrimination A monopoly engages in price discrimination if it is able to sell otherwise identical units of output at different prices Whether a.
Chapter Twenty-Five Monopoly Behavior. How Should a Monopoly Price? u So far a monopoly has been thought of as a firm which has to sell its product at.
Chapter 12 Managerial Decisions for Firms with Market Power
Managerial Decisions for Firms with Market Power
Course: Microeconomics Text: Varian’s Intermediate Microeconomics.
Chapter 5 & Main Monopoly Chapter 5 & Main Monopoly.
The Firm: Demand and Supply
a market structure in which there is only one seller of a good or service that has no close substitutes and entry to the market is completely blocked.
1 1ReadingsReadings Baye 6 th edition or 7 th edition, Chapter 8 BA 445 Lesson A.8 Competitive Markets.
Market Structure and Equilibrium We will consider the two extreme cases Perfect Competition Monopoly.
Consumption, Production, Welfare B: Monopoly and Oligopoly (partial eq) Univ. Prof. dr. Maarten Janssen University of Vienna Winter semester 2013.
Frank Cowell: Efficiency-Waste EFFICIENCY: WASTE MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell Almost essential Welfare and Efficiency Almost essential.
Part 7 Monopoly Many markets are dominated by a single seller with market power The economic model of “pure monopoly” deals with an idealized case of a.
Perfect Competition & Welfare. Outline Derive aggregate supply function Short and Long run equilibrium Practice problem Consumer and Producer Surplus.
Profit maximization by firms ECO61 Udayan Roy Fall 2008.
Chapter 2: Basic Microeconomic Tools 1 Basic Microeconomic Tools.
Monopoly. Monopoly: Why? u Natural monopoly (increasing returns to scale), e.g. (parts of) utility companies? u Artificial monopoly –a patent; e.g. a.
Perfect Competition & Welfare. Outline Derive aggregate supply function Short and Long run equilibrium Practice problem Consumer and Producer Surplus.
Profit Maximization and the Decision to Supply
slide 1Monopoly MONOPOLY A monopoly is a firm which is the sole producer of a good or service for which there are no close substitutes. The monopolist’s.
The Production Decision of a Monopoly Firm Alternative market structures: perfect competition monopolistic competition oligopoly monopoly.
Market Structures Monopoly. Monopoly  Defining monopoly  Only one seller  Barriers to entry  economies of scale  product differentiation and brand.
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy
Types of Market Structure
The Firm: Optimisation
Michael R. Baye, Managerial Economics and Business Strategy, 3e. ©The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., 1999 Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter.
Chapter 12: Managerial Decisions for Firms with Market Power
Five Sources Of Monopoly
1 Intermediate Microeconomics Monopoly. 2 Pure Monopoly A Monopolized market has only a single seller. Examples? XM radio? Microsoft? Walmart in a small.
Chapter 5 & Main Monopoly Chapter 5 & Main Monopoly.
1 Microeconomics, 2 nd Edition David Besanko and Ronald Braeutigam Chapter 12: Pricing to Capture Surplus Value Prepared by Katharine Rockett © 2006 John.
Frank Cowell: Microeconomics The Firm and the Market MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell Almost essential Firm: Demand and Supply Almost.
Monopoly. Monopoly Opposite of PC Occurs when output of entire industry is produced and sold by a single firm referred to as Monopolist.
CHAPTER 8 Managing in Competitive, Monopolistic, and Monopolistically Competitive Markets McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2014 by The McGraw-Hill Companies,
1 Intermediate Microeconomics Monopoly. 2 Pure Monopoly A Monopolized market has only a single seller. Examples: XM radio? Microsoft? Walmart in a small.
a market structure in which there is only one seller of a good or service that has no close substitutes and entry to the market is completely blocked.
The Production Decisions of Competitive Firms Alternative market structures: perfect competition monopolistic competition oligopoly monopoly.
Perfect Competition Overheads. Market Structure Market structure refers to all characteristics of a market that influence the behavior of buyers and sellers,
Monopoly CHAPTER 12. After studying this chapter you will be able to Explain how monopoly arises and distinguish between single-price monopoly and price-discriminating.
Frank Cowell: Microeconomics Duopoly MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell Almost essential Monopoly Useful, but optional Game Theory: Strategy.
PPA 723: Managerial Economics Lecture 15: Monopoly The Maxwell School, Syracuse University Professor John Yinger.
Frank Cowell: Microeconomics The Firm: Demand and Supply MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell Almost essential Firm: Optimisation Almost.
Frank Cowell: Microeconomics Exercise 3.4 MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell November 2006.
Managerial Decisions for Firms with Market Power BEC Managerial Economics.
Frank Cowell: Duopoly DUOPOLY MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell July Almost essential Monopoly Useful, but optional Game Theory:
Frank Cowell: Microeconomics The Multi-Output Firm MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell Almost essential Firm: Optimisation Useful, but.
Frank Cowell: EC202 Microeconomics Revision Lecture 2 EC202: Microeconomic Principles II Frank Cowell May 2008.
Frank Cowell: Microeconomics Exercise 4.13 MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell November 2006.
slide 1Monopoly MONOPOLY A monopoly is a firm which is the sole producer of a good or service for which there are no close substitutes. The monopolist’s.
Chapter 11 Monopoly.
Chapter 5. REVENUE Revenue curves when price varies with output (downward-sloping demand curve) – –average revenue (AR) – –marginal revenue (MR) – –total.
Chapter 5.4 &6 Monopoly Chapter 5.4 &6 Monopoly. REVENUE Revenue curves when price varies with output (downward-sloping demand curve)
Perfect Competition Overheads. Market Structure Market structure refers to all characteristics of a market that influence the behavior of buyers and sellers,
© 2010 Pearson Education Canada Monopoly ECON103 Microeconomics Cheryl Fu.
Microeconomics I Monopoly Market By Kwame Agyire-Tettey (PhD)
13 MONOPOLY. © 2012 Pearson Education A monopoly is a market:  That produces a good or service for which no close substitute exists  In which there.
Monopoly CCE ECO 211 REMEDIAL. Section3.1 MONOPOLY A monopoly is a type of an imperfect market. It is a market structure in which a single seller is the.
Monopoly.
Five Sources Of Monopoly
PERFECTLY COMPETITIVE MARKET - FIRM’S SUPPLY
ECON 330 Lecture 8 Thursday, October 11.
MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell
Lecture 8-Managerial Decision for firms with Market Power
MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell
Monopoly A monopoly is a single supplier to a market
Presentation transcript:

MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell Prerequisites Almost essential Firm: Demand and Supply Monopoly MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell July 2006

What is monopoly? Consider a simple model of market power One seller, multiple buyers Buyers act as price-takers Seller determines price An artificial construct? What prevents there being other firms in the industry? Or other firms that could potentially replace this firm? Or firms producing very close substitutes? Assume monopoly position is guaranteed by an exogenous factor (the law?) Here we will examine: …monopoly with different types of market power … the relationship with competitive market equilibrium A useful baseline case for more interesting models of the market Begin with an elementary model…

Overview... An elementary extension of profit maximisation Monopoly Simple model An elementary extension of profit maximisation Exploitation Discriminating monopolist Product diversity

A simple price-setting firm Contrast with the price-taking firm: Output price is no longer exogenous We assume a determinate demand curve No other firm’s actions are relevant Profit maximisation is still the objective

Monopoly – model structure We are given the inverse demand function: p = p(q) Gives the (uniform) price that would rule if the monopolist chose to deliver q to the market. For obvious reasons, consider it as the average revenue curve (AR). Total revenue is: p(q)q. Differentiate to get monopolist’s marginal revenue (MR): p(q)+pq(q)q pq() means dp()/dq Clearly, if pq(q) is negative (demand curve is downward sloping), then MR < AR.

Average and marginal revenue AR curve is just the market demand curve... p Total revenue: area in the rectangle underneath Differentiate total revenue to get marginal revenue p(q)q dp(q)q  dq p(q) AR MR q

Monopoly – optimisation problem Introduce the firm’s cost function C(q). Same basic properties as for the competitive firm. From C we derive marginal and average cost: MC: Cq(q). AC: C(q) / q. Given C(q) and total revenue p(q)q profits are: P(q) = p(q)q - C(q) The shape of P is important: We assume it to be differentiable Whether it is concave depends on both C() and p(). Of course P(0) = 0. Firm maximises P(q) subject to q ≥ 0.

Monopoly – solving the problem Problem is “max P(q) s.t. q ≥ 0, where: P(q) = p(q)q - C(q). First- and second-order conditions for interior maximum: Pq (q) = 0. Pqq (q) < 0. Evaluating the FOC: p(q) + pq(q)q - Cq(q) = 0. Rearrange this: p(q) + pq(q)q = Cq(q) “Marginal Revenue = Marginal Cost” This condition gives the solution. From above get optimal output q* . Put q* in p() to get monopolist’s price: p* = p(q* ). Check this diagrammatically…

Monopolist’s optimum p MC AC AR p* MR q q* P AR and MR Marginal and average cost Optimum where MC=MR Monopolist’s optimum price. Monopolist’s profit MC AC p* AR P MR q q*

Monopoly – pricing rule Introduce the elasticity of demand h: h := d(log q) / d(log p) = qpq(q) / p h < 0 First-order condition for an interior maximum p(q) + pq(q)q = Cq(q) …can be rewritten as p(q) [1+1/h] = Cq(q) This gives the monopolist’s pricing rule: p(q) = Cq(q) ——— 1 + 1/h

Monopoly – the role of demand Suppose demand were changed to a + bp(q) a and b are constants. Marginal revenue and demand elasticity are now: MR(q) = bpq(q) q + [a + bp(q) ] h = [a/b+ bp(q) ] / pq(q) Rotate the demand curve around (p*,q* ). db>0 and da =  p(q* ) db < 0. Price at q* remains the same. Marginal revenue at q* increases  dMR(q*) > 0. Abs value of elasticity at q* decreases  d|h| < 0. But what happens to optimal output? Differentiate FOC in the neighbourhood of q*: dMR(q*)db + Pqq dq* = 0 So dq* > 0 if db>0.

Monopoly – analysing the optimum Take the basic pricing rule p(q) = Cq(q) ——— 1 + 1/h Use the definition of demand elasticity p(q) ³ Cq(q) p(q) > Cq(q) if |h| < ∞. “price > marginal cost” Clearly as |h| decreases : output decreases gap between price and marginal cost increases. What happens if h ³ -1?

What is going on? To understand why there may be no solution consider two examples A firm in a competitive market: h = - p(q) =p A monopoly with inelastic demand: h = -½ p(q) = aq-2 Same quadratic cost structure for both: C(q) = c0 + c1q + c2q2 Examine the behaviour of P(q)

Profit in the two examples P in competitive example -200 200 400 600 800 1000 20 40 60 80 100 q P P in monopoly example There’s a discontinuity here Optimum in competitive example No optimum in monopoly example h = - q* h = -½

The result of simple market power There's no supply curve: For competitive firm market price is sufficient to determine output. Here output depends on shape of market demand curve. Price is artificially high: Price is above marginal cost Price/MC gap is larger if demand is inelastic There may be no solution: What if demand is very inelastic?

Overview... increased power for the monopolist? Monopoly Simple model Exploitation Discriminating monopolist Product diversity

Could the firm have more power? Consider how the simple monopolist acts: Chooses a level of output q Market determines the price that can be borne p = p(q) Monopolist sells all units of output at this price p Consumer still makes some gain from the deal Consider the total amount bought as separate units The last unit (at q) is worth exactly p to the consumer Perhaps would pay more than p for previous units (for x < q) What is total gain made by the consumer? This is given by area under the demand curve and above price p Conventionally known as consumer’s surplus q ∫0 p(x) dx  pq Use this to modify the model of monopoly power… Jump to “Consumer Welfare”

The firm with more power Suppose monopolist can charge for the right to purchase Charges a fixed “entry fee” F for customers Only works if it is impossible to resell the good This changes the maximisation problem Profits are now F + pq  C (q) q where F = ∫0 p(x) dx  pq which can be simplified to ∫0 p(x) dx  C (q) Maximising this with respect to q we get the FOC p(q) = C (q) This yields the optimum output…

Monopolist with entry fee Demand curve p Marginal cost Optimum output Price Entry fee Monopolist’s profit MC consumer’s surplus AC Profits include the rectangle and the area trapped between the demand curve and p** P p** q q**

Monopolist with entry fee We have a nice result Familiar FOC Price = marginal cost Same outcome as perfect competition? No, because consumer gets no gain from the trade Firm appropriates all the consumer surplus through entry fee

Overview... Monopolist working in many markets Monopoly Simple model Exploitation Discriminating monopolist Product diversity

Multiple markets Monopolist sells same product in more than one market An alternative model of increased power Perhaps can discriminate between the markets Can the monopolist separate the markets? Charge different prices to customers in different markets In the limit can see this as similar to previous case… …if each “market” consists of just one customer Essentials emerge in two-market case For convenience use a simplified linear model: Begin by reviewing equilibrium in each market in isolation Then combine model…. …how is output determined…? …and allocated between the markets

Monopolist: market 1 (only) AR and MR p Marginal and average cost Optimum where MC=MR Monopolist’s optimum price. p* Monopolist’s profit MC P AC AR MR q q*

Monopolist: market 2 (only) AR and MR p Marginal and average cost Optimum where MC=MR Monopolist’s optimum price. Monopolist’s profit MC p* P AC AR MR q q*

Monopoly with separated markets Problem is now “max P(q1, q2) s.t. q1, q2 ≥ 0, where: P(q1, q2) = p1(q1)q1 + p2(q2)q2 - C(q1 + q2). First-order conditions for interior maximum: Pi (q1, q2) = 0, i = 1, 2 p1(q1)q1 +p1q (q1) = Cq(q1 + q2) p2(q2)q2 +p2q (q2) = Cq(q1 + q2) Interpretation: “Market 1 MR = MC overall” “Market 2 MR = MC overall” So output in each market adjusted to equate MR Implication Set price in each market according to what it will bear Price higher in low-elasticity market

Optimum with separated markets Marginal cost p MR1 and MR2 “Horizontal sum” Optimum total output Allocation of output to markets MC MR1 MR2 q q1* q2* q1*+ q2*

Optimum with separated markets Marginal cost p MR1 and MR2 “Horizontal sum” Optimum total output Allocation of output to markets p* Price & profit in market 1 MC P MR1 AR1 q q1*

Optimum with separated markets Marginal cost p MR1 and MR2 “Horizontal sum” Optimum total output Allocation of output to markets Price & profit in market 1 Price & profit in market 2 MC p* AR2 P MR2 q q2*

Multiple markets again We’ve assumed that the monopolist can separate the markets What happens if this power is removed? Retain assumptions about the two markets But now require same price Use the standard monopoly model Trick is to construct combined AR… …and from that the combined MR

Two markets: no separation AR1 and AR2 p “Horizontal sum” Marginal revenue Marginal and average cost Optimum where MC=MR Price and profit p* MC P AC AR MR q q* .

Compare prices and profits Markets 1+2 Separated markets 1, 2 Combined markets 1+2 Higher profits if you can separate… Market 1 Market 2

Overview... Monopolistic competition Monopoly Simple model Exploitation Discriminating monopolist Product diversity

Market power and product diversity Nature of product is a major issue in classic monopoly No close substitutes? Otherwise erode monopoly position Now suppose potentially many firms making substitutes Firms' products differ one from another Each firm is a local monopoly – downward-sloping demand curve New firms can enter with new products Diversity may depend on size of market Like corner shops dotted around the neighbourhood Use standard analysis Start with a single firm – use monopoly paradigm Then consider entry of others, attracted by profit… …process similar to competitive industry

Monopolistic competition: 1 firm For simplicity take linear demand curve (AR) The derived MR curve Marginal and average costs MC AC Optimal output for single firm Price and profits p P1 AR MR q1 output of firm 1

Monopolistic competition: entry qf output of firm 1,..., f AC MC MR p Pf AR P1 p q1 output of firm 1 AR AC MC MR qf output of firm 1,..., f AC MC p Pf MR AR p qN output of firm 1,..., N AC MC MR AR Equilibrium with one local monopoly Other local monopolies set up nearby More local monopolies nearby In the limit Zero Profits Number of local monopolies, N determined by zero-profit condition

What next? All variants reviewed here have a common element… Firm does not have to condition its behaviour on what other firms do… Does not attempt to influence behaviour of other firms Not even of potential entrants Need to introduce strategic interdependence