Chapter 19 The Demand for Money.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
The Demand for Money Theories and Evidence.
Advertisements

Objectives At this point, we know
28 Money, Interest, and Inflation
Chapter 22 The Demand for Money. Copyright © 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved Velocity of Money and Equation of Exchange.
Chapter 22 The Demand for Money.
Copyright © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 13 Money and Financial Markets.
Copyright © 2012 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 10 Monetary Policy and Aggregate Demand.
Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education Canada
The Theory of Aggregate Demand Classical Model. Learning Objectives Understand the role of money in the classical model. Learn the relationship between.
Copyright © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 7 Aggregate Demand, Aggregate Supply, and the Self-Correcting Economy.
1 Monetary Theory and Policy Chapter 30 © 2006 Thomson/South-Western.
Chapter 22. Demand for Money
Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. Chapter 19 The Demand for Money.
© 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Principles of Macroeconomics 9e by Case, Fair and Oster PART III THE CORE OF MACROECONOMIC THEORY.
The Asset Market, Money, and Prices
Chapter 21 The Demand For Money. Copyright © 2001 Addison Wesley Longman TM Quantity Theory of Money Velocity P  Y V = M Equation of Exchange M.
14-1 Money, Interest Rates, and Exchange Rates Chapter 14.
Quantity Theory of Money
THEORY OF MONEY & MONEY DEMAND
Quantity Theory, Inflation, and the Demand for Money
Quantity Theory of Money, Inflation and the Demand for Money
Money Demand. Standard specification: (M/P) = f(Y, r) M = Monetary aggregate P = Price level Y = income r = interest rate  Why money demand?  Why does.
Quantity Theory, Inflation and the Demand for Money
The demand for money How much of their wealth will people choose to hold in the form of money as opposed to other assets, such as stocks or bonds? The.
Chapter 22 The Demand for Money © 2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.
Chapter 22 The Demand for Money.
Ch. 4 DEMAND FOR MONEY Dr. Mohammed Alwosabi.
TM 14-1 Copyright © 1998 Addison Wesley Longman, Inc. Motives for Holding Money Transaction.
CHAPTER 4 © 2006 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Macroeconomics, 4/e Olivier Blanchard Financial Markets Prepared by: Fernando Quijano and Yvonn Quijano.
1 Quantity Theory of Money Velocity P  Y V = M Equation of Exchange M  V = P  Y Quantity Theory of Money 1. Irving Fisher’s view: V is fairly constant.
1 International Finance Chapter 15 Money, Interest Rates, and Exchange Rates.
Chapter 4 Money and Inflation
Copyright © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 19 The Demand for Money.
Chapter 21 The Demand For Money. Copyright © 2002 Pearson Education Canada Inc Quantity Theory of Money Velocity P  Y V = M Equation of Exchange.
When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T Explain what determines the demand for money and.
Chapter 22 Quantity Theory, Inflation and the Demand for Money
Chapter 19 The Demand for Real Money Balances and Market Equilibrium ©2000 South-Western College Publishing.
Chapter 14 Supplementary Notes. What is Money? Medium of Exchange –A generally accepted means of payment A Unit of Account –A widely recognized measure.
Copyright © 2006 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved Preview What is money? Control of the supply of money The demand for money A model of.
Copyright © 2002 Pearson Education, Inc. Slide 23-1 Money and the Economy The Demand for Money.
Money, Interest, and Inflation CHAPTER 12 C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to 1 Explain.
Macroeconomics Econ 2301 Dr. Frank Jacobson Coach Stuckey Chapter 11.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western. The Influence of Monetary and Fiscal Policy on Aggregate Demand Many factors influence aggregate demand besides monetary.
1 Chapter 26 Monetary Policy ©2002 South-Western College Publishing Key Concepts Key Concepts Summary Summary Practice Quiz Internet Exercises Internet.
© 2008 Pearson Education Canada21.1 Chapter 21 The Demand for Money.
Of 261 Chapter 28 Money, Interest Rates, and Economic Activity.
Money, Interest Rates, and Exchange Rates. Preview What is money? Control of the supply of money The demand for money A model of real money balances and.
© 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved 9-1 Chapter Outline The FE Line: Equilibrium in the Labor Market The IS Curve: Equilibrium in the Goods.
Chapter 22 Quantity Theory of Money, Inflation, and the Demand for Money.
Copyright  2011 Pearson Canada Inc Chapter 21 The Demand for Money.
Overview of Chapter 19 The Demand for Money
TRANSACTIONS DEMAND PRECAUTIONARY DEMAND SPECULATIVE DEMAND.
Economics of International Finance Prof. M. El-Sakka CBA. Kuwait University Money, Banking, and Financial Markets : Econ. 212 Stephen G. Cecchetti: Chapter.
Chapter 22 Quantity Theory of Money, Inflation, and the Demand for Money.
Fed Tools and Monetary Policy & Aggregate Supply Money and Banking Econ 311 Instructor: Thomas L. Thomas.
When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T Explain what determines the demand for money and.
Money Demand KEYNES’ LIQUIDITY PREFERENCE THEORY.
MONETARY POLICY Lecture 7 MONETARY THEORY: DEMAND FOR MONEY
©2005 South-Western College Publishing
Chapter 20 Quantity Theory, Inflation and the Demand for Money
Chapter 19 Quantity Theory, Inflation and the Demand for Money
Chapter 22 Quantity Theory, Inflation and the Demand for Money
Chapter 20 Money Growth, Money Demand, and Modern Monetary Policy
Chapter 19 The Demand for Money.
Chapter 22 The Demand for Money.
Demand, Supply, and Equilibrium in the Money Market
Chapter 22 The Demand for Money © 2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.
Money and Banking Lecture 38.
Quantity Theory, Inflation and the Demand for Money
Presentation transcript:

Chapter 19 The Demand for Money

Quantity Theory of Money the quantity theory of money is a theory of how the nominal value of aggregate income is determined. Because it also tells us how much money is held for a given amount of income, it is also a theory of the demand for money. Velocity of Money and Equation of Exchange Irving Fisher examined the link between the total quantity of money M (the money supply) and the total amount of spending (P × Y), (aggregate nominal income or nominal GDP.)

Velocity of Money and Equation of Exchange The concept that provides the link between M and (P × Y) is called the velocity of money, the rate of turnover of money; or the average number of times per year that a dollar is spent in buying the total amount of goods and services produced in the economy. Velocity V is defined as total spending (P × Y) divided by the quantity of money M: V = (P × Y) l M (1) e.g., if nominal GDP (P × Y ) = $5 billion and M = $1 billion, velocity is 5, i.e., the average dollar is spent five times in purchasing final goods and services in the economy.

Velocity of Money and Equation of Exchange By multiplying both sides by M, we obtain the equation of exchange, which relates nominal income to M and V (called the equation of exchange): M × V = P × Y (2) The equation of exchange states that the quantity of money multiplied by its velocity must be equal to nominal income. Fisher reasoned that velocity is determined by the institutions in an economy that affect the way individuals conduct transactions. If people use less cash (credit cards) to pay for their purchases V increases.

Velocity of Money and Equation of Exchange But if they pay using cash or checks, velocity decreases. Fisher took the view that the institutional and technological features of the economy would affect velocity only slowly over time, so velocity would normally be reasonably constant in the short run.

Quantity Theory Quantity Theory of money Because V is constant in the short run, the equation of exchange states that nominal income is determined solely by movements in M. When M doubles, M × V doubles and so must P × Y, Classical economists (including Fisher) thought that wages and prices were completely flexible, they believed that the level of aggregate output Y produced in the economy during normal times would remain at the full-employment level, so Y in the equation of exchange could also be treated as reasonably constant in the short run.

Quantity Theory The quantity theory of money then implies that if M doubles, P must also double in the short run, because V and Y are constant. For the classical economists, movements in the price level result solely from changes in the quantity of money.

Quantity Theory of Money Demand Because the quantity theory of money tells us how much money is held for a given amount of aggregate income, it is in fact a theory of the demand for money. dividing both sides of the equation of exchange by V, thus rewriting it as: M = (1/V) × PY Using k to represent the quantity 1/V (a constant, because V is a constant), we can rewrite the equation as: Md = k × PY (3)

Quantity Theory of Money Demand Equation 3 tells us that because k is a constant, the level of transactions generated by a fixed level of nominal income PY determines the quantity of money Md that people demand. Therefore, Fisher’s quantity theory of money suggests that the demand for money is purely a function of income, and interest rates have no effect on the demand for money.

Quantity Theory of Money Demand The demand for money is determined (1) by the level of transactions generated by the level of nominal income PY and (2) by the institutions in the economy that affect the way people conduct transactions and thus determine velocity and hence k.

Keynes’s Liquidity Preference Theory In his theory, the liquidity preference theory Keynes asked the question: Why do individuals hold money? He postulated that there are three motives behind the demand for money: the transactions motive, the precautionary motive, and the speculative motive. Transactions Motive Primarily determined by the level of people’s transactions, which is proportional to income, like the classical economists, he took the transactions component of the demand for money to be proportional to income

Keynes’s Liquidity Preference Theory Precautionary Motive people hold money as a cushion against an unexpected need, e.g., shop sales, an unexpected bill, say for car repair or hospitalization. Keynes believed that the amount of precautionary money balances people want to hold is determined primarily by the level of transactions that they expect to make in the future and that these transactions are proportional to income

Keynes’s Liquidity Preference Theory Speculative Motive Keynes took the view that money is a store of wealth and called this reason for holding money the speculative motive. Keynes looked more carefully at the factors that influence the decisions regarding how much money to hold as a store of wealth, especially interest rates Keynes divided the assets that can be used to store wealth into two categories: money and bonds. Keynes assumed that the expected return on money was zero.

Keynes’s Liquidity Preference Theory For bonds, there are two components of the expected return: the interest payment and the expected rate of capital gains. Keynes assumed that individuals believe that interest rates gravitate to some normal value (an assumption less plausible in today’s world). If interest rates are below this normal value, individuals expect the interest rate on bonds to rise in the future and so expect to suffer capital losses on them. As a result, individuals will be more likely to hold their wealth as money rather than bonds, and the demand for money will be high.

Keynes’s Liquidity Preference Theory when interest rates are above the normal value, people will expect interest rates to fall, bond prices to rise, and capital gains to be realized. At higher interest rates, they are more likely to expect the return from holding a bond to be positive, thus exceeding the expected return from holding money. They will be more likely to hold bonds than money, and the demand for money will be quite low. Conclusion: as interest rates rise, the demand for money falls, and therefore money demand is negatively related to the level of interest rates.

Keynes’s Liquidity Preference Theory Putting the Three Motives Together The demand for real money balances is related to real income Y and to interest rates i. - + Md/P= f ( i,Y ) the demand for real money balances is negatively related to the interest rate i, positively related to real income Y. Is Velocity constant? Keynes’s theory of the demand for money implies that velocity is not constant, but instead fluctuates with movements in interest rates.

Keynes’s Liquidity Preference Theory Rewrite the liquidity preference equation - + P/Md=1/f (i, Y) Multiplying both sides of this equation by Y and recognizing that Md can be replaced by M because they must be equal in money market equilibrium, we solve for velocity: V=PY/M=Ylf (i, Y) when i goes up, f (i,Y) declines, and V rises. A rise in interest rates encourages people to hold lower real money balances for a given level of income; therefore V must be higher.

Keynes’s Liquidity Preference Theory The opposite is expected when interest rate goes down. Keynes rejected the view that velocity could be treated as a constant.

Further Developments in the Keynesian Approach Transactions Demand William Baumol and James Tobin independently developed similar demand for money models, which demonstrated that even money balances held for transactions purposes are sensitive to the level of interest rates. They considered a hypothetical individual who receives a payment once a period and spends it over the course of this period, as shown in the following graph.

FIGURE 2 Cash Balances in the Baumol-Tobin Model

Keynes’s Liquidity Preference Theory The conclusion of the Baumol-Tobin analysis may be stated as follows: As interest rates increase, the amount of cash held for transactions purposes will decline, which in turn means that velocity will increase as interest rates increase. Put another way, the transactions component of the demand for money is negatively related to the level of interest rates, i.e., the transactions demand for money, and not just the speculative demand, will be sensitive to interest rates.

Quantity Theory of Money Demand Precautionary Demand As interest rates rise, the opportunity cost of holding precautionary balances rises, and so the holdings of these money balances fall. We then have a result similar to the one found for the Baumol-Tobin analysis. The precautionary demand for money is negatively related to interest rates.

Friedman’s Modern Quantity Theory of Money Instead of analyzing the specific motives for holding money, as Keynes did, Friedman simply stated that the demand for money must be influenced by the same factors that influence the demand for any asset. Friedman then applied the theory of asset demand to money. The theory of asset demand indicates that the demand for money should be a function of the resources available to individuals (their wealth) and the expected returns on other assets relative to the expected return on money.

Friedman’s Modern Quantity Theory of Money Friedman expressed his formulation of the demand for money as follows: + - - - Md/P= f (Yp , rb - rm, re - rm, πe - rm) where Md/P = demand for real money balances Yp = Friedman’s measure of wealth, known as permanent income Rm = expected return on money rb = expected return on bonds re = expected return on equity (common stocks) πe = expected inflation rate

Friedman’s Modern Quantity Theory of Money money demand is positively related to Friedman’s wealth concept, permanent income, which has much smaller short-run fluctuations. Friedman categorized other assets into three: bonds, equity, and goods. The incentives for holding these assets rather than money are represented by the expected return on each of these assets relative to the expected return on money. As each relative return rises, the demand for money will fall

Friedman’s Modern Quantity Theory of Money Distinguishing Between the Friedman and Keynesian Theories. Friedman recognized more than one interest rate in his demand for money function, Keynes, lumped financial assets other than money into one bonds because he felt that their returns generally move together. Friedman viewed money and goods as substitutes; that is, people choose between them when deciding how much money to hold. Friedman did not take the expected return on money to be a constant, as Keynes did.

Friedman’s Modern Quantity Theory of Money Unlike Keynes’s theory, which indicates that interest rates are an important determinant of the demand for money, Friedman’s theory suggests that changes in interest rates should have little effect on the demand for money, such that his money demand equation can be approximated by: Md/p = f(Yp) Friedman stressed the stability of the demand for money function and suggested that random fluctuations in the demand for money are small and that the demand for money can be predicted accurately by the money demand function.

Friedman’s Modern Quantity Theory of Money Velocity is highly predictable. We can see this by writing down the velocity that is implied by the money demand equation: V = Y/f (Yp ) If we velocity is predictable, a change in the quantity of money will produce a predictable change in aggregate spending. Therefore, Friedman’s theory of money demand is indeed a restatement of the quantity theory, because it leads to the same conclusion about the importance of money to aggregate spending.