Social Insurance: The New Function of Government Chapter 12

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Fall 2008 Version Professor Dan C. Jones FINA 4355 Class Problem.
Advertisements

Chapter 12 Social Insurance: The New Function of Government
Health Insurance – Part 1 Eric Jacobson. Employer Health Benefits 2004 Annual Survey Kaiser Family Foundation
MACROECONOMICS MACROECONOMICS and the FINANCIAL SYSTEM © 2011 Worth Publishers, all rights reservedPowerPoint® slides by Ron Cronovich N. Gregory Mankiw.
Slides prepared by Thomas Bishop Copyright © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 5 The Standard Trade Model.
Heterogeneity One limitation of the static LS model lies in the heterogeneity assumption. In reality, individuals differ in preference and in information.
10 Externalities.
Important Social Insurance Programs
The Economics of Information. Risk a situation in which there is a probability that an event will occur. People tend to prefer greater certainty and less.
Health Insurance October 19, 2006 Insurance is defined as a means of protecting against risk. Risk is a state in which multiple outcomes are possible and.
Chapter 21 The Theory of Consumer Choice
RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS Chapter 6 The Insurance Solution and Institutions.
317_L17, Feb 13, 2008, J. Schaafsma 1 Review of the Last Lecture began our discussion of the case for public health insurance basic reason => market failure.
Government and Health Care Roughly 15 cents of every dollar spent in US is on health care US health care spending equaled $5841 per person in 2002 Governments.
The Theory of Consumer Choice
317_L15, Feb 8, 2008, J. Schaafsma 1 Review of the Last Lecture began our discussion of why there is a demand for health insurance basic reason => people.
Chapter 9 THE ECONOMICS OF INFORMATION Copyright ©2002 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved. MICROECONOMIC THEORY BASIC.
More Insurance How much insurance We started talking about insurance. Question now is “how much?” Recall that John’s expected utility involves his wealth.
Government and Health Care Roughly 15 cents of every dollar spent in US is on health care US health care spending equaled $5841 per person in 2002 Governments.
Wrapping UP Insurance Let’s Review Moral Hazard With health insurance, the amount of expenditures may depend on whether you have insurance. Suppose that.
EC 355 International Economics and Finance
1 Chapter 9 Knowledge and Information In this chapter we want to see what happens in a market when the amount of information participants have is different.
Basic Tools of Finance Finance is the field that studies how people make decisions regarding the allocation of resources over time and the handling of.
Taxes, Social Insurance, and Income Distribution <Review Slides>
Health Care; Information Today: More topics to help you think like an economist.
Chapter 6: Health Insurance Chapter 6 Health Insurance Copyright © 2009 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
Chapter 9 Labor Economics. Copyright © 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.9-2 Learning Objectives Determine why the demand curve for labor.
Unemployment Insurance, Disability Insurance, and Workers’ Compensation Chapter 14 Unemployment insurance, workers’ compensation, and disability insurance.
THE HEALTH CARE MARKET Chapter 9.
Introduction to Economics: Social Issues and Economic Thinking Wendy A. Stock PowerPoint Prepared by Z. Pan CHAPTER 21 THE ECONOMICS OF HEALTH CARE Copyright.
Assumptions for discussion on this topic In our class on National Income we saw that output Y = C + I + G + NX We shall ignore NX. This means we are assuming.
© 2005 Worth Publishers Slide 12-1 CHAPTER 12 Factor Markets and the Distribution of Income PowerPoint® Slides by Can Erbil and Gustavo Indart © 2005 Worth.
Money and Banking Lecture 02.
Asymmetric Information
Introduction to the Financial System. In this section, you will learn:  about securities, such as stocks and bonds  the economic functions of financial.
Chapter 1 Why Study Public Finance?
Chapter 5: Market Failure: A Role for Government
Health Care Reform in America Facing Up:. President Obama and Healthcare Reform “Health care reform is no longer just a moral imperative, it’s a fiscal.
Insurance. Standard: Protecting and Insuring People make choices to protect themselves from the financial risk of lost income, assets, health, or identity.
Supply and Demand Chapter 3 Copyright © 2011 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
11.1 Ch. 11 General Equilibrium and the Efficiency of Perfect Competition.
Health Economics Unit Definition of Economics  Demand − relationship between quantities and prices that addresses how much bought at each price.
CHAPTER 21 Taxes, Social Insurance, and Income Distribution.
Important Social Insurance Programs Social Security Unemployment insurance Disability Insurance Workers Compensation Medicare.
Chapter 3 Arbitrage and Financial Decision Making
The Economic Effects of Social Security October 10-12, 2005.
Chapter 5 Compensating Wage Differentials Copyright © 2010 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
QR 24 Economics Review Session 12/3/2009. Agenda Demand curves Supply curves Equilibrium Market failures – Moral hazard – Adverse selection Net Present.
Ch. 11 General Equilibrium and the Efficiency of Perfect Competition
© 2007 Thomson South-Western. The Theory of Consumer Choice The theory of consumer choice addresses the following questions: –Do all demand curves slope.
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Third Edition Copyright © 2010 Worth Publishers 1 of 27 Unemployment Insurance, Disability Insurance,
The Theory of Consumer Choice Chapter 21 Copyright © 2001 by Harcourt, Inc. All rights reserved. Requests for permission to make copies of any part of.
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Third Edition Copyright © 2010 Worth Publishers 1 of 24 Copyright © 2010 Worth Publishers.
5-1 Economics: Theory Through Applications. 5-2 This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution-Noncommercial-Share Alike 3.0 Unported License.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2004 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Chapter 2 Objective and Risk Management.
Adverse Selection. What Is Adverse Selection Adverse selection in health insurance exists when you know more about your likely use of health services.
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Third Edition Copyright © 2010 Worth Publishers 1 of 29 Copyright © 2010 Worth Publishers.
WHAT ROLE DOES THE GOVERNMENT PLAY???. WHAT DOES THE GOVERNMENT PROVIDE FOR IN A MARKET ECONOMY? The government provides goods and services such as military.
Chapter 6 Personal Risk Management. Slide 2 What Is Risk? 6-1 Risk Assessment and Strategies Risk is the chance of injury, damage, or economic loss. Probability.
The theory of consumer choice Chapter 21 Copyright © 2004 by South-Western,a division of Thomson Learning.
Unemployment Insurance, Disability Insurance, and Workers’ Compensation Chapter 14 Unemployment insurance, workers’ compensation, and disability insurance.
LECTURE VII: SOSIAL INSURANCE
CHAPTER 9 The Health Care Market McGraw-Hill/Irwin
©2016 by McGraw-Hill Education Limited.
Compensating Wage Differentials
Health Care Reform in America
Heterogeneity One limitation of the static LS model lies in the heterogeneity assumption. In reality, individuals differ in preference and in information.
Social Insurance: Social Security
Public Finance: Expenditures and Taxes
Presentation transcript:

Social Insurance: The New Function of Government Chapter 12 12.1 What Is Insurance and Why Do Individuals Value It? 12.2 Why Have Social Insurance? Asymmetric Information and Adverse Selection In the preamble to the United States Constitution, the framers wrote that they were uniting the states in order to “provide for the common defense, promote the general welfare, and secure the blessings of liberty to ourselves and our posterity.” For most of the country’s history “common defense,” was the federal government’s clear spending priority. Since then, the government’s spending priorities shifted dramatically, away from “common defense” and toward promoting “the general welfare.” 12.3 Other Reasons for Government Intervention in Insurance Markets 12.4 Social Insurance Versus Self-Insurance: How Much Consumption Smoothing? 12.5 The Problem with Insurance: Moral Hazard 12.6 Putting It All Together: Optimal Social Insurance 12.7 Conclusion

Important Social Insurance Programs Social Security Unemployment insurance Disability Insurance Workers Compensation Medicare

Common features of Social Insurance programs Contributions are mandatory A measurable, enabling event Benefits are not related to one’s income or assets (not means tested)

Understanding the economics of insurance markets Why individuals value insurance Why insurance markets may fail Adverse selection Moral hazard What tradeoffs in designing social insurance

Key terms Adverse selection—the insured individual knows more about their own risk level than does the insurer Moral hazard---when you insure against adverse events, you can encourage adverse behavior.

Why insurance Insurance premium---paid to insurer In return, insurer promises payment to individual if adverse event happens Examples: Health, car, property, farm crops,

Why do individuals value insurance? Individuals value because of Diminishing marginal utility Ie. They choose 2 years of smooth income over 1 year of high consumption and 1 year of starving --because excessive consumption does not raise utility as much as starvation lowers it. They prefer to smooth out consumption

Why individuals value insurance? When outcomes are uncertain, individuals wish to smooth their consumption over possible states of the world Examples: State1: get hit by a car State2: not getting hit Goal is to make choice today that determines consumption in future for each of these states

Insurance, contd. Consumers smooth by using some of today’s income to insure against adverse outcome tomorrow. Basic insurance theory suggests that individuals will demand full insurance to smooth their consumption across states of the world. Same consumption possible whether accident occurs or not

Expected Utility Model EU = (1-p) U(C0) + pU(C1) Where p stands for the probability of an adverse event C0 and C1 stand for consumption in the good and bad states of the world

Analyzing an individual’s demand for insurance Assume, a 1% chance for and accident with $30,000 of damages Sam can insure some, none, or all of these medical expenses Policy cost: m cents per $1 of coverage A policy pays $b for an accident His premium is $mb Full insurance: m x $30,000 State 0: $mb poorer State 1: $b-$mb richer than if he doesn’t buy insurance

Expected utility model Sam’s desire to buy depends on price of insurance An actuarially fair premium sets the price charged equal to the expected payout $30,000 x .01 = $300 (act. fair prem.)

Expected (Utility) Decision to buy insurance also affected by risk preference Assume a utility function U= √C. C0= 30,000 Without insurance: .99√30,000+.01 √0 =171.5 With actuarially fair insurance: .99√29,700 + .01√29,700 = 172.3 Utility is higher with insurance Partial insurance is lower utility

The expected utility model Table 1 The expected utility model If Sam … And Sam is … Consumption Utility √C Expected utility Doesn’t buy insurance Not hit by a car (D=99%) $30,000 173.2 0.99x173.2 + 0.01x0 = 171.5 Hit by a car (D=1%) Buys full insurance (for $300) $29,700 172.3 0.99x172.3 + 0.01x172.3 = 172.3 Buys partial insurance (for $150) $29,850 172.8 0.99x172.8 + 0.01x121.8 = 172.2 $14,850 121.8

Result implications Even if insurance is expensive, if premium is actuarially fair, individuals will want to insure against adverse events. Implication: The efficient market outcome is full insurance and thus full consumption smoothing

Role of risk aversion Risk aversion: extent to which an individual is willing to bear risk Risk averse individuals have a rapidly diminishing marginal utility of consumption Individuals with any degree of risk aversion will buy insurance priced fairly. If not priced fairly, they will not buy

Why have social insurance? Asymmetric information Insurance markets have information asymmetry between individuals and insurers Individual knows more about their likelihood of an accident than insurer Example: Health: the individual knows more about their health history Insurer is reluctant to sell an actuarially fair policy to a person with “high risk”

Asymmetric Information Ex. 2 groups of 100 people 1st has 5% chance of injury 2nd has .5% chance Table 2---results People have the option of buying insurance and will do so for fair deal Only high risks take policy loses money

Example with Full Information 12 . 2 Why Have Social Insurance? Asymmetric Information and Adverse Selection Example with Full Information Example with Asymmetric Information

Adverse Selection Problem Insurance market fails because of adverse selection: Individuals know more about their risks than insurance company Only those with high chance of adverse outcome, or if premium is a fair deal, buy insurance Adverse selection causes insurance companies to lose money ?should we mandate buying insurance? Example (HIV, pre-existing condition,

Will asymmetric information lead to Market Failure? Not if: Most individuals are fairly risk averse (ie they will buy an actuarially unfair policy) Policy has a risk premium above the actuarially fair price This leads to a pooling equilibrium where people buy insurance even though it is not fairly priced to all individuals Insurance companies can offer separate products at different prices Consumers reveal info on their riskiness Separating equilibrium- for different individuals

Asymmetric information Separating equilibrium leads to a market failure Insurers force low risks to choose between expensive (unfair) full insurance or partial low cost insurance Low risk group do not get full insurance—suboptimal University health policy options

How does government address adverse selection problem? It could: Impose a mandate that everyone buy private insurance ($825 per policy) Offer insurance directly Both options have low risks subsidizing high risks

Other reasons for government intervention Externalities Negative health externalities Administrative costs Economies of scale in administration Redistribution With full information (genetic testing), insurers can identify high risks Fairness of this discrimination? Paternalism Individuals won’t insure unless govt. forces Government failure is refraining from helping

Other ways to smooth consumption Self-insurance (Unemployment ex.) Own savings Labor supply of family Borrowing from friends charity Government Unemployment Insurance crowds out private provision No gain from government action Efficiency costs from raising government rev.

Example: Unemployment Insurance The UI replacement rate is the ratio of unemployment insurance benefits to pre-unemployment earnings. Figure 2a shows some examples of the possible relationship between the UI replacement rate and the drop in consumption when a person becomes unemployed. A larger fall in consumption means less consumption smoothing.

Example: Unemployment Insurance Panel A shows the scenario in which a person has no self-insurance (e.g., no savings, credit cards, or friends who can loan money to her). With no UI, consumption falls by 100%. Each percent of wages replaced by UI benefits reduces the fall in consumption by 1%, shown by the slope equal to 1 in panel A. In this case, UI plays a full consumption smoothing role: there is no crowd-out of self-insurance (because there is no self-insurance). Each $1 of UI goes directly to reducing the decline in consumption from unemployment.

Example: Unemployment Insurance Consider the other extreme, in panel C. A person has full insurance (perhaps private UI or rich parents). With no UI, consumption falls by 0%. Each percent of wages replaced by UI benefits does not reduce the fall in consumption at all, as shown by the slope equal to 0 in panel C. In this case, UI plays no full consumption smoothing role, and plays only a crowd-out role. Each $1 of UI simply means that there is one less dollar of self-insurance.

Example: Unemployment Insurance In a middle-ground case (Panel B), UI plays a partial consumption-smoothing role. It is both smoothing consumption and crowding out the use of self-insurance. Figure 2b summarizes these lessons. The UI consumption smoothing and crowding-out effects depend on the availability of self-insurance.

Lessons for Consumption-Smoothing Role of Social Insurance In summary, the importance of social insurance programs for consumption smoothing depends on: The predictability of the event. The cost of the event. The availability of other forms of consumption smoothing.

THE PROBLEM WITH INSURANCE: MORAL HAZARD When governments intervene in insurance markets, the analysis is complicated by moral hazard, the adverse behavior that is encouraged by insuring against an adverse event.

THE PROBLEM WITH INSURANCE: MORAL HAZARD Consider the Worker’s Compensation program, for example. Clearly, getting injured on the job is the kind of event we want to insure against. It is difficult, however, to determine whether the injury was really on-the-job or not. The insurance payouts include both medical costs of treating the injury, and cash compensation for lost wages. Under these circumstances, being “injured” on the “job” starts to look attractive.

THE PROBLEM WITH INSURANCE: MORAL HAZARD By trying to insure against a legitimate event, the program may actually encourage individuals to fake injury. Nonetheless, moral hazard is an inevitable cost of insurance, either private or social. Because of optimizing behavior, we increase the incidence of bad events simply by insuring against them.

What Determines Moral Hazard? The factors that determine moral hazard include how easy it is to detect whether the adverse event happened and how easy is it to change one’s behavior to establish the adverse event.

Flood Insurance and the Samaritan’s Dilemma  A P P L I C A T I O N Flood Insurance and the Samaritan’s Dilemma When a disaster hits, the government will transfer resources to help those affected. Since individuals know that the government will bail them out if things go badly, they will not take precautions against things going badly. To reduce taxpayer-funded federal expenditures on flood control, the federal government established the National Flood Insurance Program (NFIP) in 1968. Areas with a 1% chance of flooding in any given year are given the option of buying flood insurance through the program. Following Hurricane Katrina, it was revealed that nearly half of the victims did not have flood insurance. The claims from those who did have flood insurance bankrupted the program. Failures of the NFIP have many sources. Among these is that many individuals opt out of paying for insurance. This is a classic example of the Samaritan’s Dilemma: If the government is going to continue to help individuals in disasters, and people are not required by law to buy flood insurance, then why buy it? A solution to this problem would be to mandate the purchase of flood insurance at actuarially fair prices in areas at risk of flooding.

Moral Hazard Is Multidimensional Moral hazard can arise along many dimensions. In examining the effects of social insurance, four types of moral hazard play a particularly important role: Reduced precaution against entering the adverse state. Increased odds of entering the adverse state. Increased expenditure when in the adverse state. Supplier responses to insurance against the adverse state.

PUTTING IT ALL TOGETHER: OPTIMAL SOCIAL INSURANCE There are four basic lessons: First, individuals value insurance and would ideally like to smooth consumption. Second, insurance markets may fail to emerge, primarily because of adverse selection. Third, private consumption smoothing mechanisms may be available; to the extent they are, one must examine new consumption smoothing versus crowding out of existing self-insurance. Fourth, expanding insurance encourages moral hazard.

PUTTING IT ALL TOGETHER: OPTIMAL SOCIAL INSURANCE These lessons have policy implications. First, social insurance should be partial. Full insurance will almost always encourage adverse behavior. Second, social insurance should be more generous for unpredictable, long-term events where there is less room for private consumption smoothing. Third, more moral hazard should lead to less insurance.

Recap of Social Insurance: The New Function of Government What is Insurance and Why Do Individuals Value it? Why Have Social Insurance? Social Insurance versus Self Insurance: How Much Consumption Smoothing The Problem with Insurance: Moral Hazard Putting it All Together: Optimal Social Insurance