Chapter 7 learning objectives

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
The Solow Growth Model (Part Three)
Advertisements

Lecture 4: The Solow Growth Model
mankiw's macroeconomics modules
ECO 402 Fall 2013 Prof. Erdinç Economic Growth The Solow Model.
Copyright © 2002 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. 4-1 CHAPTER 4 The Theory of Economic Growth.
The Solow Growth Model.
Chapter 7 learning objectives
Macroeconomics fifth edition N. Gregory Mankiw PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich CHAPTER SEVEN Economic Growth I macro © 2002 Worth Publishers, all.
Review of the previous lecture The real interest rate adjusts to equate the demand for and supply of goods and services loanable funds A decrease in national.
Intermediate Macroeconomics
In this chapter, we learn:
In this chapter, you will learn:
Chapter 7: Economic Growth. Supply of Goods Production Function: Y = F(K, L) Assume constant returns to scale: zY = F(zK, zL) Express in labor units:
M ACROECONOMICS C H A P T E R © 2008 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved SIXTH EDITION PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich N. G REGORY M ANKIW Economic.
Economic Growth: The Solow Model
The importance of economic growth
M ACROECONOMICS C H A P T E R Unemployment 6. slide 1 CHAPTER 6 Unemployment In this chapter, you will learn… …about the natural rate of unemployment:
Macroeconomics fifth edition N. Gregory Mankiw PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich macro © 2002 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved Topic 5: Economic.
In this chapter, you will learn…
MANKIW'S MACROECONOMICS MODULES
Economic Growth: Malthus and Solow
1 Macroeconomics Lecture 3-4 Economic Growth, Solow Growth Model (Mankiw: Macroeconomics, Chapter 4) Institute of Economic Theories - University of Miskolc.
Economic Growth I: the ‘classics’ Gavin Cameron Lady Margaret Hall
Macroeconomics fifth edition N. Gregory Mankiw PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich macro © 2002 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved Topic 5: Economic.
Macroeconomics fifth edition N. Gregory Mankiw PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich macro © 2002 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved CHAPTER EIGHT Economic.
Macroeconomics & The Global Economy Ace Institute of Management Chapter 7 and 8: Economic Growth I Instructor Sandeep Basnyat
1 Macroeconomics MECN 450 Winter Topic 2: Long Run Growth the Solow Growth Model.
IN THIS CHAPTER, YOU WILL LEARN:
Economic Growth I Economics 331 J. F. O’Connor. "A world where some live in comfort and plenty, while half of the human race lives on less than $2 a day,
Copyright © 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 6 Economic Growth: Malthus and Solow.
Chapter 3 Growth and Accumulation
IN THIS CHAPTER, YOU WILL LEARN:
Copyright © 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Pearson Addison-Wesley Chapter 3 PHYSICAL CAPITAL.
Copyright © 2006 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. 4-1 The Theory of Economic Growth: The Solow Growth Model Reading: DeLong/Olney:
Economic Growth I CHAPTER 7.
ECONOMIC GROWTH Lviv, September Growth in Finland.
In this section, you will learn…
Economic Growth I Chapter Seven.
Economic Growth I: Capital Accumulation and Population Growth
Solow ’ s Model (Modeling economic growth). Solow model I: Constant productivity Assumptions of the model Population grows at rate n L ’ = (1 + n)L Population.
Economic Growth Explain improvements in standards of living (GDP per capital) along time Explain differences across countries learn how our own growth.
M ACROECONOMICS C H A P T E R © 2007 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved SIXTH EDITION PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich N. G REGORY M ANKIW Economic.
MACROECONOMICS © 2014 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved N. Gregory Mankiw PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich Fall 2013 update Economic Growth I:
Ch7: Economic Growth I: Capital Accumulation and Population Growth
Solow’s Growth Model. Solow’s Economic Growth Model ‘The’ representative Neo-Classical Growth Model: foc using on savings and investment. It explains.
Chapter 4 Growth and Policy Item Etc. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Macroeconomics, 10e © 2008 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., All Rights Reserved.
Copyright © 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 6 Economic Growth: Solow Model.
MACROECONOMICS © 2013 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich N. Gregory Mankiw Introduction to Economic Fluctuations.
CHAPTER 7 Economic Growth I slide 0 Econ 101: Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory Larry Hu Lecture 7: Introduction to Economic Growth.
Chapter 3 Growth and Accumulation Item Etc. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Macroeconomics, 10e © 2008 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., All Rights Reserved.
Macroeconomics Chapter 4
Solow’s Growth Model The mainline Classical Theory of Economic Growth.
Slide 0 CHAPTER 7 Economic Growth I Macroeconomics Sixth Edition Chapter 7: Economic Growth I: Capital Accumulation and Population Growth Econ 4020/Chatterjee.
Macroeconomics fifth edition N. Gregory Mankiw PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich macro © 2002 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved CHAPTER EIGHT Economic.
Review of the previous lecture 1.The Solow growth model shows that, in the long run, a country’s standard of living depends positively on its saving rate.
Copyright  2011 McGraw-Hill Australia Pty Ltd PowerPoint slides to accompany Principles of Macroeconomics 3e by Bernanke, Olekalns and Frank 12-1 Chapter.
The lessons of growth theory …can make a positive difference in the lives of hundreds of millions of people. These lessons help us  understand why poor.
National Income & Business Cycles 0 Ohio Wesleyan University Goran Skosples 7. Long-Run Growth.
Macroeconomics fifth edition N. Gregory Mankiw PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich CHAPTER SEVEN Economic Growth I macro © 2002 Worth Publishers, all.
Growth and Policy Chapter #4. Introduction Chapter 3 explained how GDP and GDP growth are determined by the savings rate, rate of population growth, and.
Growth and Accumulation Chapter #3. Introduction Per capita GDP (income per person) increasing over time in industrialized nations, yet stagnant in many.
MACROECONOMICS © 2013 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich N. Gregory Mankiw Economic Growth I: Capital Accumulation.
7. THE SOLOW MODEL Roberto Pasca di Magliano
Ohio Wesleyan University Goran Skosples 7. Long-Run Growth
7. THE SOLOW MODEL OF GROWTH AND TECHNOLOGICAL PROGRESS
Economic Growth I.
Saving, Capital Accumulation, and Output
Economic Growth I: Capital Accumulation and Population Growth
Macroeconomics Exercise 3 (Ch. 8 and 9)
Econ 101: Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory Larry Hu
Presentation transcript:

Economic Growth I Topic 4: (chapter 7) (ch. 7) The first 11 slides contain introductory information to motivate the study of economic growth. Most instructors likely will not test students on the details of this material. Therefore, and because the rest of the chapter is challenging, I encourage you to consider going through the introductory material a bit faster than the remainder of the material. The central equation of the Solow model first appears on slide 24. The textbook does not assign a special name to this equation, but the equation is referred to very often, so giving it a name makes life easier for students and for the instructor. In these slides, therefore, it’s referred to as “the equation of motion for k.” Because this name is not used in the textbook, one could reasonably argue that it should not be used here. If you take this position, please let me know in an email (roncron@unlv.edu). I am doing annual updates to these slides (which will publish in summer 2003 and summer 2004), so I will have the chance to incorporate feedback from users like yourself into the revisions. One final note before we begin: I strongly encourage you to take a look at William Easterly’s brilliant new book The Elusive Quest for Growth (MIT Press, 2001). It has lots of compelling real world examples (some of which I’ve included in the PowerPoint presentation of the two economic growth chapters). It also explains economic theory in ways that students (and college-educated non-econ majors) find easy to grasp. After reading it, I find I do a better job teaching Mankiw’s growth chapters to my students.

Chapter 7 learning objectives Learn the closed economy Solow model See how a country’s standard of living depends on its saving and population growth rates Learn how to use the “Golden Rule” to find the optimal savings rate and capital stock

selected poverty statistics In the poorest one-fifth of all countries, daily caloric intake is 1/3 lower than in the richest fifth the infant mortality rate is 200 per 1000 births, compared to 4 per 1000 births in the richest fifth. … source: The Elusive Quest for Growth, by William Easterly. (MIT Press, 2001)

Income and poverty in the world selected countries, 2000 source: The Elusive Quest for Growth, by William Easterly. (MIT Press, 2001) Again, the point here is this: Learning about economic growth

Huge effects from tiny differences In rich countries like the U.S., if government policies or “shocks” have even a small impact on the long-run growth rate, they will have a huge impact on our standard of living in the long run…

Huge effects from tiny differences percentage increase in standard of living after… annual growth rate of income per capita …25 years …50 years …100 years 2.0% 64.0% 169.2% 624.5% 2.5% 85.4% 243.7% 1,081.4% These calculations show that a one-half point increase in the growth rate has, in the long run, a HUGE impact on the standard of living.

Huge effects from tiny differences If the annual growth rate of U.S. real GDP per capita had been just one-tenth of one percent higher during the 1990s, the U.S. would have generated an additional $449 billion of income during that decade The $449 billion is in “today’s dollars” (i.e. measured in the prices that prevailed in the first quarter of 2002). In case you’re wondering how I did this calculation: Computed actual quarterly growth rate of real income per capita from 1989:4 through 1999:4. Added one-fourth of one-tenth of one percent to each quarter’s actual growth rate. Computed what real income per capita would have been with the new growth rates. Multiplied this hypothetical real income per capita by the population to get hypothetical real GDP. Computed the difference between hypothetical and actual real GDP. Cumulated these differences over the period 1990:1-1999:4. Like the original real GDP data, the cumulative difference was in 1996 dollars. I multiplied this amount by 10%, the amount by which the GDP deflator rose between 1996 and 2002:1, so the final result ($449 billion) is expressed in 2002:1 dollars, which I simply call “today’s dollars.” DATA SOURCE: Real GDP, GDP deflator - Dept of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. Population - Dept of Commerce, Census Bureau. All obtained from “FRED” - the St. Louis Fed’s database, on the web at http://www.stls.frb.org/fred/.

The lessons of growth theory …can make a positive difference in the lives of hundreds of millions of people. These lessons help us understand why poor countries are poor design policies that can help them grow learn how our own growth rate is affected by shocks and our government’s policies

The Solow Model due to Robert Solow, won Nobel Prize for contributions to the study of economic growth a major paradigm: widely used in policy making benchmark against which most recent growth theories are compared looks at the determinants of economic growth and the standard of living in the long run

How Solow model is different from Chapter 3’s model 1. _______________________ investment causes it to grow, depreciation causes it to shrink. 2. _________________________ population growth causes it to grow. 3. The consumption function is simpler. It’s easier for students to learn the Solow model if they see that it’s just an extension of something they already know, the classical model from Chapter 3. So, this slide and the next point out the differences.

How Solow model is different from Chapter 3’s model 4. No G or T (only to simplify presentation; we can still do fiscal policy experiments) 5. Cosmetic differences. The cosmetic differences include things like the notation (lowercase letters for per-worker magnitudes instead of uppercase letters for aggregate magnitudes) and the variables that are measured on the axes of the main graph.

The production function In aggregate terms: Y = F (K, L ) Define: y = _______________ k = _______________ Assume ____________________: zY = F (zK, zL ) for any z > 0 Pick z = 1/L. Then Y/L = F (K/L , 1) y = F (k, 1) y = f(k) where f(k) = F (k, 1) When everything on the slide is showing on the screen, explain to students how to interpret f(k): f(k) is the “per worker production function,” it shows how much output one worker could produce using k units of capital. You might want to point out that this is the same production function we worked with in chapter 3. We’re just expressing it differently.

The production function Output per worker, y Capital per worker, k f(k) 1 MPK =_________ Note: this production function exhibits ________ MPK.

The national income identity Y = C + I (remember, no G ) In “per worker” terms: _________ where c = ____ and i = ____

The consumption function s = the saving rate, ________________________ (s is an exogenous parameter) Note: s is the only lowercase variable that is not equal to its uppercase version divided by L Consumption function: __________ (per worker)

Saving and investment saving (per worker) = y – c = ________ = _____ = ________ = _____ National income identity is y = c + i Rearrange to get: __________ (investment = saving, like in chap. 3!) Using the results above, _____________ The real interest rate r does not appear explicitly in any of the Solow model’s equations. This is to simplify the presentation. You can tell your students that investment still depends on r, which adjusts behind the scenes to keep investment = saving at all times.

Output, consumption, and investment Output per worker, y Capital per worker, k ___ __ k1 __ ___ __

Depreciation  = the rate of depreciation =_________________________ Depreciation per worker, k Capital per worker, k k _ 1

Capital accumulation The basic idea: Investment makes the capital stock bigger, depreciation makes it smaller.

Capital accumulation k = __________ Change in capital stock = investment – depreciation k = __ – __k Since i = sf(k) , this becomes: k = __________

The equation of motion for k k = s f(k) – k the Solow model’s central equation Determines behavior of capital over time… …which, in turn, determines behavior of all of the other endogenous variables because they all depend on k. E.g., income per person: y =________ consump. per person: c =_______

The steady state k = s f(k) – k If investment is just enough to cover depreciation [sf(k) = k ], then capital per worker will remain constant: ___________. This constant value, denoted k*, is called the _______________________.

Moving toward the steady state k = sf(k)  k Investment and depreciation Capital per worker, k k sf(k) k* k

A numerical example Production function (aggregate): To derive the per-worker production function, divide through by L: Then substitute y = Y/L and k = K/L to get

A numerical example, cont. Assume: s = 0.3  = 0.1 initial value of k = 4.0 As each assumption appears on the screen, explain it’s interpretation. I.e., “The economy saves three-tenths of income,” “every year, 10% of the capital stock wears out,” and “suppose the economy starts out with four units of capital for every worker.”

Approaching the Steady State: A Numerical Example Year k y c i k k 1 4.000 2.000 1.400 0.600 0.400 0.200 2 4.200 2.049 1.435 0.615 0.420 0.195 3 4.395 2.096 1.467 0.629 0.440 0.189 4 4.584 2.141 1.499 0.642 0.458 0.184 … 10 5.602 2.367 1.657 0.710 0.560 0.150 25 7.351 2.706 1.894 0.812 0.732 0.080 100 8.962 2.994 2.096 0.898 0.896 0.002  9.000 3.000 2.100 0.900 0.900 0.000

Exercise: solve for the steady state Continue to assume s = 0.3,  = 0.1, and y = k 1/2 Use the equation of motion k = s f(k)  k to solve for the steady-state values of k, y, and c. Suggestion: give your students 3-5 minutes to work on this exercise in pairs. Working alone, a few students might not know to start by setting k = 0. But working in pairs, they are more likely to figure it out. Also, this gives students a little psychological momentum to make it easier for them to start on the end-of-chapter exercises (if you assign them as homework). (If any need a hint, remind them that the steady state is defined by k = 0. A further hint is that they answers they get should be the same as the last row of the big table on the preceding slide, since we are still using all the same parameter values.)

Solution to exercise:

An increase in the saving rate An increase in the saving rate raises investment… …causing the capital stock to grow toward a new steady state: Investment and depreciation k k Next, we see what the model says about the relationship between a country’s saving rate and its standard of living (income per capita) in the long run (or steady state). An earlier slide said that the model’s omission of G and T was only to simplify the presentation. We can still do policy analysis. We know from Chapter 3 that changes in G and/or T affect national saving. In the Solow model as presented here, we can simply change the exogenous saving rate to analyze the impact of fiscal policy changes.

Prediction: Higher s  ______. And since y = f(k) , higher k*  ______ . Thus, the Solow model predicts that countries with higher rates of saving and investment will have higher levels of capital and income per worker in the long run. Of course, the converse is true, as well: a fall in s (caused, for example, by tax cuts or government spending increases) leads ultimately to a lower standard of living. In the static model of Chapter 3, we learned that a fiscal expansion crowds out investment. The Solow model allows us to see the long-run dynamic effects: the fiscal expansion, by reducing the saving rate, reduces investment. If we were initially in a steady state (in which investment just covers depreciation), then the fall in investment will cause capital per worker, labor productivity, and income per capita to fall toward a new, lower steady state. (If we were initially below a steady state, then the fiscal expansion causes capital per worker and productivity to grow more slowly, and reduces their steady-state values.)

International Evidence on Investment Rates and Income per Person Graph to be updated for final version of this PowerPoint presentation.

The Golden Rule: introduction Different values of s lead to different steady states. How do we know which is the “best” steady state? Economic well-being depends on consumption, so the “best” steady state has the highest possible value of consumption per person: c* = (1–s) f(k*) An increase in s : ______________________________________ So, how do we find the s and k* that maximize c* ?

The Golden Rule Capital Stock the Golden Rule level of capital, __________________________ ___________________________. To find it, first express c* in terms of k*: c* = y*  i* = f (k*)  i* = f (k*)  k*

The Golden Rule Capital Stock steady state output and depreciation steady-state capital per worker, k*  k* Then, graph f(k*) and k*, and look for the point where the gap between them is biggest. f(k*) Students sometimes confuse this graph with the other Solow model diagram, as the curves look similar. Be sure to clarify the differences: On this graph, the horizontal axis measures k*, not k. Thus, once we have found k* using the other graph, we plot that k* on this graph to see where the economy’s steady state is in relation to the golden rule capital stock. On this graph, the curve measures f(k*), not sf(k). On the other diagram, the intersection of the two curves determines k*. On this graph, the only thing determined by the intersection of the two curves is the level of capital where c*=0, and we certainly wouldn’t want to be there. There are no dynamics in this graph, as we are in a steady state. In the other graph, the gap between the two curves determines the change in capital.

The Golden Rule Capital Stock c* = f(k*)  k* is biggest where __________________________________________________________:  k* f(k*) If your students have had a semester of calculus, you can show them that deriving the condition MPK =  is straight-forward: The problem is to find the value of k* that maximizes c* = f(k*)  k*. Just take the first derivative of that expression and set equal to zero: f(k*)   = 0 where f(k*) = MPK = slope of production function and  = slope of steady-state investment line. ___=___ steady-state capital per worker, k*

Use calculus to find golden rule We want to maximize: c* = f(k*)  k* From calculus, at the maximum we know the derivative equals zero. Find derivative: dc*/dk*= MPK  Set equal to zero: MPK  = 0 or MPK = 

The transition to the Golden Rule Steady State The economy does NOT have a tendency to move toward the Golden Rule steady state. Achieving the Golden Rule requires that policymakers adjust s. This adjustment leads to a new steady state with higher consumption. But what happens to consumption during the transition to the Golden Rule? Remember: policymakers can affect the national saving rate: - changing G or T affects national saving - holding T constant overall, but changing the structure of the tax system to provide more incentives for private saving (i.e., shifting from income tax to consumption tax in such a way that leaves total revenue unchanged)

Starting with too much capital then increasing c* requires a __________. In the transition to the Golden Rule, consumption is _______ at all points in time. time y c i t0 is the time period in which the saving rate is reduced. It would be helpful if you explained the behavior of each variable before t0, at t0 , and in the transition period (after t0 ). Before t0: in a steady state, where k, y, c, and i are all constant. At t0: The change in the saving rate doesn’t immediately change k, so y doesn’t change immediately. But the fall in s causes a fall in investment [because saving equals investment] and a rise in consumption [because c = (1-s)y, s has fallen but y has not yet changed.]. Note that c = -i, because y = c + i and y has not changed. After t0: In the previous steady state, saving and investment were just enough to cover depreciation. Then saving and investment were reduced, so depreciation is greater than investment, which causes k to fall toward a new, lower steady state value. As k falls and settles on its new, lower steady state value, so will y, c, and i (because each of them is a function of k). Even though c is falling, it doesn’t fall all the way back to its initial value. Policymakers would be happy to make this change, as it produces higher consumption at all points in time (relative to what consumption would have been if the saving rate had not been reduced. t0

Starting with too little capital then increasing c* requires an _______. Future generations enjoy higher consumption, but the current one experiences __________________________. y c Before t0: in a steady state, where k, y, c, and i are all constant. At t0: The increase in s doesn’t immediately change k, so y doesn’t change immediately. But the increase in s causes investment to rise [because higher saving means higher investment] and consumption to fall [because we are saving more of our income, and consuming less of it]. After t0: Now, saving and investment exceed depreciation, so k starts rising toward a new, higher steady state value. The behavior of k causes the same behavior in y, c, and i (qualitatively the same, that is). Ultimately, consumption ends up at a higher steady state level. But initially consumption falls. Therefore, if policymakers value the current generation’s well-being more than that of future generations, they might be reluctant to adjust the saving rate to achieve the Golden Rule. Notice, though, that if they did increase s, an infinite number of future generations would benefit, which makes the sacrifice of the current generation seem more acceptable. i t0 time

Population Growth Assume that the population--and labor force-- grow at rate n. (n is exogenous) EX: Suppose L = 1000 in year 1 and the population is growing at 2%/year (n = 0.02). Then L = n L = 0.02  1000 = 20, so L = 1020 in year 2.

Break-even investment ( + n)k = break-even investment, _______________________________________________________. Break-even investment includes: ___ to replace capital as it wears out ___ to equip new workers with capital (otherwise, k would fall as the existing capital stock would be spread more thinly over a larger population of workers)

The equation of motion for k With population growth, the equation of motion for k is k = ____  _______ actual investment break-even investment Of course, “actual investment” and “break-even investment” here are in “per worker” magnitudes.

The impact of population growth Investment, break-even investment An increase in n causes an ______ in break-even investment, leading to a ________________________. Capital per worker, k

Prediction: Higher n  _________. And since y = f(k) , lower k*  _________ . Thus, the Solow model predicts that countries with higher population growth rates will have lower levels of capital and income per worker in the long run. Of course, the converse is true, as well: a fall in s (caused, for example, by tax cuts or government spending increases) leads ultimately to a lower standard of living. In the static model of Chapter 3, we learned that a fiscal expansion crowds out investment. The Solow model allows us to see the long-run dynamic effects: the fiscal expansion, by reducing the saving rate, reduces investment. If we were initially in a steady state (in which investment just covers depreciation), then the fall in investment will cause capital per worker, labor productivity, and income per capita to fall toward a new, lower steady state. (If we were initially below a steady state, then the fiscal expansion causes capital per worker and productivity to grow more slowly, and reduces their steady-state values.)

International Evidence on Population Growth and Income per Person

The Golden Rule with Population Growth To find the Golden Rule capital stock, we again express c* in terms of k*: c* = y*  i* = f (k* )  _________ c* is maximized when MPK =  + n or equivalently, ___________ In the Golden Rule Steady State, the marginal product of capital __________________________ equals the population growth rate.

Chapter Summary The Solow growth model shows that, in the long run, a country’s standard of living depends positively on its saving rate. negatively on its population growth rate. An increase in the saving rate leads to higher output in the long run faster growth temporarily but not faster steady state growth. Before leaving this chapter, you should emphasize that we have not yet answered an important question: What causes the kind of sustained growth in living standards that we’ve experienced in the U.S. and elsewhere over the very long run? The Solow model as described in Chapter 7 has a steady state in which income per capita remains constant. Chapter 8 addresses this issue by introducing technological progress into the Solow model.

Chapter Summary If the economy has more capital than the Golden Rule level, then reducing saving will increase consumption at all points in time, making all generations better off. If the economy has less capital than the Golden Rule level, then increasing saving will increase consumption for future generations, but reduce consumption for the present generation.