Externalities © Allen C. Goodman 2009 Ideal Market Processes are desirable if … We accept the value judgment that “personal wants of individuals should.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Intermediate Microeconomics
Advertisements

Upcoming in Class Homework #1 Due Today
Chapter 8: Competitive Firms and Markets We learned firms production and cost functions. In this chapter, we study how firms use those information to reach.
PERFECT COMPETITION Economics – Course Companion
Chapter 16. GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM AND MARKET EFFICIENCY McGraw-Hill/IrwinCopyright © 2011 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Chapter.
A P.O. Is a C.E. © 1998, 2007 by Peter Berck. What Is It Good? Sum of surplus and profits allows for policies that make income less evenly distributed.
1 Chapter 14 Practice Quiz Environmental Economics.
Equity, Efficiency and Need
Demystifying Efficiency in the Economics Classroom David A. Anderson Centre College.
Equilibrium, Profits, and Adjustment in a Competitive Market Chapter 8 J. F. O’Connor.
1 Intermediate Microeconomics Equilibrium. 2 Partial Equilibrium We have now derived both the market demand curve (Q d (p)) and market supply curve (Q.
14. Externalities Varian, Chapter 33.
General Equilibrium and Efficiency. General Equilibrium Analysis is the study of the simultaneous determination of prices and quantities in all relevant.
Chapter 14 Equilibrium and Efficiency Copyright © 2014 McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. No reproduction or distribution without the prior written.
Welfare Analysis. Ranking Economic systems  Objective: to find a criteria that allows us to rank different systems or allocations of resources.  This.
Intermediate Microeconomic Theory
Part 3 Markets and Efficiency
Chapter 7 General Equilibrium and Market Efficiency
Perfect Competition & Welfare. Outline Derive aggregate supply function Short and Long run equilibrium Practice problem Consumer and Producer Surplus.
© 2008 Pearson Addison Wesley. All rights reserved Review Perfect Competition Market.
Externalities © Allen C. Goodman 2000 Ideal Market Processes are desirable if … We accept the value judgment that “personal wants of individuals should.
Chapter 10: Perfect competition
1 General Equilibrium APEC 3001 Summer 2006 Readings: Chapter 16.
Chapter 12 © 2006 Thomson Learning/South-Western General Equilibrium and Welfare.
© Allen C. Goodman, 1999 Equity and Need © Allen C. Goodman, 1999.
The Idealized Competitive Model
Perfect Competition & Welfare. Outline Derive aggregate supply function Short and Long run equilibrium Practice problem Consumer and Producer Surplus.
MBA Economics Copenhagen 21 – 24 May Associate Professor Ivar Bredesen Copenhagen 21 – 24 May Associate Professor Ivar Bredesen.
Chapter 12 © 2006 Thomson Learning/South-Western General Equilibrium and Welfare.
Ch. 5: EFFICIENCY AND EQUITY
UNIT II:Firms & Markets Theory of the Firm Profit Maximization Perfect Competition Review 7/15 MIDTERM 7/6.
More on Externalities © Allen C. Goodman 2002 Transportation Consider a roadway of distance d. Services c cars per hour, at speed s. Travel time for.
Chapter 9 Perfect Competition In A Single Market
© 2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc Chapter 13 Competitive General Equilibrium.
Chapter 10 Monopoly. Chapter 102 Review of Perfect Competition P = LMC = LRAC Normal profits or zero economic profits in the long run Large number of.
General Equilibrium and Market Efficiency
1 Externalities. 2 Externalities  Externalities are a market failure (so Government intervention may be advisable).  Externalities imply that there.
Unit II: The Nature and Function of Product Markets
General Equilibrium and the Efficiency of Perfect Competition
UNIT II:Firms & Markets Theory of the Firm Profit Maximization Perfect Competition Review 7/23 MIDTERM 7/14.
PERFECTLY COMPETITIVE MARKETS. MAIN ASSUMPTION OF PERFECT COMPETITION   many small firms (too small to affect the market price)   identical product.
Overview Efficiency Efficiency and competitive markets Efficiency in exchange Efficiency in production.
1 Intermediate Microeconomic Theory Externalities.
Review for Exam 1 Chapters 1 Through 5. Production Possibilities Frontiers and Opportunity Costs Learning Objective 2.1 Production possibilities frontier.
Modeling Market Failure Chapter 3 © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western.
Public Finance: Introduction
Perfect Competition Overheads. Market Structure Market structure refers to all characteristics of a market that influence the behavior of buyers and sellers,
Externalities and Public Policy
Market Efficiency SPHA511, John Ries. Market Economies and Perfect Competition Prices are determined by supply and demand Demand represents aggregate.
Chapter 18W McGraw-Hill/IrwinCopyright © 2010 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
Equity and Need © Allen C. Goodman, 2013 Remember the Trade-off Between Efficiency and Equity? They are not the same. We saw this in production. We’ll.
PPA 723: Managerial Economics Lecture 18: Externalities The Maxwell School, Syracuse University Professor John Yinger.
Markets, Maximizers and Efficiency
MICROECONOMICS Chapter 5 Efficiency and Equity
Market Failure Chapter 14 Externalities. Economic Freedom Economic freedom refers to the degree to which private individuals are able to carry out voluntary.
Economics Efficiency/inefficiency 1.  Recall, one role for the government:  Improve efficiency  When markets cannot cope  Other ones: rules, distribution.
Unit II: The Nature and Function of Product Markets.
A P.O. Is a C.E. © 1998 by Peter Berck. What Is It Good? §Sum of surplus and profits allows for policies that make income less evenly distributed. §A.
Perfect Competition Overheads. Market Structure Market structure refers to all characteristics of a market that influence the behavior of buyers and sellers,
Equity and Need © Allen C. Goodman, 2015 Remember the Trade-off Between Efficiency and Equity? They are not the same. We saw this in production. We’ll.
Equity and Need © Allen C. Goodman, 2014 What is equity? Horizontal equity -- Equals should be treated equally. Usually thought of with respect to taxes.
General Equilibrium Analysis
Efficiency and Equity in a Competitive Market
C h a p t e r 3 EXTERNALITIES AND GOVERNMENT POLICY
THE FIRM AND ITS CUSTOMERS: PART 2
WELFARE FOUNDATION OF CBA
Overview Efficiency Efficiency and competitive markets
Chapter 14 Environmental Economics
Chapter 10: Perfect competition
Analysis of Perfectly Competitive Market.
Presentation transcript:

Externalities © Allen C. Goodman 2009

Ideal Market Processes are desirable if … We accept the value judgment that “personal wants of individuals should guide the use of society’s resources.” Three structural characteristics are necessary: –All markets are competitive. –All participants are fully informed. –All valuable assets can be individually owned and managed without violating the competition assumption. If these hold, government’s best role involves determining an income distribution, providing rules of property and exchange and enforcing competition.

Markets If markets behave properly, COST of item equals the PRICE that buyers are willing to pay. Value to consumer = Value to producer With competition, in the short run, the firm produces to where: MC = MR = P Value of resources in production = MR = Value to consumer We can do a little bit of geometry to show this:

Typical Firm Diagram Mkt.Firm Firm qEconomy Q P P* D S MC AC MR

Pareto Efficiency Context of trade. One can’t make oneself better off, without making someone else worse off. We usually do this with an exchange Edgeworth Box. Abner Belinda Abner’s Preferences Belinda’s Preferences

Pareto Efficiency Start at Point A. Is this an Equilibrium? Abner Belinda No, they can trade Belinda can be better off. A So can Abner. B

Pareto Efficiency We can plot similar points, which we recognize as a “contract curve” Abner Belinda And so on. A B

Pareto Efficiency We must recognize that point X is Pareto Optimal. Abner Belinda So is point Y. A B X Y

Utility Possibility Frontier We can plot Abner’s utility against Belinda’s Utility. Why do we draw it this way? Abner’s Utility Belinda’s Utility X Y What if we want a perfectly egalitarian society? Does equal utility mean equal allocations?

So, are markets always great? Externality – A cost or benefit in production or consumption that does NOT accrue to the producer or the consumer of the commodity. No single person can own or manage air or water. Consider a person who wants to heat a house with a wood fire. 1.More wood  more heat. 2.W/ more heat, willingness to pay for additional heat . 3.More wood and more heat  more smoke

Heat and smoke Individual sees price of wood as P 1. Compares price to marginal benefit (demand curve). Individual purchases quantity A of wood. BUT… Heat, smoke $ MC MSC D = WTP P1P1 A Wood  Smoke. Assume that more burning  more smoke. We get MSC curve B

Heat and smoke If we go past B the marginal benefits are: Heat, smoke $ MC MSC D = WTP P1 A Wood  Smoke. Assume that more burning  more smoke. We get MSC curve B Inc. Ben. Inc. Costs If we go past B the marginal costs are:

Heat and smoke If we go past B we get societal losses. Heat, smoke $ MC MSC D = WTP P0P0 P1P1 AB Inc. Ben. Losses This is a NEGATIVE externality. How to remedy? A tax of P 0 – P 1. Called a Pigovian Tax, after, Arthur Pigou early 20 th century economist Arthur Pigou

Tax Heat and smoke Tax of P 0 – P 1. Heat, smoke $ MC MSC D = WTP P0P0 P1P1 AB Inc. Ben. Losses Tax Has nothing (necessarily) to do with cleaning up the air. We must set up a market for a resource that no one specifically owns. Think of it as taking revenues and refunding it back to population. Who gains? Who loses?

A general problem – the Lake Externalities Equations n industrial firms Y i = output P i = price x i units of labor at wage W Production Function Y i = Y i (z i, x i, q), where: z i = waste discharges q = quality of lake L = assimilative capacity of Lake q = Q (z 1, z 2,..., z n, L)

Society’s Objective Societal Objective: Max U =  P i Y i (x i, z i, q) -  W x i - C (L) - [q - Q (z 1, z 2,..., z n, L)] P i is the willingness to pay (related to utility of goods). P i Y i is the amount spent (related to utility of goods). is the valuation of the extra unit of environmental quality. First Order Conditions:  U /  x i = P i Y i xi - W = 0.(a)  U /  z i = P i Y i z i + Q zi = 0(b)  U /  q =  P j Y j q - = 0(c)  U /  L = Q L - C' = 0(d) Public Good

Society’s Objective First Order Conditions:  U /  x i = P i Y i xi - W = 0.(a)  U /  z i = P i Y i z i + Q zi = 0(b)  U /  q =  P j Y j q - = 0(c)  U /  L = Q L - C' = 0(d) For Firm 1: P 1 Y 1 x1 = W P 1 Y 1 z1 = - Q z1 P 1 Y 1 q = Eq'm: P 1 Y 1 z1 = [P 1 Y 1 q ] [- Q z1 ] z1z1 $ P 1 Y 1 z1 [P 1 Y 1 q ] [- Q z1 ] z* 1

Amount Collected Society’s Objective First Order Conditions:  U /  x i = P i Y i xi - W = 0.(a)  U /  z i = P i Y i z i + Q zi = 0(b)  U /  q =  P j Y j q - = 0(c)  U /  L = Q L - C' = 0(d) For Firm 1: P 1 Y 1 x1 = W P 1 Y 1 z1 = - Q z1 P 1 Y 1 q = z1z1 $ P 1 Y 1 z1 [P 1 Y 1 q ] [- Q z1 ] z* 1 For Society: P 1 Y 1 x1 = W P 1 Y 1 z1 = - Q z1  P j Y j q = Optimum: P 1 Y 1 z1 = [P 1 Y 1 q +  2,n P j Y j q ] [- Q z 1 ] > [P 1 Y 1 q ] [- Q z 1 ] z* 1 TAX

So … Societal optimum dictates that each firm produce less than in an autarkical system. Remedy, again, would be a tax. Once again, a situation where ownership is not well-defined and one’s actions affect others.

Coase Theorem The output mix of an economy is identical, irrespective of the assignment of property rights, as long as there are zero transactions costs. Does this mean that we don’t have to do pollution taxes, that the market will take care of things? Some argue that it’s not really a theorem. It does set out the importance of transactions costs. Let’s analyze.

Externalities and the Coase Theorem Production of Y decreases production of X, or F Y < If we maximize U (X, Y) we get:

Planning Optimum If we maximize U (X, Y) we get: If we maximize U (X, Y) w.r.t. L x and K x, we get: Does a market get us there?

Planning optimum  Market Optimum Does a market get us there? If firms maximize conventionally, we get:

So? Society’s optimum Market optimum Since F Y < 0, p Y /p X is too low by that factor. Y is underpriced.

Coase Theorem The output mix of an economy is identical, irrespective of the assignment of property rights, as long as there are zero transactions costs. Suppose that the firm producing Y owns the right to use water for pollution (e.g. waste disposal). For a price q, it will sell these rights to producers of X. Profits for the firm producing X are: Reduced by paying to pollute

Coase Theorem We know that q = -p X F Y α  1 gets to Y; Like the iceberg model

Coase Theorem We know that q = -p X F Y

Change the ownership - X owns We know that q = -p X F Y / 

If  = 1 We are at a Pareto optimum We are at same P O. If  is close to 1 We may be Pareto superior We are not necessarily at same place. Where we are depends on ownership of prop. rights.

Remarks These are efficiency arguments. Clearly, equity depends on who owns the rights. We are looking at one-consumer economy. If firm owners have different utility functions, the price-output mixes may differ depending on who has property rights.

If X holds, Y pays this muchIf Y holds, X pays this much Graphically T = T x + T y q Y’s supply (if Y holds) X’s demand (if Y holds) -p x F Y P y -r/G K = P y -w/G L T*

If X holds, Y pays this muchIf Y holds, X pays this much But, with transactions costs  T = T x + T y q Y’s supply (if Y holds) X’s demand (if Y holds) -p x F Y P y -r/G K = P y -w/G L T* Y gets this much qq X gets this much qq The equilibria are not the same!