Public Choice Chapter 6 (Part 2).

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.
Advertisements

Public Goods and Tax Policy
Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. u 35: Public Goods u 36: Asymmetric Information u 17: Auctions u 33: Law & Economics u 34: Information Technology u.
Fairness and Social Welfare Functions. Deriving the Utility Possibility Frontier (UPF) We begin with the Edgeworth Box that starts with individual 1,and.
1 Public choice Alexander W. Cappelen Econ
Chapter 13 – Taxation and Efficiency
Factor Markets and the Distribution of Income
Consumer Behavior Esa Unggul University Budget Constraints Preferences do not explain all of consumer behavior. Budget constraints also limit an.
How Consumers Make Choices under Income Constraints
1 Intermediate Microeconomics Equilibrium. 2 Partial Equilibrium We have now derived both the market demand curve (Q d (p)) and market supply curve (Q.
1 Chapter 3 – Tools of Normative Analysis Public Finance McGraw-Hill/Irwin © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., All Rights Reserved.
Consumer Equilibrium and Market Demand Chapter 4.
Welfare Analysis. Ranking Economic systems  Objective: to find a criteria that allows us to rank different systems or allocations of resources.  This.
The Theory of Consumer Choice
Consumer Equilibrium and Market Demand Chapter 4.
Consumer Choice From utility to demand. Scarcity and constraints Economics is about making choices.  Everything has an opportunity cost (scarcity): You.
Chapter 16 Public Goods and Public Choice © 2009 South-Western/ Cengage Learning.
Who Wants to be an Economist? Notice: questions in the exam will not have this kind of multiple choice format. The type of exercises in the exam will.
Chapter 20: Consumer Choice
1 Chapter 6 From Demand to Welfare. Main Topics Dissecting the effects of a price change Measuring changes in consumer welfare using demand curves 2.
The Consumer Theory How Consumers Make Choices under Income Constraints.
© 2008 Pearson Addison Wesley. All rights reserved Chapter Five Consumer Welfare and Policy Analysis.
Elasticity Test Those students who have not completed their elasticity test must do so during the period. When completed, please submit with your name.
Chapter 9 Perfect Competition In A Single Market
Harcourt Brace & Company Chapter 7 Consumers, Producers and the Efficiency of Markets.
Unit 16 – General equilibrium analysis and Economic efficiency.
Theme 4 - Public Goods Public Economics.
Supply and Demand Chapter 3 Copyright © 2010 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
ECON 6012 Cost Benefit Analysis Memorial University of Newfoundland
Public Policy Analysis MPA 404 Lecture 16. Previous Lecture  A revision of the concepts of equilibrium.  The short run disequilibrium, and the long.
Externalities and Public Goods
Chapter 5: Market Failure: A Role for Government
Lecture # 2 Review Go over Homework Sets #1 & #2 Consumer Behavior APPLIED ECONOMICS FOR BUSINESS MANAGEMENT.
7 TOPICS FOR FURTHER STUDY. Copyright©2004 South-Western 21 The Theory of Consumer Choice.
The Theory of Consumer Choice
INCOME AND SUBSTITUTION EFFECTS
The Theory of Consumer Choice
Consumer Equilibrium and Market Demand
Chapter 3 Consumer Behavior. Chapter 32©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Introduction How are consumer preferences used to determine demand? How do consumers.
Economics of Crime and its Prevention How Much is too Much?
© 2007 Thomson South-Western. The Theory of Consumer Choice The theory of consumer choice addresses the following questions: –Do all demand curves slope.
Chapter 3 Consumer Behavior. Chapter 3: Consumer BehaviorSlide 2 Topics to be Discussed Consumer Preferences Budget Constraints Consumer Choice Marginal.
Chapter 3 Consumer Behavior. Chapter 3: Consumer BehaviorSlide 2 Topics to be Discussed Consumer Preferences Budget Constraints Consumer Choice Revealed.
Lecture 7 Consumer Behavior Required Text: Frank and Bernanke – Chapter 5.
1 Consumer Choice and Demand CHAPTER 6 © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
Individual & Market Demand Chapter 4. 4 main topics related to Individual & Market Demand 1. Use the Rational Choice model Derive an individual’s demand.
1 Consumer Choice and Demand CHAPTER 6 © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
Demand Analysis Some Questions What is behind a consumer’s demand curve? How do consumers choose from among various consumer “goods”? What determines.
Fundamentals of Microeconomics
Demand.
The Theory of Consumer Choice Chapter 21 Copyright © 2001 by Harcourt, Inc. All rights reserved. Requests for permission to make copies of any part of.
4-1 Economics: Theory Through Applications. 4-2 This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution-Noncommercial-Share Alike 3.0 Unported License.
Lecture 4 Consumer Behavior Recommended Text: Franks and Bernanke - Chapter 5.
Chapter 14 Consumer’s Surplus How to estimate preferences or utility from demand A discrete good with quasilinear utility u(x,y)=v(x)+y where y is money.
Chapter Five The Demand Curve and the Behavior of Consumers.
Lecture by: Jacinto Fabiosa Fall 2005 Consumer Choice.
Slide 1Copyright © 2004 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited Chapter 16 General Equilibrium and Market Efficiency.
Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization Presented by: Kuan Chen.
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc. to accompany Exploring Economics 3rd Edition by Robert L. Sexton Copyright © 2005 Thomson Learning, Inc. Thomson.
 This will explain how consumers allocate their income over many goods.  This looks at individual’s decision making when faced with limited income and.
1 Indifference Curves and Utility Maximization CHAPTER 6 Appendix © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
The theory of consumer choice Chapter 21 Copyright © 2004 by South-Western,a division of Thomson Learning.
06A Appendix Consumer Behavior
AP Microeconomics Review #4
Chapter 5 Theory of Consumer Behavior
The Role of Government Chapter 14
Indifference Curve Analysis
AP Microeconomics Review #4
Presentation transcript:

Public Choice Chapter 6 (Part 2)

Market Failures and Government Intervention How do governments and state bureaucrats actually behave? Efficiency of providing the public goods Government failures leading to an inefficient level of government expenditure

Efficient Provision of Public Goods A trade-off between private and public goods is just like a tradeoff between two private goods The indifference curves for the public goods are also downward-sloping (more of one good must be obtained to compensate for a reduction in the availability of the other good for the consumer to remain indifferent) Indifference curves are also strictly convex to the origin (as more private goods are consumed, the household is willing to give up fewer and fewer units of the public good to obtain successive additional units of the private good) The further away from the origin the indifference curve is located, the higher overall utility it represents

Existence Value An individual may derive satisfaction from the provision of a public good even if he or she himself or herself does not consume the good Examples include charity, contributions for preserving wild nature Some people attribute value just to the fact that something exists: the existence value

Compensating Variation Suppose the household is only consuming the private good: in the space of the private and public goods the price of the public good is infinite so that the budget line is a horizontal line Suppose the government provides a certain amount of public good What is the most the household is willing to pay for the opportunity to consume that amount of public good? The reduction in quantity of the previously consumed private good that leaves the household on the same indifference curve is called compensating variation

Compensating Variation Private good A Initial budget line C CV B Public good

Marginal Willingness to Pay Private good CV Public good

Adding MWTP Curves for Public Goods Re-cap: one individual’s consumption of a public good does not reduce the other person’s ability to consume the public good Therefore, we add MWTP-s for a public good vertically rather than horizontally, to obtain the aggregate MWTP

Aggregate MWTP $ MWTP2 Aggregate MWTP MWTP1 Public good

How Large Should the Provision of the Public Good Be? Re-cap: one individual’s consumption of a public good does not reduce the other person’s ability to consume the public good Therefore, we add MWTP-s for a public good vertically rather than horizontally Suppose the marginal cost curve (MC) of producing an extra unit of a public good is increasing upwards The optimal supply is obtained when the sum of the marginal willingness to pay over all households is equal to the marginal cost of provision Since both households can consume the unit simultaneously, we just add up the households’ marginal willingness to pay for the public good in order to obtain total (aggregate) MWTP

Adding MWTP for Public Goods $ Hshld 2 Aggregate MWTP MWTP household 1 Hshld 1 Public good

Adding up MWTP for Public Goods For a supply less than the equilibrium amount, the sum of the marginal willingness to pay over all households is greater than the marginal cost of producing an extra unit of a public good For levels above the equilibrium amount households are not willing to give up a sufficient amount of consumption of other goods (or their income) to cover the cost of producing the final unit of the public good, so that reduction in supply adds to social welfare

Provision of Public Goods and Pareto Efficiency A pure public good is efficiently supplied when the sum of each individual’s marginal willingness to pay is equal to the marginal cost of supplying the good Pareto efficiency in private markets requires that an individual’s MWTP is equal to the marginal cost (p=MC) The difference arises because public goods can be consumed simultaneously by many individuals

Public Goods Provision and Pareto Efficiency Private goods: MRS1=MRS2=p1/p2=MRT Public goods: MRS1+MRS2=MRT

How can Pareto Efficient Provision of Public Goods can be Attained? Assume the voter is paying a tax price to cover the provision of public goods (the individual’s share of a dollar of government expenditure) With uniform taxation of H individuals the uniform tax price is $1/H The tax paid by the individual is p*z, where z is the amount of the public good In this case the budget constraint for a particular individual is given by y=qx+pz, where qx is price times quantity of the private good, y is income and pz is price times quantity of the public good

Deriving the Demand Curve for Public Goods By varying the tax price for the public good provision we can derive the demand curve for a public good If the public good is normal as opposed to inferior an increase in the voter’s income shifts the demand curve to the northeast Therefore, individuals with different incomes will vote for different levels of public goods (lower income people will vote for a smaller amount of public goods) If taxation is proportional, the tax price is an increasing function of income so that in this case we cannot be sure whether higher incomes will lead to an increase of decrease of the demand for a public good

Deriving the Demand Curve for a Public Good Budget Line with a Smaller Tax Price Budget Line with a Higher Tax Price

Lindahl Equilibrium Assume there are only two individuals in the economy Let those individuals pay for the public goods according to their respective demand curves Obtain equality between the sum of their tax prices and the marginal cost of producing the public good In the Lindahl equilibrium P1+P2=MC, and the two individuals are consuming the same amount of the public good

Lindahl Equilibrium and Pareto Efficiency Lindahl equilibrium is Pareto efficient in the sense that price (i.e. the sum of individual tax prices) is equal to the marginal cost However, because individuals realize their tax prices depend on their willingness to pay for the public goods provision may try to cheat by under- or over-stating their true willingness to pay for the public good This problem may be seen as a special case of the free rider problem illustrated by means of the prisoners’ dilemma In general, it is necessary to reveal individual preferences in order to arrive at Lindahl equilibrium, but it is not clear how to do that

Revealing Preferences for Optimal Taxation In general, it is necessary to reveal individual preferences in order to arrive at Lindahl equilibrium, but it is not clear how to do that In the case of private goods, individuals reveal their preferences in market place In the case of public goods there is no similar market mechanism so we need to reveal preferences Possibilities Ask people about their willingness to pay for public goods Hypothetical payment experiments (contingent valuation methodology) Use some voting mechanism

The Majority Voting Rule Majority voting rule: the alternative (among two alternatives) that receives the majority of votes wins Does the majority voting rule produce a Pareto-efficient allocation? Each level of the public good provision results in different levels of utility so we can plot utility schedules against the various levels of public good provision

Classes of Individuals according to their Most Preferred Level of Public Good Provision Utility The Rich Middle Class The Poor Public Good

The Median Voter The median voter is the one for whom the number of individuals preferring more expenditure is exactly equal to the number of individuals preferring less expenditure In the example before, the median voter’s most preferred level of public good provision gets adopted according to the majority voting rule Under uniform taxation, majority voting results in the Pareto efficient level of public good provision since the median voter prefers an expenditure level such that his MWTP is equal to the marginal costs If taxation is proportional and the median voter’s income is smaller than the average income in the society, his tax price will be small and he will vote for a greater amount of public good compared to the one where price is equal to marginal costs

Majority Voting and Pareto Efficiency Majority-voting can, but need not be Pareto efficient Sometimes majority-voting equilibrium will not exist (remember the Coase theorem discussion)

Why do Voters Vote? With millions of voters in the society, each individual’s impact on the voting outcome is negligible Why do people continue to vote? Interdependent utilities (e.g. some people may care about the poor or clean environment) In democratic societies, children are taught that voting is a duty

Bureaucrats and Voters Bureaucrats seek to maximize the size of their agencies so they choose the level of public good provision that is too high compared to the efficient one Forcing the voters to choose between too little and too much of the public good, the bureaucrats have a good chance of getting the permission to produce too much of the public good (e.g. police force in a criminal city) The economic policy may reflects interests of those in power Size of agricultural sector is way too large in most industrialized powers In short, government intervention into public goods provision does not necessarily move the economy closer to the Pareto efficient allocation