Damages in One (Fairly) Easy Lesson

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Ind – Develop a foundational knowledge of pricing to understand its role in marketing. (Part II) Entrepreneurship I.
Advertisements

Recommended Pre-Suit Case Analysis Likelihood of infringement Likelihood of validity Size of potential recovery Likelihood of injunction and its importance.
Damages Calculations in Infringement Cases Frank S. Farrell F.S. Farrell, LLC 7101 York Ave., So.; Suite 305 Edina, MN Phone: (952) Fax:
PERFECT COMPETITION Economics – Course Companion
Nov. 22, 2005 Jack Ko 1 Awarding Lost Profits for “Unpatented” Products: Rite-Hite and Other Cases By Jack Ko.
Seagate - Willfulness Prof Merges April 22, 2008.
Virtual Patent Marking Joel Lutzker General Counsel March 27, 2013.
The Process of Litigation. What is the first stage in a civil lawsuit ?  Service of Process (the summons)
HOLLOW REMEDIES: INSUFFICIENT RELIEF UNDER THE LANHAM ACT
Chapter 3 Modern Trade Theories
The Legal System and Patent Damages Recent Developments Prof. Amy Landers University of the Pacific/McGeorge School of Law.
Adequate Patent Infringement Damages in Japanese Courts: Comparative Analysis Toshiko Takenaka, Ph.D. Professor of Law; Director, CASRIP University of.
Chapter 9 – Profit maximization
Monopoly A monopoly is a single supplier to a market
© Suzanne Scotchmer 10/14/2004 Contents May Be Used Pursuant to Creative Commons Attribution-NoDerivs-NonCommercial Common Deed 1.0Attribution-NoDerivs-NonCommercial.
Patent Damages II Patent Law United States Patent 4,373,847 Hipp, et al. February 15, 1983 Releasable locking device A releasable locking device.
Damages I Patent Law
Patent Damages – Where We Are, Where We Are Going Federal Circuit Bar Ass’n Prof. Robert Merges.
Limits on Restoring Plaintiff to Rightful Position – Bargaining out of Rightful Position Default rules – rules a court applies to determine how to restore.
Principles of Microeconomics 4 and 5 Elasticity*
Economics: Principles in Action
POST GRADUATE DIPLOMA IN BUSINESS MANAGEMENT November 2013 Lesson 1.
Economics Chapter Supply, Demand, and Elasticity Combined Version
REVENUE THEORY IB Business & Management A Course Companion 2009 THE THEORY OF THE FIRM: COSTS, REVENUES AND PROFITS.
CHAPTER 8: SECTION 1 A Perfectly Competitive Market
Agustin Del Rio CalNet ID: Date: October 27th, 2008.
Monopolistic Competition
Patent Damages and Free Options Jerry Hausman MIT February 15,
IB-SL Economics Mr. Messere - CIA 4U7 Victoria Park S.S.
Civil Law in Action Wednesday 17 August Court hierarchy Review: What are the advantages of having a court hierarchy?
Trademark II Infringement. Article 57 Infringement Article 57 Any of the following conduct shall be an infringement upon the right to exclusively use.
Peter L. Michaelson, Esq. Michaelson and Associates Red Bank, New Jersey US © , P.L. Michaelson All rights reserved M&A -- Case.
Page 1 Patent Damages Brandon Baum James Pistorino March 26, 2015.
C hapter 10 Identifying Markets and Market Structures © 2002 South-Western.
Perfect Competition *MADE BY RACHEL STAND* :). I. Perfect Competition: A Model A. Basic Definitions 1. Perfect Competition: a model of the market based.
1 Patent Law in the Age of IoT The Landscape Has Shifted. Are You Prepared? 1 Jeffrey A. Miller, Esq.
Understanding Demand What is the law of demand?
Costs and Profit Maximization Under Competition
1 PATENT LAW Randy Canis CLASS 13 Additional Defenses/Remedies.
Austin ■ Boston ■ Northern California ■ Washington, D.C. Damages Analysis Innovention Toys, LLC v. MGA Entertainment, Inc. and Wal-Mart Stores, Inc. and.
Types of Cases Government Criminal Case Government Civil Case Private Civil Case W/jury Punishment (jail) Damages (money) Damages (money) W/judge only.
Economies of Scale, Imperfect Competition, and International Trade
Arlington Industies, Inc. v. Bridgeport Fittings, Inc.
. 1 Modeling Patent Damages: Rigorous and Defensible Calculations Roy J. Epstein, PhD American Intellectual Property Law Association.
COPYRIGHT LAW 2003 Professor Fischer CLASS of April THE LAST CLASS!!!
Chapter 10 Monopoly. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 102 Topics to be Discussed Monopoly and Monopoly Power Sources of Monopoly Power The Social.
Judge Sarah S. Vance, Eastern District of Louisiana Establishing Damages Under U.S. Antitrust Law.
1 Getting to “Reasonable” Law Seminars International Standards Bodies and Patent Pools Conference Arlington, Virginia October 2007 Alan Cox Senior Vice.
Patent Cases MM 450 Issues in New Media Theory Steve Baron March 3, 2009.
Patent Remedies Class Notes: April 1, 2003 Law 677 | Patent Law | Spring 2003 Professor Wagner.
Intellectual Property Patent – Infringement. Infringement 1.Literal Infringement 2.The Doctrine of Equivalents 35 U.S.C. § 271 –“(a) Except as otherwise.
Welcome and Thank You © Gordon & Rees LLP Constitutional Foundation Article 1; Section 8 Congress shall have the Power to... Promote the Progress.
© 2007 Sidley Austin LLP, Los Angeles, CA All rights reserved. What is a Civil Case?
1 1 1 AIPLA Firm Logo American Intellectual Property Law Association THE STATUS OF INDUCEMENT Japan Intellectual Property Association Tokyo Joseph A. Calvaruso.
Social Science.  The main purpose of civil law is to settle disagreements fairly  People file lawsuits, or cases in which a court is asked to settle.
Patent Infringement MM450 March 30, What is Patent Infringement? Making, using or selling an invention on which a patent is in force without the.
Class 24: Finish Remedies, then Subject Matter Patent Law Spring 2007 Professor Petherbridge.
EU-China Workshop on the Chinese Patent Law 24/25 September 2008 Topic IV: Legal Consequences of Invalidity of a Patent Prof. Dr. Christian Osterrieth.
ChapterDemand 8 8 Guiding Questions  Section 1: Understanding Demand  How does the law of demand affect the quantity demanded? The law of demand states.
Negligence Tort law establishes standards for the care that people must show to one another. Negligence is the conduct that falls below this standard.
Damages in One (Fairly) Easy Lesson Patent Law Prof. Merges.
Damages in One (Fairly) Easy Lesson Patent Law Prof. Merges.
Enhanced Damages for Patent Infringement: Halo v. Pulse
America Invents Act: Litigation Related Provisions
SolarCity vs. Salt River Project
Patent Damages Pupilage Groups 3 & 4
STRUCTURE OF THE PRESENTATION
Economics: Principles in Action
Pitfalls and privilege in a post-halo World
Presentation by Seung Woo Ben Hur September 2019
Presentation transcript:

Damages in One (Fairly) Easy Lesson Patent Law 4.21.08 Prof. Merges

Relief Prospective Effect Damages assessed for this period if marking Issuance Final injunction issues Complaint filed in District Court Preliminary injunction hearing Damages assessed for this period if marking (or actual notice)

35 U.S.C. § 284 “[T]he court shall award [the patentee] damages adequate to compensate for the infringement but in no event less than a reasonable royalty for the use made of the invention by the infringer.”

35 U.S.C. § 285 “The court in exceptional cases may award reasonable attorney fees to the prevailing party.”

35 U.S.C. § 287(a) Patentees ... making, offering for sale, or selling ... any patented article ... may give notice to the public that the same is patented, either by fixing thereon the word "patent" or the abbreviation "pat.", together with the number of the patent, or when, from the character of the article, this cannot be done, by fixing to it, or to the package wherein one or more of them is contained, a label containing a like notice. In the event of failure to so mark, no damages shall be recovered by the patentee in any action for infringement, except on proof that the infringer was notified of the infringement and continued to infringe thereafter, in which event damages may be recovered only for infringement occurring after such notice. Filing of an action for infringement shall constitute such notice.

Damages Two measures: Actual damages & the problem of proof Actual damages: “Lost Profits” Reasonable royalty Actual damages & the problem of proof Panduit Corp. v. Stahlin Bros. Fibre Works, Inc. – P. 1069

Compensation principle “But for” the defendant’s infringing sales, what would the patentee’s profits have been? NOT a disgorgement remedy: patentee’s loss, NOT infringer’s gain

Holding Below Special Master 2.5% royalty on all sales by defendant Stahlin during the infringement period 3/6/62  8/7/70 Injunction too, of course

Panduit’s damage claim Lost Profits: Stahlin’s sales OR Reasonable Royalty Lost Profits on Panduit’s own sales “Price erosion” profits

Patentee Damages Theory Monopoly price is the inventor’s reward Competition lowers price; measure “harm from competition”

Lost Profits In 2-firm market, where infringer is second firm, may be easy to calculate All sales of infringer would have been made by patentee Always true?

Panduit What does the patentee have to show to prove it would have made sales actually made by infringer?

Panduit What does the patentee have to show to prove it would have made sales actually made by infringer? “Absence of acceptable noninfringing substitutes”

Problem Here Panduit factor 4, not 2 Accounting method inadequate

“DAMP” test “Whether lost profits are legally compensable in a particular situation is a question of law that we review de novo.” Poly-Am., L.P. v. GSE Lining Tech., Inc., 383 F.3d 1303, 1311 (Fed.Cir.2004)

Ability to manufacture “Normally, if the patentee is not selling a product, by definition there can be no lost profits.” Rite-Hite, 56 F.3d at 1548. The only exception is where the patentee has the ability to manufacture and market a product, but for some legitimate reason does not. Even in these situations, though, “the burden on a patentee who has not begun to manufacture the patented product is commensurately heavy.” Hebert v. Lisle Corp., 99 F.3d 1109, 1120 (Fed.Cir.1996).

“[T]he record demonstrates that, despite his later success manufacturing and marketing a product, Wechsler lacked the capability to manufacture his device during the period of infringement.” Wechsler v. Macke Intern. Trade, Inc., 486 F.3d 1286, 1293 (Fed. Cir. 2007)

Reasonable royalty: the fallback Timing Date infringement began Hypothetical bargain procedure – pp. 1072-1073

Reasonable royalty (cont’d) Relevance of competitive situation facing firms Including substitutes In the background: cross-elasticity of demand

Cross-elasticity How much demand would be lost from the patented product for every dollar increase in its price above the “perfect competition” level?

Damages Two approaches to substitution: Patentable = unique, therefore, no substitutes. Antitrust, substitution is a function of cross-elasticity of demand. Therefore, there will usually be substitutes.

Elasticity If price rises by 10% - what happens to demand? We know demand will fall By more than 10%? By less than 10%? Elasticity measures the extent to which demand will change

Elasticity (cont’d) Price Elasticity of Demand The responsiveness of demand to changes in price Where % change in demand is greater than % change in price – elastic Where % change in demand is less than % change in price - inelastic

Elasticity The Formula: % Change in Quantity Demanded ___________________________ PED = % Change in Price If answer is between 0 and -1: the relationship is inelastic If the answer is between -1 and - infinity: the relationship is elastic Note: PED has – sign in front of it; because as price rises demand falls and vice-versa (inverse relationship between price and demand)

Elasticity in this example - 29% / 66% = - .43 NB: If the decision had been to raise the price, the firm would have lost revenue (so “inelastic demand” can still mean net loss in revenue due to price rise)

Elasticity Cross Elasticity: The responsiveness of demand of one good to changes in the price of a related good – either a substitute or a complement % Δ Q of good x __________________ XED = % Δ Price of good y

Cross elasticity - example Increase price of good Y from $1.00 to $1.10 Demand for good X increases from 100 to 120. Cross-elasticity: 20%/10% = + 2.

Elasticity Goods which are complements: Goods which are substitutes: Cross Elasticity will have negative sign (inverse relationship between the two) Hot dogs and mustard Goods which are substitutes: Cross Elasticity will have a positive sign (positive relationship between the two) : e.g., public transit and car sales These are the ones we are usually interested in in patent cases

Cross-elasticity and substitutes Number and closeness of substitutes – the greater the number of substitutes the more elastic the demand for a given product will be

The Fallback – Reasonable Royalties “Hypothetical Bargain” principle When? – Date infringement began Factors Do not reward infringement !! Available noninfringing substitutes? Does infringer get a profit?

Principle/Goal of Patent Damages Doctrine Goal: find "the difference between [patentee’s] pecuniary condition after the infringement, and what his condition would have been if the infringement had not occurred." Yale Lock Mfg. Co. v. Sargent, 117 U.S. 536, 552.

Goals/Principles II The question to be asked in determining damages is "how much had the Patent Holder and Licensee suffered by the infringement. And that question [is] primarily: had the Infringer not infringed, what would Patent Holder-Licensee have made?" Livesay Window Co. v. Livesay Industries, Inc., 51 F. 2d at 471.

Numerous cases approach this from the patentee’s perspective How much would the patentee have been able to charge in the absence of infringement? How many units would it have sold?

Growing Sophistication Crystal Semiconductor Corp. v. Tritech Microelectronics Int'l, Inc., 246 F3rd 1336, 1356 (FC 2001) "[T]o determine a patentee's market share, the record must accurately identify the market. This requires an analysis which excludes alternatives to the patented product with disparately different prices or significantly different characteristics."

Grain Processing Corp. v. Am. Maize Products Major step in development of balanced counterfactual infringement analysis How would infringer respond to presence of valid patent in the market space?

History matters! Following trial on damages, the District Court, Easterbrook, Circuit Judge, sitting by designation, awarded patent holder reasonable royalty, 893 F.Supp. 1386, and holder appealed. The Court of Appeals, 108 F.3d 1392, remanded for reconsideration of lost profits issue. On remand, the District Court, Easterbrook, Circuit Judge, 979 F.Supp. 1233, again held that holder was not entitled to lost profit damages and awarded royalty instead.

Grain Processing When basing alleged lost profits on lost sales, patent owner has an initial burden to show a reasonable probability that he would have made the asserted sales but for the infringement; once the patent owner establishes a reasonable probability of "but for" causation, the burden then shifts to the accused infringer to show that the patent owner's "but for" causation claim is unreasonable for some or all of the lost sales.

Key holding Fact that competitor's product, as made by alternative, noninfringing process, was not sold on the market during period that patent was infringed by product as it was made by infringing processes did not render product as made by noninfringing process unavailable, for purpose of patent holder's claim for lost profits.

Easterbrook: 979 F.Supp. 1233, 1236 “A product that is within a firm's existing production abilities but not on the market--in this case, Lo-Dex 10 made by Process IV (see 893 F.Supp. at 1389-90)--effectively constrains the patent holder's profits. Potential competition can be as powerful as actual competition in constraining price. William J. Baumol, John C. Panzar & Robert D. Willig, Contestable Markets and the Theory of Industry Structure (1982).”

Grain Processing 4 production processes; one (# 4) non-infringing “Practically instantaneous” transition from infringing process to noninfringing one See why this is important? Process 4 was not actually used . . . But it easily could have been!

Lesson: “There is nothing quite so useful as a good theory.” !!

Note dictum, at p. Patentees have “significant latitude to prove and recover lost profits for a wide variety of foreseeable economic effects of the infringement.”

Examples Rite Hite v. Kelly, 56 F.3d 1538, 1550 (Fed.Cir.1998). Infringer’s sale of “generation 1.0” model took sales away from patentee’s “generation 2.0” product; lost profits damages awarded even though patentee no longer selling generation 1.0 product

Examples American Seating Co. v. USSC Group, Inc. 514 F.3d 1262, 1270 (Fed. Cir. 2008) “Although the evidence in this case was relatively sparse, it sufficed for the jury to assume that USSC offered the VPRo I for sale and then substituted the non-infringing VPRo II -- a bait-and-switch -- and to find that absent USSC's offer to sell the VPRo I, the sales would have gone to American Seating.”

Other damage theories Price erosion Market share rule Lost sales of related but unpatented products Post-expiration sales Relative market share of patentee relative to non-infringers would remain the same without the infringer.

Other damage theories Price erosion Market share rule Lost sales of related but unpatented products Post-expiration sales Components and other related products which are normally sold with the patented product.

Other damage theories Price erosion Market share rule Lost sales of related but unpatented products Post-expiration sales Head-start theory. Competitor cannot enter market immediately post-expiration.

Other damage theories Price erosion Market share rule Lost sales of related but unpatented products Post-expiration sales Relative market share of patentee relative to non-infringers would remain the same without the infringer.

Market Share Rule State Indus., Inc. v. Mor-Flo Indus., Inc., 883 F.2d 1573, 1577, 12 U.S.P.Q.2d 1026, 1028 (Fed. Cir. 1989), cert. denied, 493 U.S. 1022 (1990): Apportion infringer’s sales across (1) patentee and (2) all noninfringing substitute sellers in the market “pro rata” share rule

Important assumptions (1) Everyone knows of and respects patent (2) No enforcement/assertion/infringement costs for patentee that would reduce available funds or encourage rival entry

State Industries v. Mor-Flo Allocate infringer’s market share among (1) patentee and (2) non-infringing substitutes “Pro rata” allocation rule Assume infringer’s share would be split among other competitors according to existing (actual) market shares

More Mor-Flo District court acted within its discretion by awarding damages based on patent owner's share of insulated water heater market; District court properly concluded that royalty of three percent of infringer's net sales was reasonable royalty – sales of infringing products that patentee would not have made

Mor-Flo Applied WMS Gaming, Inc. v. International Game Technology (184 F3rd 1339 (FC 1999)) Plaintiff held a 75% market share. The Federal Circuit affirmed the district court's award of lost profits of $2413 per unit on sales of 75% of the infringing machines, and a reasonable royalty of $550 per unit on sales of the remaining 25% of the infringing machines.

Other damage theories Price erosion Market share rule Lost sales of related but unpatented products Post-expiration sales Components and other related products which are normally sold with the patented product.

Entire Mkt value/ “convoyed” sales Beatrice Foods Co. v. New England Printing and Lithographing Co., 899 F.2d 1171, 1175, 14 U.S.P.Q.2d 1020, 1023 (Fed. Cir. 1990): Sales of products normally sold with patented product may be affected by infringement

Patent reform efforts “Apportionment of damages” provisions End over-compensation for patents on one small component of larger product

Willful infringement Knorr-Bremse Sys. Fuer Nutzfahrzeuge Gmbh v. Dana Corp., 383 F.3d 1337, 1343 (Fed. Cir. 2004) overturned the adverse inference created by an accused infringer’s failure to obtain and produce advice of counsel Does not direct innovators how to demonstrate “due care” in the absence of an exculpatory legal opinion

Willful Infringement II Seagate Standard: