0 MBA 299 – Section Notes 4/25/03 Haas School of Business, UC Berkeley Rawley.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Strategic competition and collusion Oligopolists need to ensure that they all restrict output – collusion is sustained AND (in the same way as monopolists)
Advertisements

Some Problems from Chapt 13
Oligopoly.
Infinitely Repeated Games
Strategic Pricing: Theory, Practice and Policy Professor John W. Mayo
Market Institutions: Oligopoly
ECON 100 Tutorial: Week 9 office: LUMS C85.
Stackelberg -leader/follower game 2 firms choose quantities sequentially (1) chooses its output; then (2) chooses it output; then the market clears This.
Game Theory “Доверяй, Но Проверяй” - Russian Proverb (Trust, but Verify) - Ronald Reagan Mike Shor Lecture 6.
1 Welcome to EC 209: Managerial Economics- Group A By: Dr. Jacqueline Khorassani Week Eleven.
Static Games and Cournot Competition
Infinitely Repeated Games. In an infinitely repeated game, the application of subgame perfection is different - after any possible history, the continuation.
Non-Cooperative Game Theory To define a game, you need to know three things: –The set of players –The strategy sets of the players (i.e., the actions they.
Infinitely Repeated Games Econ 171. Finitely Repeated Game Take any game play it, then play it again, for a specified number of times. The game that is.
EC941 - Game Theory Lecture 7 Prof. Francesco Squintani
Game Theory: Inside Oligopoly
Game Theory Lecture 9.
Industrial Organization - Matilde Machado Tacit Collusion Tacit Collusion Matilde Machado.
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy
Chapter 13 Imperfect Competition: A Game-Theoretic Approach
Strategic Decisions Making in Oligopoly Markets
Oligopoly Fun and games. Oligopoly An oligopolist is one of a small number of producers in an industry. The industry is an oligopoly.  All oligopolists.
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy
1 Welcome to EC 209: Managerial Economics- Group A By: Dr. Jacqueline Khorassani Week Ten.
Copyright © 2010 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 9 Basic Oligopoly.
Basic Oligopoly Models
Objectives © Pearson Education, 2005 Oligopoly LUBS1940: Topic 7.
© 2008 Pearson Addison Wesley. All rights reserved Chapter Fourteen Game Theory.
Static Games and Cournot Competition
APEC 8205: Applied Game Theory Fall 2007
Predatory Conduct What is predatory conduct? –Any strategy designed specifically to deter rival firms from competing in a market. –Primary objective of.
Repeated games - example This stage game is played 2 times Any SPNE where players behave differently than in a 1-time game? Player 2 LMR L1, 10, 05, 0.
TOPIC 6 REPEATED GAMES The same players play the same game G period after period. Before playing in one period they perfectly observe the actions chosen.
© 2008 Pearson Addison Wesley. All rights reserved Chapter Fourteen Game Theory.
Static Games of Complete Information: Subgame Perfection
UNIT III: COMPETITIVE STRATEGY Monopoly Oligopoly Strategic Behavior 7/21.
Oligopoly chapter 19 Copyright © 2014 McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. No reproduction or distribution without the prior written consent of.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 27 Oligopoly.
UNIT III: COMPETITIVE STRATEGY
© 2009 Institute of Information Management National Chiao Tung University Lecture Notes II-2 Dynamic Games of Complete Information Extensive Form Representation.
Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers. Introduction In a wide variety of markets firms compete sequentially –one firm makes a move new product advertising.
MBA 299 – Section Notes 4/11/03 Haas School of Business, UC Berkeley Rawley.
0 MBA 299 – Section Notes 4/18/03 Haas School of Business, UC Berkeley Rawley.
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy
ECO290E: Game Theory Lecture 12 Static Games of Incomplete Information.
Dynamic Games of complete information: Backward Induction and Subgame perfection - Repeated Games -
EC941 - Game Theory Prof. Francesco Squintani Lecture 5 1.
Chapter 9: Static Games and Cournot Competition 1 Static Games and Cournot Competition.
Dynamic Games & The Extensive Form
1 Topic 2 (continuation): Oligopoly Juan A. Mañez.
Chapter Twenty-Seven Oligopoly. u A monopoly is an industry consisting a single firm. u A duopoly is an industry consisting of two firms. u An oligopoly.
CHAPTER 15 Oligopoly PowerPoint® Slides by Can Erbil © 2004 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved.
제 10 장 게임이론 Game Theory: Inside Oligopoly
Oligopolies & Game Theory
Mixed Strategies and Repeated Games
Chapter 6 Extensive Form Games With Perfect Information (Illustrations)
Dynamic games, Stackelburg Cournot and Bertrand
Extensive Form Games With Perfect Information (Illustrations)
Chapter 27 Oligopoly. Oligopoly A monopoly is an industry consisting a single firm. A duopoly is an industry consisting of two firms. An oligopoly is.
Econ 545, Spring 2016 Industrial Organization Dynamic Games.
Entry Deterrence Players Two firms, entrant and incumbent Order of play Entrant decides to enter or stay out. If entrant enters, incumbent decides to fight.
Dynamic Game Theory and the Stackelberg Model. Dynamic Game Theory So far we have focused on static games. However, for many important economic applications.
David Bryce © Adapted from Baye © 2002 Power of Rivalry: Economics of Competition and Profits MANEC 387 Economics of Strategy MANEC 387 Economics.
ECONOMICS FOR BUSINESS (MICROECONOMICS) Lesson 8 Prof. Paolo Buccirossi Alessia Marrazzo.
ECON 330 Lecture 17 Monday, November 25.
Teoria dei giochi e Oligopolio
27 Oligopoly.
Chapter 28 Oligopoly.
Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 – Spring 2009
Presentation transcript:

0 MBA 299 – Section Notes 4/25/03 Haas School of Business, UC Berkeley Rawley

1 AGENDA Stackelberg duopoly Repeated games Problem set #3 and #4

2 STACKELBERG DUOPOLOY (I) Game Set-up Firm 1 moves first and chooses q 1 ≥0 Firm 2 observes q 1 and chooses q 2 ≥0 Payoffs are  (q i,q j )=q i [P(Q)-c] P(Q) = a - Q Q = q 1 + q 2 Solve by backwards induction

3 STACKELBERG DUOPOLOY (II) Equilibrium Outcomes Firm 2 max  2 (q 1,q 2 ) = max q 2 [a-q 1 -q 2 -c] q2≥0 q 2 =R 2 (q 1 ) = [a - q 1 - c]/2 (assuming q 1 < a -c) Firm 1 anticipates Firm 2’s move max  1 (q 1,R 2 (q 1 )) = max q 1 [a-q 1 -R 2 (q 1 )-c] q1≥0 =max q 1 [a-q 1 -c]/2 q 1 * = [a-c]/2 andR 2 (q 1 *) =q 2 * = [a-c]/4

4 STACKELBERG DUOPOLOY (III) Analysis (I) Recall the Cornout duopoly outcome was [a-c]/3 for both firms so total output is higher in the Stackelberg game... and therefore prices are lower –Cornout total output = 2[a-c]/3 –Stackelberg total output = 3[a-c]/4 Firm 1 is better off in the Stackelberg game but Firm 2 is worse off –Firm 1 could have chosen the Cornout output level but did not therefore Firm 1 must be better off –Firm 2 produces less at lower prices so must be worse off

5 STACKELBERG DUOPOLOY (IV) Analysis (II) Observe the role of information –Firm 1 knows that Firm 2 will optimize it’s output based on what Firm 1 does –Firm 2 knows that Firm 1 knows that Firm 2 will optimize it’s output based on what Firm 1 does Order matters too –If Firm 1 went after Firm 2 {and Firm 2 chose [a- c]/4}, Firm 1’s optimal output would be 3[a-c]/8... so Firm 2’s choice would not be an equilibrium outcome... and we would end up back at the Cournot output level

6 STACKELBERG DUOPOLOY (V) Intuition Firm 1 is the dominant firm, in fact it acts like a monopolist, while Firm 2 takes the scraps off the table (acting as a monopolist in the “remaining” market) Firm 1 is the first mover in a market while Firm 2 is the late-comer Note the difference in equilibrium in a sequential move game versus a simultaneous move game Do you observe this effect in the CSG game? If you are entering a market already “held” by an incumbent do you assume they will re-capture their prior period sales?

7 REPEATED GAMES: CREDIBLE THREATS An Example Credible threats about the future can influence current behavior Observe the SPNE outcome of a the game below played twice without discounting (we will cover discounting in infinite games) 1,11,15,00,0 0,54,40,0 3,33,3 U M D LCR The players anticipate that the round 2 outcome will be a NE... But will it be U,L or D,R? How will the round 2 equilibrium outcome influence stage 1 strategies?

8... AN EXAMPLE OF A FINITELY REPEATED GAME 1,11,15,00,0 0,54,40,0 3,33,3 U M D LCR If each player believes the other player will punish them with the lower NE in stage 2 if they fail to play C or M in stage 1 (respectively) then (M,C), (D,R) is the SPNE to this 2-stage game Ex. what will happen if player 2 cheats and plays L in response to 1’s M in stage 1? Player 1 will play U in stage 2. Payoffs: 2 gets 5+1 = 6 vs. 4+3 = 7 in the SPNE outcome... so 2 has an incentive not to cheat in stage 1

9 COMMENTS ON REPEATED GAMES (I) Repetition of a NE of the stage game of a repeated game is always a SPNE of the repeated game A credible threat specifies that of a set of Nash Equilibria play the one such that the other player(s) is (are) worse off than in their preferred outcome (see previous ex.) If there are credible threats there are SPNE that differ from stage game NE outcomes in some rounds... but if there is only one NE in the stage game and the end of the game is known with certainty the unraveling results holds where the only SPNE is repeated play of the stage game NE Remember, only SPNE strategies are credible... think about this... recall Odysseus vs. the Sirens

10 COMMENTS ON REPEATED GAMES (II) Does the last period have to be a NE? Yes Cooperation can be achieved in all but the last round of a repeated game... this means the players may not be playing a stage game NE in every period except the last... still at every subgame (the current stage game plus all the future stage games) will be in NE and therefore the whole game is in SPNE Think about stage games, subgames, NE, SPNE and credible threats

11 DISCOUNTING IN INFINITELY REPEATED GAMES context: infinite “doom” trigger strategies - cooperate unless the other player defects, then defect every round forever discount factor is  = 1/[1+r] < 1 Discounting in infinitely repeated games S =  x p = x t + x t+1 + x t xS =  x p =x t+1 + x t+2 + x t S - xS = (1-x)S= x t S = x t /(1-x) if x =  and p=0 then S = 1/(1-  ) and p=1 then S =  /(1-  ) p=t infinity p=t

12 INFINITE PD WITH DISCOUNTING 3,33,36,2 2,64,44,4 D C DC Proposed strategy for i play C unless j plays D then play D forever When is this strategy a SPNE? 4[1/(1-  )] > 6 + 3[  /(1-  )] if  ≥2/3 Therefore, cooperating in every subgame is SPNE if  is large enough (players don’t discount too much)

13 THE FOLK THEOREM: MULTIPLE SPNE As long as gamma is big enough (players are sufficiently patient) any stage game outcome with payoffs in excess of the stage game Nash Equilibrium (singular) outcome can be supported as a cooperative SPNE Contrast this with the unraveling result This is a nice result because it tells us we can support cooperation with trigger strategies in long-period repeated games where players are patient as long as neither player knows when the game will end Problem: An embarrassment of riches

14 TACIT COLLUSION The repeated Bertrand game as the “oligopoly game” –Rather than sustaining p=MC why not sustain p=p M *? –strategy for i charge p=p M unless j charges a lower price, then charge p=c forever the punishment is a stage game NE so it is SP (see Odysseus) check the math (p.18 of Professor Hermalin’s notes), if  ≥ 1/2 the strategy is SPNE –Note that the minimum  increases as the number of players increase Tacit collusion = the oligopoly game = f(N,  ) –Impatient players do not make good tacit co-conspirators

15 PRICE WARS Punishment strategies do not have to be doom trigger strategies –Punishments don’t have to last forever to be effective... however, they do need to be deep to be effective if they are short Price wars are short, deep punishments (note: discounting still plays a role) When only imperfect monitoring of rivals exists trigger strategies are the only credible threat rivals will respect... they need not be doom triggers though

16 PROBLEM SET ON COURNOT, TACIT COLLUSION AND ENTRY DETERRENCE #3 (I) (a)Compare the payoff to undercutting in the summer (once only) to colluding forever NPV undercut = 10D(v-c) NPV collude = 10D/4(v-c) +.9D/4(v-c) D/4(v-c) D/4(v-c) D/4(v-c)... = 10D/4(v-c)[1/( )] + D/4(v-c)[.9/(1-.9)-.9 4 /( )] =10D(v-c)* (b)  (collude at p summer ) = 10D(p s -c)/4 = 10D[(v+9c)/10-c]/4 =D(v-c)/4 See problem #2 for how tacit collusion can be obtained at this level

17 PROBLEM SET ON COURNOT, TACIT COLLUSION AND ENTRY DETERRENCE #3 (II) (c) This explains seasonal sales as a mechanism for sustaining tacit collusion when demand is high... These are essentially ways to release tension in the tacit colluding process (d) 10D(p s – c) ≤ NPV collude NPV collude = 10D/4(p s ) +.9D/4(100) D/4(100) D/4(100) D/4(p s )... = 10D/4(p s )[1/( )] + D/4(100)[.9/(1-.9)-.9 4 /( )] =10D(v-c)* So 40p s ≤ 10p s x x => p s = 64.95

18 PROBLEM SET ON COURNOT, TACIT COLLUSION AND ENTRY DETERRENCE #4 (a)  1 = (v-c)*D (b)  2 = cD-K => if c>K/D player 2 will enter (c)E[c]*D – K, where E[c] = 3v/4*1/2 = 3v/8 since K<3v/8 player 2 should enter (d) If player 1 plays K/D in the first period in anticipation of keeping player 2 out she will earn (K/D –c)D + (v-c)D If she does not want to keep player 2 out she will price at v and earn (v-c)D Therefore, entry deterrence only makes sense if K/D>c (e) Limit pricing can work but only if costs are low enough

19

20 MBA 299 – Section Notes 4/18/03 Haas School of Business, UC Berkeley Rawley

21 AGENDA Administrative CSG concepts –Discussion of demand estimation –Cournot equilibrium Multiple players Different costs –Firm-specific demand for differentiated products and how that can look very different than the demand faced by a monopolist Problem set on Cournot, Tacit Collusion and Entry Deterrence

22 QUESTION 1: COURNOT EQUILIBRIUM Q(p) = 2,000, ,000p MC 1 = MC 2 = 10 a.) P(Q) = 40 - Q/50,000 => q1 = q2 = (40-10)/3*50,000 = 500,000 b.)  i = (p-c)*q i = (40-1,000,000/50,000-10)*500,000 = $5M c.) Setting MR = MC => a – 2bQ = c Q* = (a-c)/2b =>  m = {a – b[(a-c)/2b]}*(a-c)/2b = (a-c) 2 /4b =>  m = (40-10)/4*50,000 =$11.25M

23 QUESTION 2: REPEATED GAMES AND TACIT COLLUSION Bertrand model set-up with four firms and  = 0.9  (cooperate) = D*(v – c)/4  (defect) = D*(v – c)  (punishment) = 0 Colluding is superior iff  {D*(v-c)/4*  t } = D*(v-c)/4*[1/(1-.9)]  D*(v-c) + 0 since 10/4  1 this is true, hence cooperation/collusion is sustainable