Chapter Three Preferences.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Preferences. Rationality in Economics u Behavioral Postulate: A decisionmaker always chooses its most preferred alternative from its set of available.
Advertisements

Chapter Five Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those.
Choice.
Chapter Four Utility. Preferences - A Reminder u x y: x is preferred strictly to y.  x  y: x and y are equally preferred. u x y: x is preferred at least.
Chapter 3 Preferences Choose the “best” thing one can “afford” Start with consumption bundles (a complete list of the goods that is involved in consumer’s.
Chapter 3. * Prerequisite: A binary relation R on X is said to be Complete if xRy or yRx for any pair of x and y in X; Reflexive if xRx for any x in X;
Utilities Indifference curves
UNIT I: Theory of the Consumer
Tastes/Preferences Indifference Curves.
Combinations (X1, Y1) and (X2, Y2) provide the same level of utility
Intermediate Microeconomics
Chapter Five Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those.
PREFERENCES AND UTILITY
Axioms of Rational Choice
Utility.
Chapter Seven Revealed Preference. Revealed Preference Analysis u Suppose we observe the demands (consumption choices) that a consumer makes for different.
Chapter Five Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those.
Axioms of Rational Choice
Chapter Three Preferences. Rationality in Economics u Behavioral Postulate: A decisionmaker always chooses its most preferred alternative from its set.
Utility.
Chapter Eighteen Technology. Technologies  A technology is a process by which inputs are converted to an output.  E.g. labor, a computer, a projector,
Chapter Three Preferences. Rationality in Economics u Behavioral Postulate: A decisionmaker always chooses its most preferred alternative from its set.
Preferences. Preference Relation The consumer strictly prefers bundle X to bundle Y: The consumer is indifferent between X and Y:
Chapter Four Utility.
1 Chapter 3 PREFERENCES AND UTILITY Copyright ©2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.
1 Intermediate Microeconomics Preferences. 2 Consumer Behavior Budget Set organizes information about possible choices available to a given consumer.
Chapter Three Preferences. Rationality in Economics u Behavioral Postulate: An economic decisionmaker always chooses her most preferred alternative from.
Chapter Five Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those.
Chapter Three Preferences 偏好. Structure 3.1 Preference relations 3.2 Assumptions about preferences 3.3 Graphical representation of preferences—indifference.
Chapter 5 Choice.
The Theory of Individual Behavior. Overview I. Consumer Behavior n Indifference Curve Analysis n Consumer Preference Ordering II. Constraints n The Budget.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 4 Utility. © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 2 Preferences - A Reminder u x y: x is preferred strictly to y.  x.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 5 Choice. © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 2 Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that.
Rationality in Economics Behavioral Postulate: A decisionmaker always chooses its most preferred alternative from its set of available alternatives. So.
Course: Microeconomics Text: Varian’s Intermediate Microeconomics 1.
Consumer Preferences and the Concept of Utility
1 Chapter 3 PREFERENCES AND UTILITY Copyright ©2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.
Chapter 3 Preferences.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 3 Preferences.
1 Preferences Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 – Spring 2009.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 4 Utility. © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 2 Preferences - A Reminder u x y: x is preferred strictly to y.  x.
Chapter Three Preferences. u Consumer behavior is best understood in three distinct steps: 1. Consumer Preferences: The first step is to find a practical.
CDAE Class 4 Sept. 6 Last class: 1.Introduction 2.Preferences and choice Class exercise 1 Today: 2. Preferences and choice Next class: 2.Preferences.
CHAPTER 2 UTILITY AND CHOICE. Objective Build a model to understand how a consumer makes decisions under scarcity. To understand his choice we need to.
L03 Utility. Big picture u Behavioral Postulate: A decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from the set of affordable alternatives. u Budget.
Budgetary and Other Constraints on Choice
L04 Choice. Big picture u Behavioral Postulate: A decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from the set of affordable alternatives. u Budget.
L02 Preferences. Rationality in Economics u Behavioral Postulate: A decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from the set of affordable alternatives.
Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 – Spring 2009
L03 Utility. Quiz How much do you like microeconomics A: I love it (unconditionally) B: I cannot live without it C: I would die for it D: All of the above.
Rational Consumer Choice Chapter 3. Rational Choice Theory Assumption that consumers enter the market place with clear preferences Price takers Consumers.
Recall: Consumer behavior Why are we interested? –New good in the market. What price should be charged? How much more for a premium brand? –Subsidy program:
PREFERENCES. Rationality in Economics Behavioral Postulate: A decisionmaker always chooses its most preferred alternative from its set of available alternatives.
L02 Preferences.
Chapter 3 Preferences Intermediate Microeconomics:
Choice.
3 Preferences.
Chapter 5 Choice.
Chapter Three Preferences.
Chapter Seven Revealed Preference.
PREFERENCES.
L02 Preferences.
L03 Utility.
L02 Preferences.
Choice.
Chapter 3 Preferences.
Chapter 3 Preferences Key Concept: characterize preferences by a binary comparison measuring at least as good as. Derive the indifference curves for a.
L02 Preferences.
L02 Preferences.
L02 Preferences.
Presentation transcript:

Chapter Three Preferences

Rationality in Economics Behavioral Postulate: A decisionmaker always chooses its most preferred alternative from its set of available alternatives. So to model choice we must model decisionmakers’ preferences.

Preference Relations Comparing two different consumption bundles, x and y: strict preference: x is more preferred than is y. weak preference: x is as at least as preferred as is y. indifference: x is exactly as preferred as is y.

Preference Relations Strict preference, weak preference and indifference are all preference relations. Particularly, they are ordinal relations; i.e. they state only the order in which bundles are preferred.

Preference Relations p p denotes strict preference; x y means that bundle x is preferred strictly to bundle y. p

Preference Relations p p denotes strict preference; x y means bundle x is preferred strictly to bundle y. ~ denotes indifference; x ~ y means x and y are equally preferred. p

Preference Relations p p f ~ f ~ denotes strict preference so x y means that bundle x is preferred strictly to bundle y. ~ denotes indifference; x ~ y means x and y are equally preferred. denotes weak preference; x y means x is preferred at least as much as is y. p ~ f ~ f

Preference Relations ~ f ~ f x y and y x imply x ~ y.

Preference Relations ~ f ~ f ~ f ~ f p x y and y x imply x ~ y. x y and (not y x) imply x y. ~ f ~ f p

Assumptions about Preference Relations Completeness: For any two bundles x and y it is always possible to make the statement that either x y or y x. ~ f ~ f

Assumptions about Preference Relations Reflexivity: Any bundle x is always at least as preferred as itself; i.e. x x. ~ f

Assumptions about Preference Relations Transitivity: If x is at least as preferred as y, and y is at least as preferred as z, then x is at least as preferred as z; i.e. x y and y z x z. ~ f ~ f ~ f

Indifference Curves Take a reference bundle x’. The set of all bundles equally preferred to x’ is the indifference curve containing x’; the set of all bundles y ~ x’. Since an indifference “curve” is not always a curve a better name might be an indifference “set”.

Indifference Curves x2 x’ ~ x” ~ x”’ x’ x” x”’ x1

Indifference Curves x2 z x y p p x z y x1

Indifference Curves I1 All bundles in I1 are strictly preferred to all in I2. x2 x z I2 All bundles in I2 are strictly preferred to all in I3. y I3 x1

Indifference Curves x2 x I(x’) I(x) x1 WP(x), the set of bundles weakly preferred to x. x I(x’) I(x) x1

Indifference Curves x2 x I(x) x1 WP(x), the set of bundles weakly preferred to x. x WP(x) includes I(x). I(x) x1

Indifference Curves x2 x I(x) x1 SP(x), the set of bundles strictly preferred to x, does not include I(x). x I(x) x1

Indifference Curves Cannot Intersect From I1, x ~ y. From I2, x ~ z. Therefore y ~ z. x2 I1 x y z x1

Indifference Curves Cannot Intersect From I1, x ~ y. From I2, x ~ z. Therefore y ~ z. But from I1 and I2 we see y z, a contradiction. x2 I2 I1 p x y z x1

Slopes of Indifference Curves When more of a commodity is always preferred, the commodity is a good. If every commodity is a good then indifference curves are negatively sloped.

Slopes of Indifference Curves Good 2 Two goods a negatively sloped indifference curve. Better Worse Good 1

Slopes of Indifference Curves If less of a commodity is always preferred then the commodity is a bad.

Slopes of Indifference Curves Good 2 One good and one bad a positively sloped indifference curve. Better Worse Bad 1

Extreme Cases of Indifference Curves; Perfect Substitutes If a consumer always regards units of commodities 1 and 2 as equivalent, then the commodities are perfect substitutes and only the total amount of the two commodities in bundles determines their preference rank-order.

Extreme Cases of Indifference Curves; Perfect Substitutes Slopes are constant at - 1. 15 I2 Bundles in I2 all have a total of 15 units and are strictly preferred to all bundles in I1, which have a total of only 8 units in them. 8 I1 x1 8 15

Extreme Cases of Indifference Curves; Perfect Complements If a consumer always consumes commodities 1 and 2 in fixed proportion (e.g. one-to-one), then the commodities are perfect complements and only the number of pairs of units of the two commodities determines the preference rank-order of bundles.

Extreme Cases of Indifference Curves; Perfect Complements Each of (5,5), (5,9) and (9,5) contains 5 pairs so each is equally preferred. 9 5 I1 x1 5 9

Extreme Cases of Indifference Curves; Perfect Complements Since each of (5,5), (5,9) and (9,5) contains 5 pairs, each is less preferred than the bundle (9,9) which contains 9 pairs. 9 I2 5 I1 x1 5 9

Preferences Exhibiting Satiation A bundle strictly preferred to any other is a satiation point or a bliss point. What do indifference curves look like for preferences exhibiting satiation?

Indifference Curves Exhibiting Satiation Satiation (bliss) point x1

Indifference Curves Exhibiting Satiation Better Better Satiation (bliss) point Better x1

Indifference Curves Exhibiting Satiation Better Better Satiation (bliss) point Better x1

Well-Behaved Preferences A preference relation is “well-behaved” if it is monotonic and convex. Monotonicity: More of any commodity is always preferred (i.e. no satiation and every commodity is a good).

Well-Behaved Preferences Convexity: Mixtures of bundles are (at least weakly) preferred to the bundles themselves. E.g., the 50-50 mixture of the bundles x and y is z = (0.5)x + (0.5)y. z is at least as preferred as x or y.

Well-Behaved Preferences -- Convexity. x+y is strictly preferred to both x and y. x2+y2 z = 2 2 y y2 x1 x1+y1 y1 2

Well-Behaved Preferences -- Convexity. z =(tx1+(1-t)y1, tx2+(1-t)y2) is preferred to x and y for all 0 < t < 1. y y2 x1 y1

Well-Behaved Preferences -- Convexity. Preferences are strictly convex when all mixtures z are strictly preferred to their component bundles x and y. x x2 z y y2 x1 y1

Well-Behaved Preferences -- Weak Convexity. Preferences are weakly convex if at least one mixture z is equally preferred to a component bundle. x’ z’ x z y y’

Non-Convex Preferences Better The mixture z is less preferred than x or y. z y2 x1 y1

More Non-Convex Preferences Better The mixture z is less preferred than x or y. z y2 x1 y1

Slopes of Indifference Curves The slope of an indifference curve is its marginal rate-of-substitution (MRS). How can a MRS be calculated?

Marginal Rate of Substitution x2 MRS at x’ is the slope of the indifference curve at x’ x’ x1

Marginal Rate of Substitution x2 MRS at x’ is lim {Dx2/Dx1} Dx1 0 = dx2/dx1 at x’ Dx2 x’ Dx1 x1

MRS & Ind. Curve Properties Good 2 MRS = - 5 MRS always increases with x1 (becomes less negative) if and only if preferences are strictly convex. MRS = - 0.5 Good 1

MRS & Ind. Curve Properties x2 MRS decreases (becomes more negative) as x1 increases nonconvex preferences MRS = - 0.5 MRS = - 5 x1

MRS & Ind. Curve Properties MRS is not always increasing as x1 increases nonconvex preferences. x2 MRS = - 1 MRS = - 0.5 MRS = - 2 x1