Extensive-form games: applications Stackelberg model Spence-Dixit model Rubinstein bargaining model.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Some examples in Cournot Competition
Advertisements

The World of Oligopoly: Preliminaries to Successful Entry
1 Predatory Conduct. 2 Predatory conduct is the implementation of a strategy designed specifically to deter rival firms from competing in a market. To.
Stackelberg -leader/follower game 2 firms choose quantities sequentially (1) chooses its output; then (2) chooses it output; then the market clears This.
Chapter Twenty-Seven Oligopoly. u A monopoly is an industry consisting a single firm. u A duopoly is an industry consisting of two firms. u An oligopoly.
Cournot versus Stackelberg n Cournot duopoly (simultaneous quantity competition) n Stackelberg duopoly (sequential quantity competition) x2x2 x1x1 x1x2x1x2.
1 Industrial Organization Entry deterrence Univ. Prof. dr. Maarten Janssen University of Vienna Summer semester Week 5.
ECO290E: Game Theory Lecture 9 Subgame Perfect Equilibrium.
Predatory Conduct What is predatory conduct?
HKKK TMP 38E050 © Markku Stenborg Entry How does entry or potential competition affect market power of established firms? How can dominant firms.
Source: Perloff. Some parts: © 2004 Pearson Addison- Wesley. All rights reserved Strategy Perloff: Chapter 14.
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy
EC941 - Game Theory Prof. Francesco Squintani Lecture 8 1.
Chapter 11 Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers.
UNIT II: The Basic Theory Zero-sum Games Nonzero-sum Games Nash Equilibrium: Properties and Problems Bargaining Games Review Midterm3/21 3/7.
Cournot versus Stackelberg n Cournot duopoly (simultaneous quantity competition) n Stackelberg duopoly (sequential quantity competition) x2x2 x1x1 x1x2x1x2.
© 2008 Pearson Addison Wesley. All rights reserved Chapter Fourteen Game Theory.
Job Market Signaling (Spence model)
APEC 8205: Applied Game Theory Fall 2007
Predatory Conduct What is predatory conduct? –Any strategy designed specifically to deter rival firms from competing in a market. –Primary objective of.
© 2008 Pearson Addison Wesley. All rights reserved Chapter Fourteen Game Theory.
Static Games of Complete Information: Subgame Perfection
UNIT II: The Basic Theory Zero-sum Games Nonzero-sum Games Nash Equilibrium: Properties and Problems Bargaining Games Review Midterm3/23 3/2.
Chapter Fourteen Strategy. © 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.14–2 Strategic Behavior A set of actions a firm takes to increase its profit,
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 27 Oligopoly.
UNIT II: The Basic Theory Zero-sum Games Nonzero-sum Games Nash Equilibrium: Properties and Problems Bargaining Games Review Midterm3/19 3/5.
© 2009 Institute of Information Management National Chiao Tung University Lecture Notes II-2 Dynamic Games of Complete Information Extensive Form Representation.
David J. Bryce © 2002 Michael R. Baye © 2002 Game Theory: Entry Games MANEC 387 Economics of Strategy MANEC 387 Economics of Strategy David J. Bryce.
Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers. Introduction In a wide variety of markets firms compete sequentially –one firm makes a move new product advertising.
Dynamic Games of Complete Information
1 Game Theory Sequential bargaining and Repeated Games Univ. Prof.dr. M.C.W. Janssen University of Vienna Winter semester Week 46 (November 14-15)
Lecture 8: pricing and Strategy Advanced Micro Theory MSc.EnviNatResEcon. 1/2006 Charit Tingsabadh.
Extensive Form Games With Perfect Information (Extensions)
EC941 - Game Theory Prof. Francesco Squintani Lecture 5 1.
Bargaining Whoever offers to another a bargain of any kind, proposes to do this. Give me that which I want, and you shall have this which you want …; and.
Dynamic Games & The Extensive Form
1 Lecture 6: Strategic commitment & applications to entry and exit (II) Entry, Capacity and Price Competition: Gelman & Salop, 1983, Bell Journal of Economics,
Monopolistic Competition Large number of firms producing differentiated products By differentiating its product from its competitors’ products, the firm.
ECO290E: Game Theory Lecture 6 Dynamic Games and Backward Induction.
Chapter Twenty-Seven Oligopoly. u A monopoly is an industry consisting a single firm. u A duopoly is an industry consisting of two firms. u An oligopoly.
제 10 장 게임이론 Game Theory: Inside Oligopoly
Chapter 6 Extensive Form Games With Perfect Information (Illustrations)
Game Theory (Microeconomic Theory (IV)) Instructor: Yongqin Wang School of Economics, Fudan University December, 2004.
Dynamic games, Stackelburg Cournot and Bertrand
Extensive Form Games With Perfect Information (Illustrations)
Oligopoly Theory1 Oligopoly Theory (6) Endogenous Timing in Oligopoly The aim of the lecture (1) To understand the basic idea of endogenous (2) To understand.
Topics to be Discussed Gaming and Strategic Decisions
Chapter 28 Oligopoly It is the case that lies between two extremes (pure competition and pure monopoly). Often there are a number of competitors but not.
Bargaining games Econ 414. General bargaining games A common application of repeated games is to examine situations of two or more parties bargaining.
Chapter 27 Oligopoly. Oligopoly A monopoly is an industry consisting a single firm. A duopoly is an industry consisting of two firms. An oligopoly is.
Entry Deterrence Players Two firms, entrant and incumbent Order of play Entrant decides to enter or stay out. If entrant enters, incumbent decides to fight.
Dynamic Game Theory and the Stackelberg Model. Dynamic Game Theory So far we have focused on static games. However, for many important economic applications.
Lecture V: Bargaining Recommended Reading: Dixit & Skeath, Chapter 17 Osborne, Chapter 6.1, 16 Powell, In the Shadow of Power, Ch. 3.
Managerial Economics Game Theory
ECON 330 Lecture 21 Monday, December 9.
ECON 330 Lecture 26 Thursday, December 27.
Teoria dei giochi e Oligopolio
ECONOMICS FOR BUSINESS (MICROECONOMICS) Lesson 9
ECON 330 Lecture 23 Thursday, December 13.
27 Oligopoly.
Chapter 28 Oligopoly.
Stackelberg Models of Duopoly
ECON 4100: Industrial Organization
Chapter 28 Oligopoly Key Concept: We have the first taste of how to solve a game! Stackelberg, Cournot, Bertrand.
Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers
LECTURE 3 DYNAMIC GAMES OF COMPLETE INFORMATION
ECE700.07: Game Theory with Engineering Applications
Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers
Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers
Chapter Twenty-Seven Oligopoly.
Presentation transcript:

Extensive-form games: applications Stackelberg model Spence-Dixit model Rubinstein bargaining model

Stackelberg model Consider a Stackelberg duopoly game with asymmetric technologies. There are two inputs K (capital) and L (labor). Firms have the same Leontief production functions: The cost of L is w and the cost of K is r, hence the cost functions are: The (inverse) demand curve: P = 1 – Q Firm 1 (leader) chooses q 1 first and then firm chooses q 2

Stackelberg model - solution We solve the game backwards. In stage 2, firm 2 maximizes its profit: F.O.C: Best response: Firm 1 maximizes:

Stackelberg-solution F.O.C. for firm 1 Solution: Firm 1 has an advantage and makes 2x more profit than firm 2

Spence-Dixit model of entry deterrence Step 1. An incumbent firm (1) chooses the capacity level k. Installing capacity costs r per unit. Step 2. A potential entrant firm (2) decides whether to enter the market or not. If enters, pays the fixed cost F. Step 3. Firm 1’s marginal cost is w for the first k units, and (w + r) for all units above k. If firm 2 stays out, firm 1 acts as a (static) monopolist. If firm 2 enters, they compete as in Cournot model, but firm 2’s marginal cost is (w + r) for all units.

Spence-Dixit - solution In step 3, if firm 2 enters, the F.O.C.s are and the equilibrium quantities are provided that q 1  k we will not worry about the case q 1 > k for reasons that will become apparent

Spence-Dixit - solution In step 3, if firm 2 stayed out, firm 1 is a monopolist and chooses where c is the marginal cost In step 2, firm 2 enters iff  2 (q 2 D )>0 In step 1, firm 1 chooses k. There are 3 cases: Blockaded entry: firm 2 will not enter even if firm 1 installs k = 0 Entry deterred: firm 1 discourages firm 2 from entering by overinvesting, i.e. choosing some k > q 1 M (what a pure monopolist would produce) Entry accommodated: firm 1 chooses k = q 1 D and firm 1 enters

Rubinstein bargaining model This is a (potentially) infinitely repeated version of the ultimatum game Player 1 begins by offering a split of 1$ to player 2 Player 2 accepts or rejects If rejects, he makes the next offer of split, except the 1$ decreases to $  - discount factor Players alternate their offers until there is an agreement

Rubinstein model - solution Let (s t, 1-s t ) denote the split offered in period t Suppose that the players know that if they don’t come to an agreement after 2 stages (2 offers), they will receive the split (s, 1-s) In stage 2, player 2 is choosing between proposing an acceptable offer or getting  (1-s) after rejection the best acceptable offer is s 2 =  s (what player 1 gets in stage 3 afetr rejection) hence the offer in stage 2 will be (  s, 1-  s) In stage 1, player 1 is choosing between proposing an acceptable offer or getting  2 s after rejection the best acceptable offer is s 1 = 1 -  (1-  s) (1 - what player 2 gets in stage 3 after rejection) hence the offer in stage 1 will be (1-  (1-  s),  (1-  s))

Rubinstein - solution OK, but there is no final period. How do we know that s exists? What is it? Let s H be the highest share that player 1 can expect in this game. By the above argument we know that the highest first-period share is 1 -  (1-  s H ). But since all subgames starting at odd periods look the same, s H = 1 -  (1-  s H )  s H = 1/(1+  ) Let s L be the lowest share that player 1 can expect in this game. By the above argument we know that the highest first-period share is 1 -  (1-  s L ). But since all subgames starting at odd periods look the same, s L = 1 -  (1-  s L )  s L = s H = 1/(1+  ) Hence the only equilibrium is for player 1 to offer (1/(1+  ),  /(1+  )) and for player 2 to accept

Extensive-form games with imperfect information Husband HomeOut (2, 2) This game can be represented as... Wife FootballBallet Hus band Football3, 10, 0 Ballet0, 01, 3

Extensive-form games with imperfect information This, the dotted line connects decision nodes that are in the same information set Husband HomeOut (2, 2) Husband Wife FootballBallet FootballBalletFootballBallet (3, 1)(0, 0)(1, 1)(1, 3)

Repeated games This is a special class of games in extensive form An identical „stage game” is repeated several times The payoffs are paid out after each „stage game” The payoffs from future period are discounted ( the payoff u in period t is worth  t u now)

Rubinstein - solution Notation

Finitely Repeated Games: An Example