Static Games and Cournot Competition

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Strategic Pricing: Theory, Practice and Policy Professor John W. Mayo
Advertisements

The World of Oligopoly: Preliminaries to Successful Entry
Market Institutions: Oligopoly
Monopoly Standard Profit Maximization is max r(y)-c(y). With Monopoly this is Max p(y)y-c(y) (the difference to competition is price now depends upon output).
Chapter Twenty-Seven Oligopoly. u A monopoly is an industry consisting a single firm. u A duopoly is an industry consisting of two firms. u An oligopoly.
© 2009 Pearson Education Canada 16/1 Chapter 16 Game Theory and Oligopoly.
Static Games and Cournot Competition
Strategic Interaction Finance 510: Microeconomic Analysis.
Chapter 12 Oligopoly. Chapter 122 Oligopoly – Characteristics Small number of firms Product differentiation may or may not exist Barriers to entry.
Chapter 13 Imperfect Competition: A Game-Theoretic Approach
Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy
1 Welcome to EC 209: Managerial Economics- Group A By: Dr. Jacqueline Khorassani Week Ten.
Simultaneous games with continuous strategies Suppose two players have to choose a number between 0 and 100. They can choose any real number (i.e. any.
Copyright © 2010 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 9 Basic Oligopoly.
© 2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc Chapter 16 Game Theory and Oligopoly.
A camper awakens to the growl of a hungry bear and sees his friend putting on a pair of running shoes, “You can’t outrun a bear,” scoffs the camper. His.
Basic Oligopoly Models
Chapter 11 Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers.
Chapter 12 Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly.
Finance 30210: Managerial Economics Strategic Pricing Techniques.
CHAPTER 9 Basic Oligopoly Models Copyright © 2014 McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. No reproduction or distribution without the prior written.
Monopolistic Competition
Oligopoly and Strategic Interaction
Chapter Twenty-Seven Oligopoly. u A monopoly is an industry consisting a single firm. u A duopoly is an industry consisting of two firms. u An oligopoly.
Figure 12.1 Perfect Price Discrimination
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 27 Oligopoly.
Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers. Introduction In a wide variety of markets firms compete sequentially –one firm makes a move new product advertising.
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy
Oligopoly Chapter 16. Imperfect Competition Imperfect competition includes industries in which firms have competitors but do not face so much competition.
Lecture 8: pricing and Strategy Advanced Micro Theory MSc.EnviNatResEcon. 1/2006 Charit Tingsabadh.
Static Games and Cournot Competition
3.1. Strategic Behavior Matilde Machado.
Market structure and competition By A.V. Vedpuriswar.
Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly
Nash equilibrium Nash equilibrium is defined in terms of strategies, not payoffs Every player is best responding simultaneously (everyone optimizes) This.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.1 Prepared by: Kevin Richter, Douglas College Charlene Richter, British Columbia Institute of Technology.
Chapter 9: Static Games and Cournot Competition 1 Static Games and Cournot Competition.
Oligopoly. Oligopoly is a market in which a small number of firms compete. In oligopoly, the quantity sold by one firm depends on the firm’s own price.
CHAPTER 12 Imperfect Competition. The profit-maximizing output for the monopoly 2 If there are no other market entrants, the entrepreneur can earn monopoly.
Yohanes E. Riyanto EC 3322 (Industrial Organization I) 1 EC 3322 Semester I – 2008/2009 Topic 5: Static Games Cournot Competition.
Oligopoly. Structure Assume Duopoly Firms know information about market demand Perfect Information.
Lecture 12Slide 1 Topics to be Discussed Oligopoly Price Competition Competition Versus Collusion: The Prisoners’ Dilemma.
CHAPTER 23 MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY.
Perfect competition, with an infinite number of firms, and monopoly, with a single firm, are polar opposites. Monopolistic competition and oligopoly.
Chapter Twenty-Seven Oligopoly. u A monopoly is an industry consisting a single firm. u A duopoly is an industry consisting of two firms. u An oligopoly.
Microeconomics 2 John Hey.
1 Chapter 10 Price Competition 2 In a wide variety of markets firms compete in prices –Internet access –Restaurants –Consultants –Financial services.
Business Strategy in Oligopoly Markets
Monopolistic competition and Oligopoly
Managerial Economics Game Theory Aalto University School of Science Department of Industrial Engineering and Management January 12 – 28, 2016 Dr. Arto.
Chapter 27 Oligopoly. Oligopoly A monopoly is an industry consisting a single firm. A duopoly is an industry consisting of two firms. An oligopoly is.
Lecture 6 Oligopoly 1. 2 Introduction A monopoly does not have to worry about how rivals will react to its action simply because there are no rivals.
Static Games and Cournot Competition
27 Oligopoly.
Chapter 28 Oligopoly.
Games Of Strategy Chapter 4 Dixit, Skeath, and Reiley
Oligopoly and Monopolistic Competition
Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 – Spring 2009
CHAPTER 12 OUTLINE Monopolistic Competition Oligopoly Price Competition Competition versus Collusion: The Prisoners’ Dilemma 12.5.
Lecture 9 Static Games and the Cournot Model
Static Games and Cournot Competition
Static Games and Quantity vs. Price Competition
Static Games and Quantity vs. Price Competition
Dynamic games and First and Second Movers (The Stackelberg Model)
Static Games and Quantity vs. Price Competition
Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers
Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers
Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers
Chapter Twenty-Seven Oligopoly.
Presentation transcript:

Static Games and Cournot Competition Chapter 9 Static Games and Cournot Competition

Introduction In the majority of markets firms interact with few competitors In determining strategy each firm has to consider rival’s reactions strategic interaction in prices, outputs, advertising … This kind of interaction is analyzed using game theory assumes that “players” are rational Distinguish cooperative and noncooperative games focus on noncooperative games Also consider timing simultaneous versus sequential games

Oligopoly Theory No single theory Need a concept of equilibrium employ game theoretic tools that are appropriate outcome depends upon information available Need a concept of equilibrium players (firms?) choose strategies, one for each player combination of strategies determines outcome outcome determines pay-offs (profits?) Equilibrium first formalized by Nash: No firm wants to change its current strategy given that no other firm changes its current strategy

Nash Equilibrium Equilibrium need not be “nice” firms might do better by coordinating but such coordination may not be possible (or legal) Some strategies can be eliminated on occasions they are never good strategies no matter what the rivals do These are dominated strategies they are never employed and so can be eliminated elimination of a dominated strategy may result in another being dominated: it also can be eliminated One strategy might always be chosen no matter what the rivals do: dominant strategy

An Example Two airlines Prices set: compete in departure times 70% of consumers prefer evening departure, 30% prefer morning departure If the airlines choose the same departure times they share the market equally Pay-offs to the airlines are determined by market shares Represent the pay-offs in a pay-off matrix

The example (cont.) What is the equilibrium for this game? The Pay-Off Matrix The left-hand number is the pay-off to Delta American Morning Evening Morning (15, 15) (30, 70) The right-hand number is the pay-off to American Delta Evening (70, 30) (35, 35)

1, If American chooses a morning departure, Delta will choose evening 2, If American chooses an evening departure, Delta will still choose evening 3, The morning departure is a dominated strategy for Delta and so can be eliminated. 4, The morning departure is also a dominated strategy for American and again can be eliminated 5, The Nash Equilibrium must therefore be one in which both airlines choose an evening departure

The example (cont.) The Pay-Off Matrix American Morning Evening (15, 15) (30, 70) Delta (35, 35) Evening (70, 30) (35, 35)

This changes the pay-off matrix Now suppose that Delta has a frequent flier program; When both airline choose the same departure times Delta gets 60% of the travelers This changes the pay-off matrix If Delta chooses a morning departure, American will choose evening But if Delta chooses an evening departure, American will choose morning American has no dominated strategy. However, a morning departure is still a dominated strategy for Delta. So, evening is still a dominant strategy. American knows this and so chooses a morning departure.

The example (cont.) The Pay-Off Matrix American Morning Evening (18, 12) (30, 70) Delta (70, 30) Evening (70, 30) (42, 28)

Nash Equilibrium Again What if there are no dominated or dominant strategies? The Nash equilibrium concept can still help us in eliminating at least some outcomes Change the airline game to a pricing game: 60 potential passengers with a reservation price of $500 120 additional passengers with a reservation price of $220 price discrimination is not possible (perhaps for regulatory reasons or because the airlines don’t know the passenger types) costs are $200 per passenger no matter when the plane leaves the airlines must choose between a price of $500 and a price of $220 if equal prices are charged the passengers are evenly shared Otherwise the low-price airline gets all the passengers The pay-off matrix is now:

See example in next page 1, If both price high then both get 30 passengers. Profit per passenger is $300. 2, If Delta prices high and American low then American gets all 180 passengers. Profit per passenger is $20. 3, Delta prices low and American high then Delta gets all 180 passengers. Profit per passenger is $20. 4, If both price low they each get 90 passengers. Profit per passenger is $20.

The example (cont.) The Pay-Off Matrix American PH = $500 PL = $220 $9000,$9000) ($0, $3600) Delta PL = $220 ($3600, $0) ($1800, $1800)

1, (PH, PL) cannot be a Nash equilibrium 1, (PH, PL) cannot be a Nash equilibrium. If American prices low then Delta should also price low. 2, (PL, PH) cannot be a Nash equilibrium. If American prices high then Delta should also price high. 3, (PH, PH) is a Nash equilibrium. If both are pricing high then neither wants to change. 4, (PL, PL) is a Nash equilibrium. If both are pricing low then neither wants to change. 5, There are two Nash equilibria to this version of the game. 6,There is no simple way to choose between these equilibria. But even so, the Nash concept has eliminated half of the outcomes as equilibria. 7, Custom and familiarity might lead both to price high. 8, Regret” might cause both to price low.

Nash Equilibrium (cont.) The Pay-Off Matrix American PH = $500 PL = $220 ($9000, $9000) ($0, $3600) PH = $500 ($9000,$9000) ($0, $3600) Delta ($3600, $0) ($1800, $1800) PL = $220 ($3600, $0) ($1800, $1800)

1, (PH, PL) cannot be a Nash equilibrium 1, (PH, PL) cannot be a Nash equilibrium. If American prices low then Delta would want to price low, too. 2, (PL, PH) cannot be a Nash equilibrium. If American prices high then Delta should also price high. 3, (PH, PH) is a Nash equilibrium. If both are pricing high then neither wants to change. 4, (PL, PL) is a Nash equilibrium. If both are pricing low then neither wants to change. 5, There are two Nash equilibria to this version of the game. 6, There is no simple way to choose between these equilibria, but at least we have eliminated half of the outcomes as possible equilibria.

Nash Equilibrium (cont.) The Pay-Off Matrix American PH = $500 PL = $220 ($9000, $9000) ($0, $3600) PH = $500 ($9000,$9000) ($0, $3600) Delta ($3600, $0) ($1800, $1800) PL = $220 ($3600, $0) ($1800, $1800)

See next page 1, Sometimes, consideration of the timing of moves can help us find the equilibrium. 2, Suppose that Delta can set its price first. 3, Delta can see that if it sets a high price, then American will do best by also pricing high. Delta earns $9000. 4, This means that PH, PL cannot be an equilibrium outcome 5, Delta can also see that if it sets a low price, American will do best by pricing low. Delta will then earn $1800. 6, This means that PL,PH cannot be an equilibrium. 7, The only sensible choice for Delta is PH knowing that American will follow with PH and each will earn $9000. So, the Nash equilibria now is (PH, PH).

Nash Equilibrium (cont.) The Pay-Off Matrix American PH = $500 PL = $220 ($3,000, $3,000) ($0, $3600) PH = $500 ($9000,$9000) ($0, $3600) Delta ($3600, $0) ($1800, $1800) ($1800, $1800) PL = $220 ($3600, $0) ($1800, $1800)

Oligopoly Models There are three dominant oligopoly models Cournot Bertrand Stackelberg They are distinguished by the decision variable that firms choose the timing of the underlying game But each embodies the Nash equilibrium concept

Demand for this product is The Cournot Model Start with a duopoly Two firms making an identical product (Cournot supposed this was spring water) Demand for this product is P = A - BQ = A - B(q1 + q2) where q1 is output of firm 1 and q2 is output of firm 2 Marginal cost for each firm is constant at c per unit To get the demand curve for one of the firms we treat the output of the other firm as constant So for firm 2, demand is P = (A - Bq1) - Bq2

The Cournot model (cont.) If the output of firm 1 is increased the demand curve for firm 2 moves to the left P = (A - Bq1) - Bq2 $ The profit-maximizing choice of output by firm 2 depends upon the output of firm 1 A - Bq1 A - Bq’1 Marginal revenue for firm 2 is Solve this for output q2 Demand c MC MR2 = (A - Bq1) - 2Bq2 MR2 MR2 = MC q*2 Quantity A - Bq1 - 2Bq2 = c  q*2 = (A - c)/2B - q1/2

The Cournot model (cont.) q*2 = (A - c)/2B - q1/2 This is the best response function( or reaction function) for firm 2 It gives firm 2’s profit-maximizing choice of output for any choice of output by firm 1 There is also a best response function for firm 1 By exactly the same argument it can be written: q*1 = (A - c)/2B - q2/2 Cournot-Nash equilibrium requires that both firms be on their best response functions.

See next page 1, The best response function for firm 1 is q*1 = (A-c)/2B - q2/2. 2, If firm 2 produces nothing then firm 1 will produce the monopoly output (A-c)/2B 3, If firm 2 produces (A-c)/B then firm 1 will choose to produce no output 4, The best response function for firm 2 is q*2 = (A-c)/2B - q1/2 5, The Cournot-Nash equilibrium is at Point C at the intersection of the best response functions

Cournot-Nash Equilibrium (A-c)/B Firm 1’s best response function (A-c)/2B C qC2 Firm 2’s best response function q1 (A-c)/2B (A-c)/B qC1

Cournot-Nash Equilibrium q*1 = (A - c)/2B - q*2/2 q2 q*2 = (A - c)/2B - q*1/2 (A-c)/B  q*2 = (A - c)/2B - (A - c)/4B + q*2/4 Firm 1’s best response function  3q*2/4 = (A - c)/4B (A-c)/2B q*2 = (A - c)/3B C (A-c)/3B q*1 = (A - c)/3B Firm 2’s best response function q1 (A-c)/2B (A-c)/B (A-c)/3B

Cournot-Nash Equilibrium (cont.) In equilibrium each firm produces qC1 = qC2 = (A - c)/3B Total output is, therefore, Q* = 2(A - c)/3B Recall that demand is P = A - BQ So the equilibrium price is P* = A - 2(A - c)/3 = (A + 2c)/3 Profit of firm 1 is (P* - c)qC1 = (A - c)2/9 Profit of firm 2 is the same A monopolist would produce QM = (A - c)/2B Competition between the firms causes their total output to exceed the monopoly output. Price is therefore lower than the monopoly price but exceeds MC. But output is less than the competitive output (A - c)/B where price equals marginal cost

Numerical Example of Cournot Duopoly Demand: P = 100 - 2Q = 100 - 2(q1 + q2); A = 100; B = 2 Unit cost: c = 10 Equilibrium total output: Q = 2(A – c)/3B = 30; Individual Firm output: q1 = q2 = 15 Equilibrium price is P* = (A + 2c)/3 = $40 Profit of firm 1 is (P* - c)qC1 = (A - c)2/9B = $450 Competition: Q* = (A – c)/B = 45; P = c = $10 Monopoly: QM = (A - c)/2B = 22.5; P = $55 Total output exceeds the monopoly output, but is less than the competitive output Price exceeds marginal cost but is less than the monopoly price

Cournot-Nash Equilibrium (cont.) What if there are more than two firms? Much the same approach. Say that there are N identical firms producing identical products Total output Q = q1 + q2 + … + qN Demand is P = A - BQ = A - B(q1 + q2 + … + qN) Consider firm 1. It’s demand curve can be written: P = A - B(q2 + … + qN) - Bq1 Use a simplifying notation: Q-1= q2 + q3 + … + qN. This denotes output of every firm other than firm 1 So demand for firm 1 is P = (A - BQ-1) - Bq1

The Cournot model (cont.) If the output of the other firms is increased the demand curve for firm 1 moves to the left P = (A - BQ-1) - Bq1 $ The profit-maximizing choice of output by firm 1 depends upon the output of the other firms A - BQ-1 A - BQ’-1 Marginal revenue for firm 1 is Demand c MC MR1 = (A - BQ-1) - 2Bq1 MR1 MR1 = MC q*1 Quantity A - BQ-1 - 2Bq1 = c  q*1 = (A - c)/2B - Q-1/2

Cournot-Nash Equilibrium How do we solve this for q*1? q*1 = (A - c)/2B - Q-1/2 The firms are identical, So in equilibrium they will have identical outputs  Q*-1 = (N - 1)q*1  q*1 = (A - c)/2B - (N - 1)q*1/2  (1 + (N - 1)/2)q*1 = (A - c)/2B  q*1(N + 1)/2 = (A - c)/2B  q*1 = (A - c)/(N + 1)B  Q* = N(A - c)/(N + 1)B  P* = A - BQ* = (A + Nc)/(N + 1) = (A - c)2/(N + 1)2B Profit of firm 1 is P*1 = (P* - c)q*1

3, As the number of firms increases price tends to marginal cost Related with previous page 1, From q*1 , we know as the number of firms increases output of each firm falls 2, From Q*, we know as the number of firms increases aggregate output increases 3, As the number of firms increases price tends to marginal cost 4, As the number of firms increases profit of each firm falls.

Cournot-Nash equilibrium (cont.) What if the firms do not have identical costs? Once again, much the same analysis can be used Assume that marginal costs of firm 1 are c1 and of firm 2 are c2. Demand is P = A - BQ = A - B(q1 + q2) We have marginal revenue for firm 1 as before MR1 = (A - Bq2) - 2Bq1 Equate to marginal cost: (A - Bq2) - 2Bq1 = c1 Solve this for output q1  q*1 = (A - c1)/2B - q2/2 A symmetric result holds for output of firm 2  q*2 = (A - c2)/2B - q1/2

Cournot-Nash Equilibrium 3, The equilibrium output of firm 2 increases and of firm 1 falls 2, As the marginal cost of firm 2 falls its best response curve shifts to the right Cournot-Nash Equilibrium q*1 = (A - c1)/2B - q*2/2 q2 q*2 = (A - c2)/2B - q*1/2 (A-c1)/B R1  q*2 = (A - c2)/2B - (A - c1)/4B + q*2/4  3q*2/4 = (A - 2c2 + c1)/4B (A-c2)/2B  q*2 = (A - 2c2 + c1)/3B C R2  q*1 = (A - 2c1 + c2)/3B q1 1, What happens to this equilibrium when costs change? (A-c1)/2B (A-c2)/B

Cournot-Nash Equilibrium (cont.) In equilibrium the firms produce qC1 = (A - 2c1 + c2)/3B; qC2 = (A - 2c2 + c1)/3B Total output is, therefore, Q* = (2A - c1 - c2)/3B Recall that demand is P = A - BQ So price is P* = A - (2A - c1 - c2)/3 = (A + c1 +c2)/3 Profit of firm 1 is (P* - c1)qC1 = (A - 2c1 + c2)2/9B Profit of firm 2 is (P* - c2)qC2 = (A - 2c2 + c1)2/9B Equilibrium output is less than the competitive level Output is produced inefficiently: the low-cost firm should produce all the output

A Numerical Example with Different Costs Let demand be given by: P = 100 – 2Q; A = 100, B =2 Let c1 = 5 and c2 = 15 Total output is, Q* = (2A - c1 - c2)/3B = (200 – 5 – 15)/6 = 30 qC1 = (A - 2c1 + c2)/3B = (100 – 10 + 15)/6 = 17.5 qC2 = (A - 2c2 + c1)/3B = (100 – 30 + 5)/3B = 12.5 Price is P* = (A + c1 +c2)/3 = (100 + 5 + 15)/3 = 40 Profit of firm 1 is (A - 2c1 + c2)2/9B =(100 – 10 +5)2/18 = $612.5 Profit of firm 2 is (A - 2c2 + c1)2/9B = $312.5 Producers would be better off and consumers no worse off if firm 2’s 12.5 units were instead produced by firm 1

Concentration and Profitability Assume that we have N firms with different marginal costs We can use the N-firm analysis with a simple change Recall that demand for firm 1 is P = (A - BQ-1) - Bq1 But then demand for firm i is P = (A - BQ-i) - Bqi Equate this to marginal cost ci A - BQ-i - 2Bqi = ci This can be reorganized to give the equilibrium condition: A - B(Q*-i + q*i) - Bq*i - ci = 0 But Q*-i + q*i = Q* and A - BQ* = P*  P* - ci = Bq*i  P* - Bq*i - ci = 0

Concentration and profitability (cont.) P* - ci = Bq*i 1, The price-cost margin for each firm is determined by its own market share and overall market demand elasticity Divide by P* and multiply the right-hand side by Q*/Q* P* - ci BQ* q*i = P* P* Q* But BQ*/P* = 1/ and q*i/Q* = si P* - ci si so: =  P* 2, The verage price-cost margin is determined by industry concentration as measured by the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index Extending this we have P* - c H = P* 