© Suzanne Scotchmer 2007 Contents May Be Used Pursuant to Creative Commons Attribution-NoDerivs-NonCommercial Common Deed 1.0Attribution-NoDerivs-NonCommercial.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Monopoly.
Advertisements

Equilibrium, Profits, and Adjustment in a Competitive Market Chapter 8 J. F. O’Connor.
12 Prepared by: Fernando Quijano and Yvonn Quijano © 2004 Prentice Hall Business PublishingPrinciples of Economics, 7/eKarl Case, Ray Fair Monopoly.
Roger LeRoy Miller © 2012 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Economics Today, Sixteenth Edition Chapter 24: Monopoly.
Incentives and the Innovative Environment Suzanne Scotchmer ESNIE, Cargèse, May 2007 references: Chs 2, 8 Innovation and Incentives (MIT Press, 2005)
Understanding Monopoly 10. Natural Barriers to Entry Economies of scale –“Bigger is better” (more cost-efficient) –This is due to the ATC being downward-
© Suzanne Scotchmer 09/14/2004 Contents May Be Used Pursuant to Creative Commons Attribution-NoDerivs-NonCommercial Common Deed R&D: How much, by whom?
Ch. 12: Monopoly Causes of monopoly
Chapter 9 – Profit maximization
15 Monopoly.
Introduction A monopoly is a firm that is the sole seller of a product without close substitutes. In this chapter, we study monopoly and contrast it with.
Monopoly - Characteristics
Departures from perfect competition
Ch. 12: Monopoly  Causes of monopoly  Monopoly pricing and output determination  Performance and efficiency of single-price monopoly and competition.
© Suzanne Scotchmer 10/14/2004 Contents May Be Used Pursuant to Creative Commons Attribution-NoDerivs-NonCommercial Common Deed 1.0Attribution-NoDerivs-NonCommercial.
© Suzanne Scotchmer 09/14/2004 Contents May Be Used Pursuant to Creative Commons Attribution-NoDerivs-NonCommercial Common Deed 1.0Attribution-NoDerivs-NonCommercial.
© Suzanne Scotchmer 2010 from Innovation and Incentives MIT Press 2004 Review: The (Public Goods) Nature of Knowledge & Information Goods Longitude Example:
© Suzanne Scotchmer 2007 Contents May Be Used Pursuant to Creative Commons Attribution-NoDerivs-NonCommercial Common Deed 1.0 Attribution-NoDerivs-NonCommercial.
Monopoly Monopoly and perfect competition. Profit maximization by a monopolist. Inefficiency of a monopoly. Why do monopolies occur? Natural Monopolies.
© Suzanne Scotchmer 09/07/2004 Contents May Be Used Pursuant to Creative Commons Attribution-NoDerivs-NonCommercial Common Deed 1.0Attribution-NoDerivs-NonCommercial.
ECON 101 Tutorial: Week 7 Shane Murphy Office Hours: Monday 3:00-4:00 – LUMS C85.
The Production Decision of a Monopoly Firm Alternative market structures: perfect competition monopolistic competition oligopoly monopoly.
1 Strategic Investment and Non-Price Competition.
Imperfect Competition and Market Power: Core Concepts Defining Industry Boundaries Barriers to Entry Price: The Fourth Decision Variable Price and Output.
Types of Market Structure
Changes in Demand and Market Processes. Profits and Avocadoes Firms will grow avocadoes only if they can make a profit To make a profit, price must cover.
 Firm that is sole seller of product without close substitutes  Price Maker not a Price Taker  There are barriers to entry thru: Monopoly Resources,
Comparing Equilibrium situations for Monopoly and perfect Competition.
Price Discrimination Price discrimination is the practice of selling different units of a good or service for different prices. To be able to price discriminate,
1 Economics of Innovation Innovation and market structure: Introduction Manuel Trajtenberg.
UBEA 1013: ECONOMICS 1 CHAPTER 6: MARKET STRUCTURE: MONOPOLY 6.1 Characteristic 6.2 Short-run Decision: Profit Maximization 6.3 Short-run Decision: Minimizing.
1 Monopoly and Antitrust Policy Chapter IMPERFECT COMPETITION AND MARKET POWER imperfectly competitive industry An industry in which single firms.
Eco 6351 Economics for Managers Chapter 7. Monopoly Prof. Vera Adamchik.
General Equilibrium and the Efficiency of Perfect Competition
Chapter 22 Microeconomics Unit III: The Theory of the Firm.
Digital Rights Management and the Pricing of Digital Products Yooki Park and Suzanne Scotchmer Workshop on the Economics of Information Security KSG, Cambridge,
© Suzanne Scotchmer 2007 from Innovation and Incentives Licensing Some Terms: Exclusive Exclusive licensing versus exclusive dealing Royalties versus Fixed.
Roadmap: Chapter 14 provided a theory of competitive markets. One important feature: Firms are price takers. Chapter 15 deals with... Monopoly: a firm.
Cap and Trade: The Technology Adoption Problem May 4, 2009 Economic Games and Mechanisms to Address Climate Change Suzanne Scotchmer University of California.
Chapter Firms in Competitive Markets 13. What is a Competitive Market? The meaning of competition Competitive market – Market with many buyers and sellers.
PowerPoint Slides prepared by: Andreea CHIRITESCU Eastern Illinois University Monopoly 1 © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied,
1 Monopoly. 2 Monopoly- assumptions  One seller  Many buyers  Entry and exit into the market: very difficult or prohibited  Monopolist usually produce.
Unit 4, Lesson 10 Competition AOF Business Economics Copyright © 2008–2011 National Academy Foundation. All rights reserved.
1. Introduction to Price Fixing: Legal and Economic Foundations Antitrust Law Fall 2015 NYU School of Law Dale Collins SLIDES FOR CLASS.
1. Introduction to Price Fixing: Legal and Economic Foundations Antitrust Law Fall 2014 Yale Law School Dale Collins MORE SLIDES FOR CLASS.
© Suzanne Scotchmer Contents May Be Used Pursuant to Creative Commons Attribution-NoDerivs-NonCommercial Common Deed 1.0 Attribution-NoDerivs-NonCommercial.
PPA 723: Managerial Economics Lecture 15: Monopoly The Maxwell School, Syracuse University Professor John Yinger.
MONPOLY. CONDITIONS One Firm High barriers of entry No close substitutes for good the monopoly firm produces.
Monopoly & Efficiency Deadweight Loss Analysis. Allocative Efficiency Total Welfare is maximized only when MC = MB for society –Since MB = Price => only.
© Suzanne Scotchmer 2007 from Innovation and Incentives MIT Press 2004 The (Public Goods) Nature of Knowledge & Information Goods Longitude Example: What.
Market Failure. Occurs when free market forces, using the price mechanism, fail to produce the products that people want, in the quantities they desire.
Chapter Monopoly 15. In economic terms, why are monopolies bad? Explain. 2.
© Suzanne Scotchmer 2007 from Innovation and Incentives MIT Press 2004 The (Public Goods) Nature of Knowledge & Information Goods Longitude Example: What.
Monopoly 1. Why Monopolies Arise Monopoly –Firm that is the sole seller of a product without close substitutes –Price maker Barriers to entry –Monopoly.
Monopoly 15. Monopoly A firm is considered a monopoly if... it is the sole seller of its product. it is the sole seller of its product. its product does.
I. A Simple Model. Players: Sellers, I and E, and a consumer Period 1: Seller I and the buyer can make an exclusive contract. Period 2: Seller E decides.
Comparing Equilibrium situations for Monopoly and perfect Competition.
Chapter 16: Government Regulation of Business
Government Regulation of Business
Monopoly versus Perfect Competition
Chapter 16 Government Regulation of Business
Monopoly © 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a.
ECN 201: Principles of Microeconomics
Ch. 13: Monopoly Causes of monopoly
Monopoly © 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a.
Monopoly © 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a.
Market Structures I: Monopoly
Announcements Midterm results posted next week
Chapter 16: Government Regulation of Business
Deadweight Loss Analysis
Presentation transcript:

© Suzanne Scotchmer 2007 Contents May Be Used Pursuant to Creative Commons Attribution-NoDerivs-NonCommercial Common Deed 1.0Attribution-NoDerivs-NonCommercial Common Deed 1.0 Design of IP Two questions: (1) How large should the rewards to innovation be? (2)How should the reward be structured? How large? –When ideas are scarce (no patent race) –When ideas are common knowledge (patent race) Structure: Mainly about length and breadth of the right.

© Suzanne Scotchmer 2007 Contents May Be Used Pursuant to Creative Commons Attribution-NoDerivs-NonCommercial Common Deed 1.0Attribution-NoDerivs-NonCommercial Common Deed 1.0 Size of the reward (e.g., patent life) Two arguments. a) Nordhaus (scarce ideas) and b) race (# of firms) Nordhaus: Implicitly focuses on single inventors with scarce ideas. Tradeoff is between “too few innovations” and “too much deadweight loss.” The number of innovations can always be increased by increasing the patent value, but it increases deadweight loss on every inframarginal innovation. Race: Arises where ideas are not scarce. The problem is to avoid over-entry or under-rewards

© Suzanne Scotchmer 2007 Contents May Be Used Pursuant to Creative Commons Attribution-NoDerivs-NonCommercial Common Deed 1.0Attribution-NoDerivs-NonCommercial Common Deed 1.0 Optimal reward when Ideas are Scarce A higher reward (patent life T) increases deadweight loss. (This diagram is illustrative; know the idea, not the diagram.)  (v a,, c a ) value,v  (v b,, c b ) cost,c space of ideas (v,c) v  T’ vTvT

© Suzanne Scotchmer 2007 Contents May Be Used Pursuant to Creative Commons Attribution-NoDerivs-NonCommercial Common Deed 1.0Attribution-NoDerivs-NonCommercial Common Deed 1.0 Optimal reward when ideas are common knowledge A high reward may lead to a profit-dissipating race. Racing can be inefficient. –Duplication of effort. –Pursuit of wrong ideas. Is a race beneficial for society? –May duplicate costs (bad) –May increase the probability of success or the time of discovery (good). We cannot know whether a patent race is good or bad without knowing how innovation works. We need the right model of the creative environment.

© Suzanne Scotchmer 2007 Contents May Be Used Pursuant to Creative Commons Attribution-NoDerivs-NonCommercial Common Deed 1.0Attribution-NoDerivs-NonCommercial Common Deed 1.0 Races “Duplication” is not well defined. A simple patent race: Suppose the social value of discovery is S. Suppose each firm has an independent probability p of failure. Let P(n) be the probability that at least one of n firms succeeds. P(1) = (1-p), P(2) = (1-p 2 ), P(3) = (1-p 3 ), P(n) = (1-p n ) (increasing) The expected social value of the investment (ignoring costs) with one firm: S P(1) =S(1-p). with two firms: S P(2) =S(1-p 2 ). with three firms: S P(3) =S(1-p 3 ) with n firms: S P(n) =S(1-p n ) The marginal social value contributed by the first firm: S(1-p). the second firm: S(p-p 2 ). the third firm: S(p 2 -p 3 ) the n th firm: S(p n-1 -p n ) (becomes close to zero)

© Suzanne Scotchmer 2007 Contents May Be Used Pursuant to Creative Commons Attribution-NoDerivs-NonCommercial Common Deed 1.0Attribution-NoDerivs-NonCommercial Common Deed 1.0 Races continued Now take account of costs. Suppose that the winner of the patent race gets the entire social value, S. Should the private reward be less than S? (Yes, why?) S P(n) S P(n) number of firms n free entry outcome if winner receives the whole social value nene n*n* optimal cn

© Suzanne Scotchmer 2007 Contents May Be Used Pursuant to Creative Commons Attribution-NoDerivs-NonCommercial Common Deed 1.0Attribution-NoDerivs-NonCommercial Common Deed 1.0 Races continued Modify diagram to account for the fact that the winner receives less than the whole social value. Reduces number of entrants, possibly to the efficient number. S x P(n) number of firms n free entry outcome if winner receives  instead of S nene n*n* cn  x P(n) Tandon 1983

© Suzanne Scotchmer 2007 Contents May Be Used Pursuant to Creative Commons Attribution-NoDerivs-NonCommercial Common Deed 1.0Attribution-NoDerivs-NonCommercial Common Deed 1.0 What have we learned here? There are two reasons that the reward should be less than the social value of the innovation: If the reward is given as a patent, the patent involves deadweight loss. We should be willing to forego some high-cost innovations in order to reduce DWL on innovations we will get in any case. Cost duplication. Giving the entire social value will lead to a profit-dissipating race, which also dissipates social value by wasting resources.

© Suzanne Scotchmer 2007 Contents May Be Used Pursuant to Creative Commons Attribution-NoDerivs-NonCommercial Common Deed 1.0Attribution-NoDerivs-NonCommercial Common Deed 1.0 Size versus Structure of the reward So far we have mainly been discussing the optimal size of the reward, however it is given. But the reward can also be structured in different ways. Two important policy levers for intellectual property: Length T Breadth: –Oncomouse. What about an oncowalrus? –Amazon’s one-click patent.

© Suzanne Scotchmer 2007 Contents May Be Used Pursuant to Creative Commons Attribution-NoDerivs-NonCommercial Common Deed 1.0Attribution-NoDerivs-NonCommercial Common Deed 1.0 Breadth: Three Definitions Breadth excludes horizontal substitutes –Define breadth on the product side Breadth defines cost of entry –Define breadth on the technology side Breadth excludes vertical substitutes –Defined for sequential innovation (later lecture)

© Suzanne Scotchmer 2007 Contents May Be Used Pursuant to Creative Commons Attribution-NoDerivs-NonCommercial Common Deed 1.0Attribution-NoDerivs-NonCommercial Common Deed 1.0 Breadth & Horizontal Competition A higher price increases demand of substitute goods. ) ˆ,( 211 ppx ) ~,( 211 ppx 2 ˆ p mcp  2 ~ 1 ~ p 1 ˆ p ) ˆ,( 122 ppx  ˆ  ~ substitute good, x 2 ) ~,( 122 ppx 1 1  ˆ 2 proprietary good, x 1

© Suzanne Scotchmer 2007 Contents May Be Used Pursuant to Creative Commons Attribution-NoDerivs-NonCommercial Common Deed 1.0Attribution-NoDerivs-NonCommercial Common Deed 1.0 Breadth & Cost of Entry, K The number of entrants, n(K), depends on the cost of entry, K. If K decreases, the number of entrants n(K) increases. If K decreases, the price p(K) decreases. If K is 0 (free entry), “infinitely” many firms enter. The price becomes competitive, p=MC=0. Demand x(p ) Monopoly price P c =MC=0 P(n(K)) Price falls with the number of entrants, n price p

© Suzanne Scotchmer 2007 Contents May Be Used Pursuant to Creative Commons Attribution-NoDerivs-NonCommercial Common Deed 1.0Attribution-NoDerivs-NonCommercial Common Deed 1.0 We can use this apparatus to ask whether patents should be narrow or broad. The “breadth” is represented by K. High K means that entrants must “invent around” the patent. Keeping the patent life, T, fixed, what happens to the inventor’s incentives if the patent is narrower (K is smaller)? To phrase the question sensibly -- how should patents be structured – something should be kept fixed. Holding total profit fixed, should patents be long and narrow? Short and broad?

© Suzanne Scotchmer 2007 Contents May Be Used Pursuant to Creative Commons Attribution-NoDerivs-NonCommercial Common Deed 1.0Attribution-NoDerivs-NonCommercial Common Deed 1.0 The ratio test: Should breadth cause price to be lower, and the IP right to last longer? The consumer cost of raising money through monopoly pricing is deadweight loss. Goal: Maximize ratio of profit to deadweight loss. p x(p)x(p) p*p* x(p*)x(p*) p p x(p)x(p) p*p* x(p*)x(p*) p ~~ ~ ~