Chapter 7 General Equilibrium and Market Efficiency

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
13. Production Varian, Chapter 31.
Advertisements

General Equilibrium (Welfare Economics). General Equilibrium u Partial Equilibrium: Neglects the way in which changes in one market affect other (product/factor)
TOOLS OF NORMATIVE ANALYSIS
Chapter 16. GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM AND MARKET EFFICIENCY McGraw-Hill/IrwinCopyright © 2011 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Chapter.
Equity, Efficiency and Need
Demystifying Efficiency in the Economics Classroom David A. Anderson Centre College.
General Equilibrium Analysis
1 Chapter 3 – Tools of Normative Analysis Public Finance McGraw-Hill/Irwin © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., All Rights Reserved.
General Equilibrium Theory
General Equilibrium and Efficiency. General Equilibrium Analysis is the study of the simultaneous determination of prices and quantities in all relevant.
12. General equilibrium: An exchange economy
Fernando & Yvonn Quijano Prepared by: General Equilibrium and Economic Efficiency 16 C H A P T E R Copyright © 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing.
Microeconomics General equilibrium Institute of Economic Theories - University of Miskolc Mónika Kis-Orloczki Assistant lecturer.
MICROECONOMICS: Theory & Applications Chapter 19 General Equilibrium Analysis and Economic Efficiency By Edgar K. Browning & Mark A. Zupan John Wiley.
Neoclassical Revival 1920s and “Empty Economic Boxes” debate Developments in the 1930s –Demand Theory –Theory of Production and Cost –Welfare Economics.
Chapter 5 A Closed- Economy One-Period Macroeconomic Model Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education Canada.
© 2008 Pearson Addison Wesley. All rights reserved Review Perfect Competition Market.
1 General Equilibrium APEC 3001 Summer 2006 Readings: Chapter 16.
Chapter 12 © 2006 Thomson Learning/South-Western General Equilibrium and Welfare.
Assoc. Prof. Y.KuştepeliECN 242 PUBLIC ECONOMICS1 TOOLS OF NORMATIVE ANALYSIS.
Externalities © Allen C. Goodman 2009 Ideal Market Processes are desirable if … We accept the value judgment that “personal wants of individuals should.
UNIT II:Firms & Markets Theory of the Firm Profit Maximization Perfect Competition Review 7/15 MIDTERM 7/6.
General Equilibrium and Market Efficiency Production Economy.
PUBLIC SECTOR ECONOMICS
Microeconomics and Corporate Analysis State Intervention, Public choice and Economic Regulation Lecture Slides Rui Baptista.
© 2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc Chapter 13 Competitive General Equilibrium.
1. The Market Economy Fall Outline A. Introduction: What is Efficiency? B. Supply and Demand (1 Market) C. Efficiency of Consumption (Many Markets)
Chapter 32 Production We now add production into the economy. Two goods: foods and clothes (F and C). Two inputs: L and K. Two firms: one producing F and.
1 of 22 General Equilibrium and the Efficiency of Perfect Competition General Equilibrium Analysis Allocative Efficiency and Competitive Equilibrium The.
Unit 16 – General equilibrium analysis and Economic efficiency.
General Equilibrium and Economic Welfare
CHAPTER 12 General Equilibrium and the Efficiency of Perfect Competition © 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Principles of Economics.
General Equilibrium and Market Efficiency
Chapter 5: Market Failure: A Role for Government
1 Chapter 10: General Equilibrium So far, we have studied a partial equilibrium analysis, which determines the equilibrium price and quantities in one.
 General Equilibrium and Welfare.  Partial vs. General equilibrium analysis  Partial Equilibrium: narrow focus  General equilibrium: framework of.
General Equilibrium and the Efficiency of Perfect Competition
Consumer Behavior & Public Policy Lecture #3 Microeconomics.
Overview Efficiency Efficiency and competitive markets Efficiency in exchange Efficiency in production.
Chapter Thirty-Two Production. Exchange Economies (revisited)  No production, only endowments, so no description of how resources are converted to consumables.
#1 What is Production? Production is the process by which resources are transformed into useful forms. Resources, or inputs, refer to anything provided.
Modeling Market Failure Chapter 3 © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western.
Microeconomics Course E John Hey. An overview...of the first two parts of the course......of the most important points.
Chapter 16 General Equilibrium, Efficiency, and Equity McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved.
Chapter 16 General Equilibrium, Efficiency, and Equity Copyright © 2014 McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. No reproduction or distribution without.
1 Chapters 6 & 19.1 & 19.2: Exchange Efficiency, and Prices.
Lecture 8 Profit Maximization. Comparison of consumer theory with producer theory In consumer theory we learned that the main objective of consumer is.
Chapter 18W McGraw-Hill/IrwinCopyright © 2010 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
CHAPTER 31 PRODUCTION. The Robinson Crusoe Economy One consumer and one firm; The consumer owns the firm; Preference: over leisure and coconuts; Technology:
General Equilibrium Theory
Market Failure Diagrams.  Learning Objective:  To understand how to illustrate market failure with diagrams  Learning Outcome / Success Criteria 
Chapter 16 General Equilibrium. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc.Chapter 162 General Equilibrium Analysis To study how markets interrelate, we can use general.
Markets, Maximizers and Efficiency
Market Failure Chapter 14 Externalities. Economic Freedom Economic freedom refers to the degree to which private individuals are able to carry out voluntary.
General equilibrium & welfareslide 1 General Equilibrium & Welfare How should society organize the production and distribution of goods if the objective.
MICROECONOMICS: Theory & Applications By Edgar K. Browning & Mark A. Zupan John Wiley & Sons, Inc. 11 th Edition, Copyright 2012 PowerPoint prepared by.
EC PUBLIC SECTOR ECONOMICS 1 TOOLS OF NORMATIVE ANALYSIS Prof.Dr. Y.Kuştepeli.
Slide 1Copyright © 2004 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited Chapter 16 General Equilibrium and Market Efficiency.
Chapter 32 Production. Exchange Economies (revisited) No production, only endowments, so no description of how resources are converted to consumables.
1 Production. 2 Exchange Economies (revisited) No production, only endowments, so no description of how resources are converted to consumables. General.
Chapter 7: Competitive General Equilibrium Decentralization markets are promoting the economic prosperity more effectively than state planning or intervention.
Exchange Chapter 31 Niklas Jakobsson Click to add notes.
General Equilibrium Analysis
TOOLS OF NORMATIVE ANALYSIS
Efficiency and Equity in a Competitive Market
Eco 3311 Lecture 12 One Period Closed Economy Model - Equilibrium
Chapter 3 - Tools of Normative Analysis
General Equilibrium, Efficiency, and Equity
Overview Efficiency Efficiency and competitive markets
CHAPTER 16 OUTLINE 16.1 General Equilibrium Analysis
Presentation transcript:

Chapter 7 General Equilibrium and Market Efficiency

Outline. A simple exchange economy Efficiency in production Efficiency in product mix Sources of inefficiency

A simple exchange economy Consider a simple economy in which there are only two consumers A (Ann) and B (Bill) and two goods: food and clothing. Available quantities of goods are exogenous: Food = 100 Clothing = 200 An allocation is an assignment of these quantities between A and B. The amounts of goods with which A and B start each period are called their initial endowments.

Personal bargaining What do A and B do with their initial endowments? They may either consume what they already have or to engage in exchange one with the other. Exchange is purely voluntary so it only takes place if it is beneficial to both parties Exchange makes someone better off if it places him on a higher indifference curve

The Edgeworth Box

Improving utility through exchange

Further improving utility through exchange

Reaching a Pareto-optimal allocation

The Contract Curve

From initial endowments to the contract curve

Market economies In our very simple example, exchange took place through personal bargaining. In market economies, most exchanges have a more impersonal character. People have given endowments and they face given prices. They then decide how many goods and services they want to buy and sell. We can introduce market-type exchanges by assuming that there exists a third (fictive) person playing the role of an auctioneer.

Exchanges in a market economy

General equilibrium in a market economy

The first theorem of welfare economics It is also called the theorem of the Invisible Hand. It can be stated as follows: an equilibrium produced by competitive markets will exhaust all possible gains from exchange. Another way to put it is that equilibrium in competitive markets is Pareto optimal: competitive equilibrium is efficient

The second theorem of welfare economics It states that any allocation on the contract curve can be sustained as a competitive equilibrium. The basic condition that assures this result is that consumer indifference curves be convex when viewed from the origin. Why not redistribute initial endowments in order to achieve the desired outcome directly? Lack of information on consumers' indifference curves Consequence of the theorem: the issue of equity in distribution is logically separable from the issue of efficiency in allocation

Decentralisation of the optimum

Outline. Efficiency in production Efficiency in product mix Sources of inefficiency

Efficiency in production The product mix in an economy is the result of the allocation of productive inputs Suppose we add a productive sector to our exchange economy. It consists of 2 firms, each of them using capital K and labour L. Firm C produces clothing and firm F produces food. Suppose the total quantities of the 2 inputs are fixed with K = 50 and L = 100. The production processes used by the 2 firms give rise to conventional convex-shaped isoquants.

The Edgeworth production box

The efficiency of general equilibrium If firms maximise their profits, the resulting general equilibrium will satisfy the requirements of efficiency in production Suppose that food and clothing prices are P*F and P*C. Suppose that firms hire labour and capital on perfectly competitive markets at hourly rates w and r. If both firms minimise costs we have: Given that the price of inputs is the same for both firms, this yields

Outline. Efficiency in product mix Sources of inefficiency

Efficiency in production mix An economy may be efficient in production and, at the same time do a very poor job in satisfying the wants of its members So, there is one more efficiency criterion of concern which is whether the economy has an efficient mix of the two products To define the efficient product mix, it is useful to translate the contract curve from the Edgeworth production box into a production possibilities frontier Definition: this is the set of all possible output combinations that can be produced with given quantities of capital and labour.

The marginal rate of transformation The slope of the production possibilities frontier at any point is called the marginal rate of transformation (MRT) It measures the opportunity cost of clothing in terms of food. For the economy we consider, the MRT increases when we move to the right. This is always the case as long as there are constant or decreasing returns to scale.

Efficiency in product mix In order for an economy to be efficient in terms of production mix, the MRS for each consumer has to be equal to the MRT

General equilibrium and efficiency in product mix Let P*F and P*C denote the equilibrium prices for food and clothing. As we have seen for the simple exchange economy, in equilibrium, the MRS of every consumer will be equal to the ratio of these prices P*C / P*F. In order to show that the general equilibrium is efficient, we need to show that the MRT is also equal to P*C / P*F

Demonstration Let’s show that at any point on the production possibilities frontier he MRT is equal to the ratio of the marginal cost of clothing (MCC) to the marginal cost of food (MCF). The MRT is given by: It is the amount of food you have to give up in order to get one more unit of clothing. In order to produce one more unit of clothing, we need to use a bundle of inputs the value of which is MCC.

Demonstration (ctd1) In order to get that bundle of input, we need to produce less food. For each unit of food we give up, we get an input bundle which is worth MCF. So, in order to get an input bundle worth 1, we need to give up 1/ MCF units of food In order to get an input bundle worth MCC, we need to give up MCC / MCF units of food. So,

Demonstration (ctd2) The equilibrium condition for food and clothing producers is that product prices be equal to the corresponding marginal costs. P*F = MCF and P*C = MCC So, So, an economy in competitive general equilibrium is simultaneously efficient (i.e. Pareto optimal) in consumption, production and in the choice of product mix.

Outline. Sources of inefficiency

Taxes in general equilibrium

Taxes and inefficiency in the product mix Even with the tax on food, consumers have a common value of MRS in equilibrium and that producers have a common value of MRTS. So, the economy is efficient in consumption and production. The tax causes producers to see a different price ratio from the one seen by consumers: consumption decisions are based on gross prices whereas production decisions are guided by net prices. So, the MRS and MRT can never be equal in equilibrium. So, the tax leads to an inefficient production mix.

Minimising Distorsions Subsidies, like taxes upset the conditions required for efficiency The tax system has to be designed in order to minimise distorsions Taxing food and clothing at the same rate t. But in general, comodity taxes will have distortionary effects Lump-sum taxes But generate equity problems The best tax: tax levied on activities of which there would otherwise be too much

Externalities Another source of inefficiency occurs when production or consumption activities involve benefits or costs for people not directly involved in them. Such benefits and costs are called externalities Example of negative externality: pollution Example of positive externality: flowers Externalities create a problem very similar to taxes: they cause producers and consumers to react to a different set of relative prices .

Externalities (ctd) Solution Tax negative externalities Subsidise positive externalities The existence of externalities is a good example of market failure It is a case in which the outcome generated by the working of the market is no optimal. This sets the ground for public intervention in the economy.

Public goods Pure public goods have 2 characteristics They are non-rival: the fact that one person uses the good does not reduce the amount of good that can be used by another person. Example: radio or TV programs, national defence. They are non-excludable: it is impossible to exclude somebody who does not pay from using the good. Example: TV programs before cable TV, radio programs, national defence There is no reason to presume that private markets will supply optimal quantities of pure public goods

Public goods (ctd) The problem is less acute with goods that are non-rival but excludable. Example: cable TV. It is possible to exclude people from watching programs they do not pay for. But even here there are likely to be inefficiencies: Once a TV program has been produced, it costs society nothing to let an extra person see it. Here again, these market failures set the ground for public intervention in the economy.