Capital Structure Decision-Making with Growth: An Instructional Class Exercise Professor Robert M. Hull Clarence W. King Endowed Chair in Finance School.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Capital Structure Decisions Chapter 15 and 16
Advertisements

Optimal Capital Structure under Corporate and Personal Taxation Harry DeANGELO University of Washington Ronald W. MASULIS University of California Securities.
Session 9 Topics to be covered: –Debt Policy –Capital Structure –Modigliani-Miller Propositions.
Last Lecture.. Cost of Equity Cost of Preferred Stock Cost of Debt
McGraw-Hill © 2004 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Leverage and Capital Structure Chapter 13.
Financial Leverage and Capital Structure Policy
Chapter 8 Cost of Capital
Firm Valuation: A Summary
Financial Analysis, Planning and Forecasting Theory and Application By Alice C. Lee San Francisco State University John C. Lee J.P. Morgan Chase Cheng.
A Teaching Application for Assessing the Impact of Debt Professor Robert M. Hull and Daniel McNulty Beatrice Presentation: March 2007.
Goal of the Lecture: Understand how to determine the proper mix of debt and equity to use to fund corporate investments.
Valuation and Rates of Return
Capital Structure Decision
P.V. VISWANATH FOR A FIRST COURSE IN FINANCE 1. 2 Corporations pay taxes on their profits after interest payments are deducted. Thus, interest expense.
Valuing Securities.
Objectives Understand the basic concept and sources of capital associated with the cost of capital. Explain what is meant by the marginal cost of capital.
Chapter 9 An Introduction to Security Valuation. 2 The Investment Decision Process Determine the required rate of return Evaluate the investment to determine.
Risk, Return and Capital Budgeting For 9.220, Term 1, 2002/03 02_Lecture15.ppt Student Version.
Capital Structure (Ch. 12)
© 2003 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Cost of Capital Chapter Fourteen.
How Much Does It Cost to Raise Capital? Or How Much Return Do Security-Holders Require a Company to Offer to Buy Its Securities? Lecture: 5 - Capital Cost.
Chapter 7 Valuation Concepts © 2005 Thomson/South-Western.
Theory of Valuation The value of an asset is the present value of its expected cash flows You expect an asset to provide a stream of cash flows while you.
Investment Analysis Lecture: 21 Course Code: MBF702.
Why Cost of Capital Is Important
Hospitality Financial Management By Robert E. Chatfield and Michael C. Dalbor ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Pearson Prentice Hall Upper Saddle River, NJ.
FINANCE IN A CANADIAN SETTING Sixth Canadian Edition Lusztig, Cleary, Schwab.
FIN 819 The Capital Structure Some classic arguments.
12-1 CHAPTER 14 Capital Structure and Leverage Leverage and risk Optimal capital structure Compare profit, return and risk for leverage and un-leveraged.
An Introduction to Security Valuation
Chapter 14 Berk and DeMarzo
Chapter 9 The Cost of Capital.
Capital Budgeting and Financial Planning
Capital Structure.
Capital Structure Decisions
Beatrice Presentation February 22, 2005 Robert M. Hull, Beatrice Professor Summer 2005 School of Business, Washburn University, 1700 SW College Avenue,
Cost of Capital MF 807 Corporate Finance Professor Thomas Chemmanur.
Cost of capital. What types of long-term capital do firms use? Long-term debt Preferred stock Common equity Term loans Retained earnings.
Advanced Project Evaluation
Chapter McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Valuation and Rates of Return 10.
VALUATION AND FINANCING
Chapter McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Cost of Capital 11.
Capital Structure and Valuation Example.
Chapter McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Valuation and Rates of Return 10.
Copyright © 2009 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved. Chapter 10 The Cost of Capital.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Corporate Finance, 7/e © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved CHAPTER 17 Capital Budgeting for the Levered.
Financial Leverage and Capital Structure Policy
Lecture 9 Discounting and Valuation. The investment guru Financial Markets and Corporate Strategy, David Hillier Average rate of return on investments.
1 Finance School of Management FINANCE Review of Questions and Problems Part V: Chapter 16 & 17.
1. 2 Learning Outcomes Chapter 11 Compute the component cost of capital for (a) debt, (b) preferred stock, (c) retained earnings, and (d) new common equity.
Capital Structure. Effect of Corporate Taxes So far capital structure was irrelevant. What if we introduces corporate taxes? Corporate taxes are paid after.
Chapter 6 Frameworks for Valuation: Adjusted Present Value (APV) Instructors: Please do not post raw PowerPoint files on public website. Thank you! 1.
Chapter 7 Valuing Stocks TOPICS COVERED Stocks and the Stock Market Valuing Common Stocks Simplifying the Dividend Discount Model Growth Stocks and Income.
101 EXAMPLE, Historical Weights, using Market Value Weights In addition to the data from Ex. 10.7, assume that the security market prices are as follows:
Amity School Of Business 1 Amity School Of Business BBA Semister four Financial Management-II Ashish Samarpit Noel.
The Investment Decision Process Determine the required rate of return Evaluate the investment to determine if its market price is consistent with your.
Chapter McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2006 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. 15 Cost of Capital.
6- 1 Outline 6: Capital Structure 6.1 Debt and Value in a Tax Free Economy 6.2 Capital Structure and Corporate Taxes 6.3 Cost of Financial Distress 6.4.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2012 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
Chapter 11 Cost of Capital Copyright © 2011 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
Chapter 12: Leverage and Capital Structure
Stock & Bond Valuation Professor XXXXX Course Name / Number.
Stock Valuation. 2 Valuation The determination of what a stock is worth; the stock's intrinsic value If the price exceeds the valuation, buy the stock.
Cost of Capital 1. Hilliard Corp. wants to calculate its weighted average cost of capital (WACC). The company’s CFO has collected the following information:
Capital Structure Theory (1)
Capital Structure I: Basic Concepts.
Final Review FIN3701.
Capital Structure Determination
Chapter 10 Stock Valuation
Prof. P. Basatin Arockia Raj
Presentation transcript:

Capital Structure Decision-Making with Growth: An Instructional Class Exercise Professor Robert M. Hull Clarence W. King Endowed Chair in Finance School of Business Washburn University 1700 SW College Avenue Topeka, Kansas (Phone: 785  393  5630) 1

Overview  This paper offers an instructional class exercise of the capital structure decision-making process including a hands-on application of how to use four gain to leverage (G L ) equations including a recent equation that is used when managing growth firms. The latter equation is given by the recent Hull [2010, IMFI] Capital Structure Model (CSM) with growth. Given estimates for the costs of capital, tax rates and growth rates, this equation illustrates how managers of growth firms go about choosing an optimal debt level.  The exercise demonstrates the interdependency of the plowback- payout and debt-equity decisions when maximizing firm value.  By incorporating growth, this paper extends the non-growth pedagogical exercise of Hull [2008, JFEd]. This growth extension has proven to be successful in helping advanced business students understand the impact of the plowback and debt choices on firm value. 2

3 Capital structure perpetuity research begins with Modigliani and Miller, MM, (1963) who derive a gain to leverage (G L ) formulation in the context of an unleveraged firm issuing risk-free debt to replace risky equity. For MM, G L is the corporate tax rate multiplied by debt value. The applicability of MM’s G L formulation is limited. Miller (1977) and Warner (1977) are among those who argue that debt- related effects are weak and have no real impact on firm value. Altman (1984), Cutler and Summers (1988), Fischer, Heinkel and Zechner (1989), and Kayhan and Titman (2006) provide contrary evidence. Graham (2000) estimates that the corporate and personal tax benefit of debt is as low as 4.3% of firm value. Korteweg (2009) finds that the net benefit of leverage is typically 5.5% of firm value. Given the presence of debt in the capital structure of most firms as well as the evidence concerning leverage-related wealth effects, there is a need to offer usable equations that can quantify these effects. This paper aims to fill this void by offering G L formulations quantifying these effects.

Definitions Gain to Leverage (G L ) formulations are formulations that measure the change in value caused by changing the amount of debt. Equity discount rate is the firm’s cost of borrowing for equity or the return required by investors in equity (for most firms equity is just common equity). The rate can be for an unleveraged firm (r U ) or a leveraged firm (r L ). Debt discount rate is the firm’s cost of borrowing for debt or the return required by investors in debt (r D ). For most firms debt is long-term debt such as bonds or short-term debt that is renewed indefinitely. Plowback-payout choice determines the unleveraged growth rate (g U ). This choice along with the leverage choice decides the leveraged growth rate (g L ). Optimal debt-equity choice (ODE) is the optimal amount of debt relative to the amount equity at which the firm and its manager strive to obtain so as to maximize firm value. Perpetuity with growth involves a perpetual cash, a discount rate, and a growth rate. Any series of uneven cash flows can be approximated by a perpetuity with growth. Growth-adjusted discount rate refers to the discount rate minus the growth rate. For an unleveraged firm the equity growth-adjusted rate is r U g = r U  g U. For a leveraged firm it is r Lg = r L  g L. 4

MM (1958): Gain to Leverage (G L ) = 0. Value determined solely by operating assets. MM (1963): G L = T C D where T C is the applicable corporate tax rate and D = I/r D where I is the perpetual interest payment and r D is the cost of debt. Miller (1977): G L = (1  α)D where α = (1  T E )(1  T C ) / (1  T D ) with T E and T D the personal tax rates applicable to income from equity and debt, D now equals (1  T D )I/r D, and (1  α) < T C is expected to hold. Hull (2007): G L = [1  (αr D /r L )]D  [1  (r U /r L )]E U. CSM non-growth equation extends MM and Miller by incorporating equity discount rates (e.g., the unleveraged equity rate of r U and the leveraged equity rate of r L ). 5

Hull (2007): G L = [1  (αr D /r L )]D  [1  (r U /r L )]E U. CSM non-growth equation extends MM and Miller by incorporating equity discount rates (e.g., the unleveraged equity rate of r U and the leveraged equity rate of r L ). Hull (2010): G L = [1  (αr D /r Lg )]D  [1  (r Ug /r Lg )]E U. CSM growth equation extends CSM non-growth equation in incorporate growth-adjusted discount rates: r Ug = r U – g U and r Lg = r L – g L. 6

1) 1)The Capital Structure Model (CSM) with growth (2010, IMFI) enables this paper to broaden the non-growth pedagogical application of Hull (2008, JFEd). 2) 2)The model recognizes (in its application) the notion that the plowback ratio decides the minimum unleveraged growth rate (g U ) and that this leads to choosing a minimum plowback ratio (PBR). 3) 3)The model uses a break-through concept: the leveraged growth rate for equity (g L ), which depends on both the plowback-payout decision and the debt-equity decision, thus showing how these decisions are intertwined. 4) 4)The model can illustrate why firms with moderate growth can have larger optimal debt-equity (ODE) ratios, while firms with more pronounced growth must have lower ODEs. Features of Growth Model Used In Exercise 7

8 Why Internal Equity Is More Costly than External Equity Double Taxation: Because corporate taxes are paid before internal equity or retained earnings (RE) can be used for growth purposes, a firm actually has (1  T C )RE available to reinvest for these purposes. This gives a double taxation situation because the cash flow generated from retained earnings is taxed again at the corporate level before being paid out to owners. How does this double taxation affect the before-tax plowback ratio (PBR)? In terms of cash earnings available before taxes for distribution or plowback, we have: (1) cash that is retained (RE) and (2) cash that is paid out (C). We have (1  T C )RE useable for reinvestment after we adjust for double taxation.

Minimum Unleveraged Growth Rate What is the minimum unleveraged growth rate (g U ) that an unleveraged firm must attain so that unleveraged equity value (E U ) will not fall when the firm chooses to reinvest its retained earnings?  This can be shown to depend on the plowback ratio (PBR). For example, consider the value of an unleveraged firm with no growth (E U ): E U (no growth) = (1  T E )(1  T C )(1–PBR)CF BT / r U = (1  T E )(1  T C )CF BT / r U where T E is the effective personal tax rate paid by equity owners, T C is effective corporate tax rate, PBR is the before-tax plowback ratio, CF BT the before-tax cash flow paid out to equity owners, and r U is unleveraged equity cost of borrowing.  For non-growth PBR = 0 but with growth PBR > 0. Thus the numerator becomes multiplies by (1–PBR). This means that the discount rate of r U must be lowered by at least (1–PBR) if E U is not to decrease when it chooses growth. For this lowered discount rate, we have: (1–PBR)(r U ) = r U –(PBR)r U where the minimum unleveraged growth rate (g U ) must equal (PBR)r U making the making the growth-adjusted denominator equal to r U –g U. With g U = (PBR)r U, the two E U values are equal. For example, = E U (no growth) = E U (growth) implies (1–T E )(1–T C ) CF BT /r U = (1–T E )(1–T C ) (1–PBR)CF BT / r U –g U. 9

Equilibrating Growth Rates  Equilibrating g U = r U (1  T C )RE/C  Equilibrating g L = r L (1  T C )RE/[C+G  I/(1  T C )]  In comparing to equilibrating g L and g U formulas, we see that the equilibrating g L > equilibrating g U. 10

Question 1: Computing MM and Miller Values Unlevgrowth Inc. (UGI) is an unlevered growth firm. UGI’s managers believe it can increase its equity value by retiring a proportion of its outstanding equity through a new debt issue. UGI will treat its new debt as perpetual since it plans to continuously roll it over whenever it reaches maturity. Besides increasing its value through the use of debt, UGI is also considering expansion through its technological innovation. The expansion will involve a new line of marketable products for which future patents will assure constant long-term growth in cash payable to equity owners. UGI will make no choice about growth until it makes its leverage decision. After considerable discussion, UGI’s managers decide to issue debt and retire one-half of its outstanding equity shares. UGI’s managers estimate values for key variables needed when using the MM and Miller G L equations. These values are given in Table 1… Fill in the blank cells in Exhibit 1. 11

Table 1. MM and Miller Values [Note. When different, the MM and Miller values are denoted in subscripts.] T EMM = personal tax rate on equity income = 0%T EMiller = 5.00% T DMM = personal tax rate on debt income = 0%T DMiller = 15.00% T C = corporate tax rate = 30.00%α Miller = α = (1  T E )(1  T C ) / (1  T D ) G LMM = T C (D MM )G LMiller = [1−α Miller ]D Miller r U = cost of capital for unlevered equity = 11.00% r F = risk-free rate = 5.00% I = Interest = r D (D) where I = 0 for an unlevered firm because D = 0 CF BT = perpetual before-tax cash flow generated by operating assets = $1,654,135, PBR = plowback ratio used on CF BT (PBR = 0 with no growth) POR = payout ratio = 1 – PBR RE = before-tax retained earnings = PBR(CF BT ) with RE = $0 for no growth because PBR = 0 C = before-tax cash to equity = POR(CF BT ) with C = $1,654,135, for no growth because POR = 1 12

Question 2. Computing CSM Values without Growth UGI is not satisfied with the results from MM and Miller models and so it decides to turn to Capital Structure Model (CSM) without growth. This CSM equation is: G L = ; Before using the CSM, UGI estimates the costs of capital (r D and r L ) for each debt level choice. The values for r D and r L are in Exhibit 2. The CSM non-growth value for V U and D in Exhibit 2 are the same as Miller’s V U and debt values because both consider personal and corporate taxes while assuming no growth. Fill in the blank cells in Exhibit 2. After you fill in all cells, identify and comment on the debt choice for UGI’s maximum G L, the largest increase in its firm value (as given by the “%ΔV” row), and the optimal D/V L. Finally, explain the significance of the “Incremental ΔG L ” and “Incremental %ΔV” rows and what their first negative values indicate. 13

Table 2. CSM (without growth) Values PBR = plowback ratio used on CF BT = 0.35POR = payout ratio = 1 – 0.35 = 0.65 T C = corporate tax rate = 30.00%T D = personal tax rate on debt income = 15.00% α = r U = 11.00% CF BT = perpetual before-tax cash flow generated by operating assets = $1,654,135, RE = before-tax retained earnings = PBR(CF BT ) = 0.35($1,654,135,338.34) = $578,947, C = before-tax cash to equity = POR(CF BT ) = 0.65($1,654,135,338.34) = $1,075,187, I = Interest = where D is D Miller and I must be computed for each D choice. [Note. The CSM, like Miller, assumes personal taxes, and so we divide D by (1–T D ) because the below g L equation uses an I value before personal taxes are considered.] G = perpetuity cash flow beyond I created with debt when G L ≠ 0. (Supplied for each D choice.) g U = unlevered equity growth rate = g U = r U (1  T C )RE/C = % g L = levered equity growth rate = g L = r L (1  T C )RE/[C+G  I/(1  T C )] (Computed for each D choice.) r Ug = growth-adjusted unlevered equity rate of return = r U  g U = 11%  % = % r Lg = growth-adjusted levered equity rate of return = r L  g L (Computed for each D choice.) V U (no growth) = (1–T E )(1–T C ) CF BT /r U = $10,000,000,000 V U (growth) = (1–T E )(1–T C ) (1–PBR)CF BT / r Ug = $10,432,098,

Question 3. Computing Growth-Adjusted Costs of Borrowing While UGI’s managers are satisfied with the valuation results using the CSM model with no growth, they still want to know if UGI can improve its value through a new line of marketable products for which future patents can assure constant long-term growth in cash payable to equity. To determine if growth can add to its current value, UGI will use the G L equation given by the CSM with growth. But first it must make some needed computations concerning the value of growth as well as its levered growth rates for various debt choices. Using the values and equations in Table 2, supply answers to the below questions…Fill in the blank cells in Exhibit 3. 15

Question 4. Computing CSM Values Using the CSM with Growth Fill in the blank cells in Exhibit 4. For the r Lg row, copy in the values computed previously. After you fill in all cells, identify and comment on the debt choice for UGI’s maximum G L, the largest increase in its firm value (as given by the “%ΔV” row), and the optimal D/V L. Finally, explain the significance of the “Incremental ΔG L ” and “Incremental %ΔV” rows and what their first negative values indicate. Comment on how values for these two rows differ from Exhibit 2 when the CSM G L equation was used without growth. Can you offer an explanation or two to explain the difference? 16

Question 5. Computing and Comparing G L Values In Questions 1, 2, and 4, you computed the G L values using the MM, Miller and CSM equations for the nine after-tax perpetual debt choices. From your answers for these three questions, fill in Exhibit 5 expressing all values in billions of dollars to four decimals. After filling in Exhibit 5 and studying how the G L values change as the proportion changes, answer the below questions. (a) The G L answers in Exhibit 5 use the MM, Miller and CSM equations. In comparing these answers, which (if any) of the three equations is consistent with trade-off theory? Explain. ….. (e) Which equation would you feel more comfortable with if you were a UGI manager charged with the capital structure decision? Explain. 17

Exhibit 5. Comparison of Values Given By Four G L Equations [Note. All values are expressed in billions of dollars to four decimals.] P = Debt Choice (proportion of unlevered equity retired by debt) G L Model MM's G L Miller's G L CSM's G L CSM's G L    

19

20

Relation between Optimal Payback and Leverage Choices: Fix T C = 0.10; g U = 4.45%; g L = 7.54% PBR: DE : $406,133,726$584,060,566$595,066,819$490,277,818$322,277,754-$75,930,001-$516,358, : $406,204,799$593,671,035$644,796,555$608,180,772$545,212,133$383,617,482-$2,981,936, : $414,538,198$612,697,475$683,739,702$678,297,490$666,331,387$630,148,421-$3,165,641, : $420,444,325$625,885,851$709,609,103$724,029,509$745,686,775$798,467,867-$3,267,207, : $436,681,828$661,749,409$778,133,891$844,232,463$957,565,742-$3,877,540,403-$3,493,225, : $517,571,211$840,502,919$1,113,353,404$1,444,840,597-$5,179,813,748-$4,603,741,882-$4,238,732, : $544,614,239$901,053,893$1,228,041,530$1,659,219,239-$5,372,799,978-$4,794,845,068-$4,430,248, : $577,145,549$974,526,842$1,368,699,081-$6,309,293,696-$5,587,401,266-$5,006,406,071-$4,640,736, : $721,927,950-$8,830,311,051-$7,969,604,746-$7,158,211,444-$6,398,231,232-$5,798,700,437-$5,418,646, : $1,533,815,988-$9,024,397,854-$8,152,700,907-$7,331,968,915-$6,564,211,949-$5,959,794,343-$5,575,324,257 21

22

Relation between Optimal Payback and Leverage Choices: Fix T C = 0.30; g U = 4.92%; g L = 8.35 PBR: DE : $434,632,560$669,654,615$745,744,788$710,471,209$609,654,045$288,670,869-$173,109, : $429,042,179$669,610,812$775,645,491$781,888,862$725,918,778$488,193,881$223,564, : $483,672,218$783,812,446$973,627,922$1,090,987,281$1,193,367,665$1,289,652,011-$2,331,871, : $557,393,968$939,614,274$1,243,709,710$1,531,937,010$1,945,446,020-$3,093,139,569-$2,707,461, : $635,524,783$1,109,375,208$1,548,349,336$2,066,314,473-$3,913,930,913-$3,416,091,195-$3,031,359, : $670,907,102$1,187,833,426$1,693,225,511$2,296,612,998-$4,052,022,144-$3,549,308,769-$3,163,204, : $712,724,243$1,281,807,758$1,870,256,428-$4,791,952,920-$4,207,378,575-$3,698,760,134-$3,310,175, : $762,518,798$1,395,353,990-$5,501,499,522-$4,979,330,361-$4,382,991,184-$3,867,218,922-$3,474,837, : $425,397,181-$6,213,307,287-$5,787,663,077-$5,158,441,671-$4,550,929,429-$4,027,899,478-$3,631,064, : $41,516,035-$6,357,884,696-$5,799,645,666-$5,169,615,196-$4,561,403,704-$4,037,908,769-$3,640,772,740 23

24

Final Remarks Student feedback when using the CSM exercises has been positive over the years from both upper level undergraduate finance students and graduate students. The below quote typifies students’ feelings on the exercise: “The CSM with Growth model is most complete because it provisions for more scenarios which is keeping in line with diversity of situations faced by managers in trying to determine the optimum leverage. CSM with growth gives due consideration to the growth that can be brought about if the company keeps aside some of its earning to fuel expansion.” The approval from students concerning the CSM applications has been received not only for courses taught in the classroom but also online. 25

Celebrate Relax 26 It’s Over!