The Theory of Consumer Choice

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
1 CHAPTER.
Advertisements

8 CHAPTER Possibilities, Preferences, and Choices.
7 TOPICS FOR FURTHER STUDY. Copyright © 2006 Thomson Learning 21 The Theory of Consumer Choice.
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy
AAEC 2305 Fundamentals of Ag Economics Chapter 2 Economics of Demand.
© 2010 Pearson Education Canada. You buy your music online and play it on an iPod. As the prices of a music download and an iPod have tumbled, the volume.
WHY DOES THE DEMAND CURVE SLOPE DOWNWARD?
In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:
Chapter 21 The Theory of Consumer Choice
The Theory of Consumer Choice
The Theory of Consumer Choice
8 Possibilities, Preferences, and Choices
In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:
9 POSSIBILITIES, PREFERENCES, AND CHOICES © 2012 Pearson Education.
8 Possibilities, Preferences, and Choices
7 TOPICS FOR FURTHER STUDY. Copyright©2004 South-Western 21 The Theory of Consumer Choice Kenningin um val neytenda.
1 Chapter 6 From Demand to Welfare. Main Topics Dissecting the effects of a price change Measuring changes in consumer welfare using demand curves 2.
Principles of Microeconomics: Ch. 21 First Canadian Edition Overview u The budget constraint u Indifference curves u The consumer’s optimal choice u Income.
Indifference Curves and Utility Maximization
Chapter 4 Consumer and Firm Behavior: The Work- Leisure Decision and Profit Maximization Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education, Inc.
POSSIBILITIES, PREFERENCES, AND CHOICES 8 CHAPTER.
Economics Winter 14 February 24 th, 2014 Lecture 15 Ch. 8 and Ch. 9.
Consumer Choice ETP Economics 101.
7 TOPICS FOR FURTHER STUDY. Copyright©2004 South-Western 21 The Theory of Consumer Choice.
PART 7 TOPICS FOR FURTHER STUDY. Copyright © 2006 Nelson, a division of Thomson Canada Ltd. 21 The Theory of Consumer Choice.
The Theory of Consumer Choice
PowerPoint Slides prepared by: Andreea CHIRITESCU Eastern Illinois University The Theory of Consumer Choice 1 © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved.
The Theory of Consumer Choice
Week 8 – Economics Theory Consumer Choice. The Theory of Consumer Choice The theory of consumer choice addresses the following questions: –Do all demand.
In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:
Principles of Microeconomics
McTaggart, Findlay, Parkin: Microeconomics © 2007 Pearson Education Australia Chapter 8: Households’ Choices.
© 2011 South-Western, a part of Cengage Learning, all rights reserved C H A P T E R 2011 update The Theory of Consumer Choice M icroeconomics P R I N C.
The Theory of Consumer Choice
Economic Analysis for Business Session XV: Theory of Consumer Choice (Chapter 21) Instructor Sandeep Basnyat
The Theory of Consumer Choice
Review of the previous lecture A consumer’s budget constraint shows the possible combinations of different goods he can buy given his income and the prices.
BACHELOR OF ARTS IN ECONOMICS Econ 111 – ECONOMIC ANALYSIS Pangasinan State University Social Science Department – PSU Lingayen CHAPTER 7 CONSUMER BEHAVIOR.
© 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western. The Theory of Consumer Choice The theory of consumer choice addresses the following questions: –Do all demand curves slope.
Lecture 7 Consumer Behavior Required Text: Frank and Bernanke – Chapter 5.
Theory of Consumer Behaviour
The Theory of Consumer Choice Chapter 21 Copyright © 2001 by Harcourt, Inc. All rights reserved. Requests for permission to make copies of any part of.
Lecture 4 Consumer Behavior Recommended Text: Franks and Bernanke - Chapter 5.
The Theory of Consumer Choice
Review of the previous lecture
S PP 2 T OPIC 1 I SSUE 2: C HANGE IN PRICES AFFECT CONSUMER ’ S CHOICES T HE THEORY OF CONSUMER CHOICE Xiaozhen Chen Hai Tran.
© 2010 Pearson Education Canada Possibilities, Preferences and Choice ECON103 Microeconomics Cheryl Fu.
Consumer Choice Theory Public Finance and The Price System 4 th Edition Browning, Browning Johnny Patta KK Pengelolaan Pembangunan dan Pengembangan Kebijakan.
1 Indifference Curves and Utility Maximization CHAPTER 6 Appendix © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
© 2011 South-Western, a part of Cengage Learning, all rights reserved C H A P T E R 2011 update The Theory of Consumer Choice M icroeconomics P R I N C.
The theory of consumer choice Chapter 21 Copyright © 2004 by South-Western,a division of Thomson Learning.
Copyright © 2011 Cengage Learning 21 The Theory of Consumer Choice.
Two Extreme Examples of Indifference Curves
The Theory of Consumer Choice
ECN 201: Principles of Microeconomics
The Theory of Consumer Choice
21 The Theory of Consumer Choice CHAPTER
Background to Demand: The Theory of Consumer Choice
21 The Theory of Consumer Choice CHAPTER
Microeconomics 1000 Lecture 16 Labour supply.
Consumer Behavior Ch. 7.
TOPICS FOR FURTHER STUDY
TOPICS FOR FURTHER STUDY
TOPICS FOR FURTHER STUDY
Background to Demand: The Theory of Consumer Choice
The Theory of Consumer Choice
Presentation transcript:

The Theory of Consumer Choice 21 The Theory of Consumer Choice

What’s Important in Chapter 21 Budget Constraint & its Shape Consumer Preferences and the Shape of the Indifference Curves Consumer optimum Changes in Income Changes in Price

The theory of consumer choice addresses the following questions: Do all demand curves slope downward? How do wages affect labor supply? How do interest rates affect household saving?

THE BUDGET CONSTRAINT: WHAT THE CONSUMER CAN AFFORD The budget constraint depicts the limit on the consumption “bundles” that a consumer can afford. People consume less than they desire because their spending is constrained, or limited, by their income.

THE BUDGET CONSTRAINT: WHAT THE CONSUMER CAN AFFORD The budget constraint shows the various combinations of goods the consumer can afford given his or her income and the prices of the two goods.

The Consumer’s Budget Constraint Pizza Price=$10;Pepsi=$2

THE BUDGET CONSTRAINT: WHAT THE CONSUMER CAN AFFORD The Consumer’s Budget Constraint Any point on the budget constraint line indicates the consumer’s combination or tradeoff between two goods. For example, if the consumer buys no pizzas, he can afford 500 pints of Pepsi (point B on the upcoming graph). If he buys no Pepsi, he can afford 100 pizzas (point A).

Figure 1 The Consumer’s Budget Constraint Quantity of Pepsi 500 B Consumer’s budget constraint 100 A Quantity of Pizza Copyright©2004 South-Western

THE BUDGET CONSTRAINT: WHAT THE CONSUMER CAN AFFORD The Consumer’s Budget Constraint Alternately, the consumer can buy 50 pizzas and 250 pints of Pepsi.

Figure 1 The Consumer’s Budget Constraint Quantity of Pepsi 500 B Consumer’s budget constraint 250 50 C 100 A Quantity of Pizza Copyright©2004 South-Western

THE BUDGET CONSTRAINT: WHAT THE CONSUMER CAN AFFORD The slope of the budget constraint line equals the relative price of the two goods, that is, the price of one good compared to the price of the other. It measures the rate at which the consumer can trade one good for the other. The slope of the preceding graph is -5 (the price of Pepsi/the price of Pizza; 10/2; the slope is negative indicating an inverse relationship)

PREFERENCES: WHAT THE CONSUMER WANTS A consumer’s preference among consumption bundles may be illustrated with indifference curves.

Representing Preferences with Indifference Curves An indifference curve is a curve that shows consumption bundles that give the consumer the same level of satisfaction.

Figure 2 The Consumer’s Preferences Quantity I2 Indifference curve, I1 of Pepsi C B D A Quantity of Pizza Copyright©2004 South-Western

Representing Preferences with Indifference Curves The Consumer’s Preferences The consumer is indifferent, or equally happy, with the combinations shown at points A, B, and C because they are all on the same curve. The Marginal Rate of Substitution The slope at any point on an indifference curve is the marginal rate of substitution. It is the rate at which a consumer is willing to trade one good for another. It is the amount of one good that a consumer requires as compensation to give up one unit of the other good.

Figure 2 The Consumer’s Preferences Quantity I2 Indifference curve, I1 of Pepsi C B D 1 MRS A Quantity of Pizza Copyright©2004 South-Western

Four Properties of Indifference Curves Higher indifference curves are preferred to lower ones. Indifference curves are downward sloping. Indifference curves do not cross. Indifference curves are bowed inward convex.

Four Properties of Indifference Curves Property 1: Higher indifference curves are preferred to lower ones. Consumers usually prefer more of something to less of it. Higher indifference curves represent larger quantities of goods than do lower indifference curves.

Figure 2 The Consumer’s Preferences Quantity I2 Indifference curve, I1 of Pepsi Point D is preferred to A,B, or C C B D A Quantity of Pizza Copyright©2004 South-Western

Four Properties of Indifference Curves Property 2: Indifference curves are downward sloping. A consumer is willing to give up one good only if he or she gets more of the other good in order to remain equally happy. If the quantity of one good is reduced, the quantity of the other good must increase. For this reason, most indifference curves slope downward.

Figure 2 The Consumer’s Preferences Quantity Indifference curve, I1 of Pepsi Indifference Curves Slope Downward Quantity of Pizza Copyright©2004 South-Western

Four Properties of Indifference Curves Property 3: Indifference curves do not cross. Points A and B on the next slide should make the consumer equally happy. Points B and C should make the consumer equally happy. This implies that A and C would make the consumer equally happy. But C has more of both goods compared to A.

Figure 3 The Impossibility of Intersecting Indifference Curves Quantity of Pepsi PROOF: A=B B=C So C should =A, but does not C A B Quantity of Pizza Copyright©2004 South-Western

Four Properties of Indifference Curves Property 4: Indifference curves are bowed inward. People are more willing to trade away goods that they have in abundance and less willing to trade away goods of which they have little. These differences in a consumer’s marginal substitution rates cause his or her indifference curve to bow inward.

Figure 4 Bowed Indifference Curves Quantity of Pepsi Indifference curve The more of a drink (Pepsi) I have, the more I am willing to give up for food (Pizza) 14 2 1 MRS = 6 8 3 A 4 6 3 7 B 1 MRS = 1 Quantity of Pizza Copyright©2004 South-Western

Two Extreme Examples of Indifference Curves Perfect substitutes Perfect complements

Two Extreme Examples of Indifference Curves Perfect Substitutes Two goods with straight-line indifference curves are perfect substitutes. The marginal rate of substitution is a fixed number.

Figure 5 Perfect Substitutes and Perfect Complements (a) Perfect Substitutes Nickels 3 6 I3 2 4 I2 1 2 I1 Dimes Copyright©2004 South-Western

Two Extreme Examples of Indifference Curves Perfect Complements Two goods with right-angle indifference curves are perfect complements.

Figure 5 Perfect Substitutes and Perfect Complements (b) Perfect Complements Left Shoes I1 I2 7 5 Right Shoes Copyright©2004 South-Western

OPTIMIZATION: WHAT THE CONSUMER CHOOSES Consumers want to get the combination of goods on the highest possible indifference curve. However, the consumer must also end up on or below his budget constraint.

The Consumer’s Optimal Choices Combining the indifference curve and the budget constraint determines the consumer’s optimal choice.

The Consumer’s Optimal Choices In other words: Consumer optimum occurs at the point where the highest indifference curve and the budget constraint touch. The consumer chooses consumption of the two goods so that the marginal rate of substitution equals the relative price.

The Consumer’s Optimal Choice At the consumer’s optimum, the consumer’s valuation of the two goods equals the market’s valuation.

Figure 6 The Consumer’s Optimum Quantity I3 of Pepsi I2 Budget constraint I1 Optimum is the highest Indifference curve that your budget permits B A Quantity of Pizza Copyright©2004 South-Western

How Changes in Income Affect the Consumer’s Choices An increase in income shifts the budget constraint outward. The consumer is able to choose a better combination of goods on a higher indifference curve.

Figure 7 An Increase in Income (NORMAL GOOD) Quantity of Pepsi New budget constraint I2 1. An increase in income shifts the budget constraint outward . . . I1 New optimum 3. . . . and Pepsi consumption. Initial optimum Initial budget constraint Quantity 2. . . . raising pizza consumption . . . of Pizza Copyright©2004 South-Western

How Changes in Income Affect the Consumer’s Choices Normal versus Inferior Goods If a consumer buys more of a good when his or her income rises, the good is called a normal good. If a consumer buys less of a good when his or her income rises, the good is called an inferior good.

Figure 8 Increase in Income: INFERIOR Good Quantity of Pepsi New budget constraint I2 I1 1. When an increase in income shifts the budget constraint outward . . . 3. . . . but Pepsi consumption falls, making Pepsi an inferior good. Initial optimum New optimum Initial budget constraint Quantity 2. . . . pizza consumption rises, making pizza a normal good . . . of Pizza Copyright©2004 South-Western

How Changes in Prices Affect Consumer’s Choices A fall in the price of any good rotates the budget constraint outward and changes the slope of the budget constraint. The product whose price does not change is the “anchor” for the rotation The product whose price changes has a new axis intercept

Figure 9 A Change in Price from $1 to $2 for Pepsi ( See slide 6 or Fig 1, Text) Quantity of Pepsi New budget constraint 1,000 D I1 I2 New optimum 1. A fall in the price of Pepsi rotates the budget constraint outward . . . 500 B 100 A 3. . . . and raising Pepsi consumption. Initial optimum Initial budget constraint Quantity 2. . . . reducing pizza consumption . . . of Pizza Copyright©2004 South-Western

Income and Substitution Effects A price change has two effects on consumption. An income effect A substitution effect

Income and Substitution Effects The Income Effect The income effect is the change in consumption that results when a price change moves the consumer to a higher or lower indifference curve. The Substitution Effect The substitution effect is the change in consumption that results when a price change moves the consumer along an indifference curve to a point with a different marginal rate of substitution.

Income and Substitution Effects A Change in Price: Substitution Effect A price change first causes the consumer to move from one point on an indifference curve to another on the same curve. Illustrated by movement from point A to point B in fig.10 . A Change in Price: Income Effect After moving from one point to another on the same curve, the consumer will move to another indifference curve. Illustrated by movement from point B to point C.

Figure 10 Income and Substitution Effects Quantity of Pepsi I2 I1 New budget constraint C New optimum Income effect Income effect B A Initial optimum Initial budget constraint Substitution effect Substitution effect Quantity of Pizza Copyright©2004 South-Western

Table 1 Income and Substitution Effects When the Price of Pepsi Falls Copyright©2004 South-Western

Deriving the Demand Curve A consumer’s demand curve can be viewed as a summary of the optimal decisions that arise from his or her budget constraint and indifference curves.

Figure 11 Deriving the Demand Curve (See Fig 9 of Text) (a) The Consumer ’ s Optimum (b) The Demand Curve for Pepsi Quantity Price of of Pepsi Pepsi New budget constraint I2 Demand 750 B 250 $2 A I1 750 1 B 250 A Initial budget constraint Quantity Quantity of Pizza of Pepsi Copyright©2004 South-Western

THREE APPLICATIONS Do all demand curves slope downward? Demand curves can sometimes slope upward. This happens when a consumer buys more of a good when its price rises. Giffen goods Economists use the term Giffen good to describe a good that violates the law of demand. Giffen goods are goods for which an increase in the price raises the quantity demanded. The income effect dominates the substitution effect. They have demand curves that slope upwards.

Figure 12 A Giffen Good Quantity of Potatoes Initial budget constraint Optimum with high price of potatoes I2 Optimum with low price of potatoes D E 2. . . . which increases potato consumption if potatoes are a Giffen good. 1. An increase in the price of potatoes rotates the budget constraint inward . . . C New budget constraint Quantity of Meat Copyright©2004 South-Western

THREE APPLICATIONS How do wages affect labor supply? If the substitution effect is greater than the income effect for the worker, he or she works more. If income effect is greater than the substitution effect, he or she works less.

Figure 13 The Work-Leisure Decision Consumption I3 I2 $5,000 100 I1 Optimum 2,000 60 Hours of Leisure Copyright©2004 South-Western

Figure 14 An Increase in the Wage (a) For a person with these preferences . . . . . . the labor supply curve slopes upward. Consumption Wage Labor supply I2 I1 1. When the wage rises . . . BC1 BC2 Hours of Hours of Labor 2. . . . hours of leisure decrease . . . 3. . . . and hours of labor increase. Leisure Supplied Copyright©2004 South-Western

Figure 14 An Increase in the Wage (b) For a person with these preferences . . . . . . the labor supply curve slopes backward. Consumption Wage Labor supply BC2 1. When the wage rises . . . I2 I1 BC1 Hours of Hours of Labor 2. . . . hours of leisure increase . . . 3. . . . and hours of labor decrease. Leisure Supplied Copyright©2004 South-Western

THREE APPLICATIONS How do interest rates affect household saving? If the substitution effect of a higher interest rate is greater than the income effect, households save more. If the income effect of a higher interest rate is greater than the substitution effect, households save less.

Figure 15 The Consumption-Saving Decision Budget constraint when Old I3 $110,000 100,000 I2 I1 55,000 $50,000 Optimum Consumption when Young Copyright©2004 South-Western

Figure 16 An Increase in the Interest Rate (a) Higher Interest Rate Raises Saving (b) Higher Interest Rate Lowers Saving Consumption Consumption when Old when Old BC2 BC2 1. A higher interest rate rotates the budget constraint outward . . . 1. A higher interest rate rotates the budget constraint outward . . . I2 I1 I1 I2 BC1 BC1 Consumption Consumption 2. . . . resulting in lower consumption when young and, thus, higher saving. 2. . . . resulting in higher consumption when young and, thus, lower saving. when Young when Young Copyright©2004 South-Western

THREE APPLICATIONS Thus, an increase in the interest rate could either encourage or discourage saving.