Lind on Measuring Benefits © Allen C. Goodman, 2009.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Pure Competition in the Long Run
Advertisements

Chapter 4: Essential Microeconomic Tools Everything should be made as simple as possible, but not simpler. Albert Einstein.
Introduction to Land Rent Land Rent and Fertility Fixed prices of inputs and outputs. Zero economic profit. Three types of land –high fertility –medium.
Valuation 2 and 3: Demand and welfare theory
Chapter 16 Equilibrium.
Investment and Saving Decisions
Equilibrium, Profits, and Adjustment in a Competitive Market Chapter 8 J. F. O’Connor.
Module 4: Market Equilibrium
Frank Cowell: Efficiency-Waste EFFICIENCY: WASTE MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell Almost essential Welfare and Efficiency Almost essential.
Basic Concepts in Economics: Theory of Demand and Supply
Introduction to Land Rent © Allen C. Goodman, 2006.
Upcoming in Class Homework #5 Due Next Tuesday Oct.
Housing Demand and Supply Today Return Exam Second Paper – Discussion Housing Services and Supply.
More Insurance How much insurance We started talking about insurance. Question now is “how much?” Recall that John’s expected utility involves his wealth.
3 Prepared by: Fernando Quijano and Yvonn Quijano © 2004 Prentice Hall Business PublishingPrinciples of Economics, 7/eKarl Case, Ray Fair Demand, Supply,
Introduction to Land Rent © Allen C. Goodman, 2006.
Demand and Supply Analysis
Simple Consumer Location Model (from R. Braid) © Allen C. Goodman, 2009.
Chapter 10: Perfect competition
Things to do with Hedonic Prices © Allen C. Goodman, 2000.
Polinsky and Shavell, Tauchen and Witte, Pashigian © Allen C. Goodman 2002.
Fun with Rent Functions! We derived a rent gradient Remember, slope was related to mgl transport cost. Let’s assume that we have an open city. What does.
Equilibrium and Efficiency
Lind on Measuring Benefits © Allen C. Goodman, 2002.
Fun with Rent Functions! We derived a rent gradient Remember, slope was related to mgl transport cost. Let’s assume that we have an open city. What does.
Communities and Goods © Allen C. Goodman, How do people sort themselves into communities? DW ( ) provide a simple model. Let’s assume that.
AE = C + I + G + NX AE = GDP = Y = C + I + G + NX
Labor Market Equilibrium
Externalities © Allen C. Goodman 2009 Ideal Market Processes are desirable if … We accept the value judgment that “personal wants of individuals should.
slide 1Competition in the long-run In the short-run the number of firms in a competitive industry is fixed. In the long-run new firms can enter or existing.
Economic surplus Gains and losses with international trade: Economic Welfare.
THE ECONOMICS OF LABOR MARKETS
Differentiation in Economics – Objectives 1 Understand that differentiation lets us identify marginal relationships in economics Measure the rate of change.
 Homework #5 Due Monday  Homework #6 Due Oct. 22  Extra Credit Writing Assignment Oct. 17th  Writing Assignment Due Oct. 24th.
mankiw's macroeconomics modules
4 Market Structures Candy Markets Simulation.
Demand, Supply, & Market Equilibrium Chapter 3. Demand A schedule or curve that shows the various amounts of a product that consumers are willing and.
© 2007 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics 8e by Case and Fair Prepared by: Fernando & Yvonn Quijano 3 Chapter Demand, Supply, and.
ECON 6012 Cost Benefit Analysis Memorial University of Newfoundland
The Laws of Demand and Supply.
INCOME AND SUBSTITUTION EFFECTS

Derivatives to Business and Economics. Our textbook tells us that business analysts and economists have increasingly turned to mathematical models to.
CHAPTER 21 PURE COMPETITION COMPETITION.
Perfect Competition A perfectly competitive industry is one that obeys the following assumptions:  there are a large number of firms, each producing the.
Unit 3 Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply: Fluctuations in Outputs and Prices.
Review for Exam 1 Chapters 1 Through 5. Production Possibilities Frontiers and Opportunity Costs Learning Objective 2.1 Production possibilities frontier.
1 Demand and Supply Analysis Cheryl Carleton Asher Villanova University Chapter 4 © 2006 Thomson/South-Western.
Chapter 14 Equilibrium and Efficiency. What Makes a Market Competitive? Buyers and sellers have absolutely no effect on price Three characteristics: Absence.
CHAPTER 12 Expenditure Multipliers
CHAPTER 3 NATIONAL INCOME: WHERE IT COMES FROM AND WHERE IT GOES ECN 2003 MACROECONOMICS 1 Assoc. Prof. Yeşim Kuştepeli.
Chapter 4 Demand, supply and market equilibrium. Let’s remember Colleen and Bill Colleen’s firm supplied logs Bill’s firm supplied food Colleen DEMANDED.
Today  LR industry supply –Constant cost –Increasing cost  Implications of LR equilibrium.
Touro University International1 Supply and Demand Issues Supply and demand are the starting point of all economic analysis The essence of choice is being.
Today  LR industry supply –Constant cost –Increasing cost  Implications of LR equilibrium  Market efficiency in perfect competition.
Chapter 14 Equilibrium and Efficiency McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved.
Today LR industry supply Constant cost, increasing cost, and decreasing cost industries Market efficiency in perfect competition.
 Many small firms  Standardized product  No need to advertise  “Price takers”  Free entry and exit  Perfectly elastic demand  Average revenue.
Market Failure Diagrams.  Learning Objective:  To understand how to illustrate market failure with diagrams  Learning Outcome / Success Criteria 
1 Demand, Supply, and Market Equilibrium Chapter 3.
1 Chapter 8 Practice Quiz Perfect Competition A perfectly competitive market is not characterized by a. many small firms. b. a great variety of.
1 of 46 Lecture 3 Demand, Supply, and Market Equilibrium Firms and Households: The Basic Decision-Making Units Input Markets and Output Markets: The Circular.
Economic Analysis for Business Session IX: Consumer Surplus, Producer Surplus and Market Efficiency-1 Instructor Sandeep Basnyat
What three factors determine the demand for a product?
 This will explain how consumers allocate their income over many goods.  This looks at individual’s decision making when faced with limited income and.
Chapter 23 Industry Supply
Utility Functions, Budget Lines and Consumer Demand
Costs Of Production.
Tutorial 3: Market Failures
Chapter 10: Perfect competition
Presentation transcript:

Lind on Measuring Benefits © Allen C. Goodman, 2009

Suppose We have 2 types of land, half polluted (p), half not (u). P p = 100; P u = 200 If a program of air pollution control equalizes productivity everywhere, rent may end up at 150. If so total property values remain same. Does this mean there were no benefits?

Diagram PpPp PuPu

Analysis Assume class of programs w/ output specific to particular locations. How do we measure benefits? Two major findings –Benefits of a project can be approximating by measuring net increase in profits of activities located on land directly affected by project. –W/ zero profits, total change in productivity equals change in land values.

Analysis a ij = maximum rent individual i would pay for parcel j. Alternatively: a ij = Net earnings of firm i at parcel j exclusive of land cost. n activities, n parcels p j = rental value of parcel j. Activity locates at parcel j ONLY IF: (2.3) a ij  p j AND (2.4) a ij - p j  a ik - p k p j, a ij pjpj

Analysis Define consumer surplus (or profit) as s ij. s ij  a ij – p j. SO, the total benefit from land is (2.5)  a ij =  s ij +  p j Land is ENHANCED if there is some a ij > a ij for some parcels, and a ij =  ij for the rest. Let: A =  a jj (2.7) A  a j  (j) (2.8) A  a j  (j) - a j  j p j, a ij s ij

Analysis (2.5)  a ij =  s ij +  p j Let: A =  a jj (2.7) A  a j  (j) (2.8) A  a j  (j) - a j  j From (2.5) (2.9) A  s j  (j) - s j  j ) +  p j - p j ) What does this mean? Change in total land values = change in productivity ONLY if surplus terms = 0, or surplus terms don’t change! Essentially an open city argument.

Benefit Measurement Lind shows that any cycle of relocation NOT involving a parcel of land affected by the project will leave net productivity unchanged. We need to consider ONLY parcels that are directly affected, where land is improved. Benefits can be measured by considering  in surplus of those activities alone that move onto improved land.

Suppose we have 3 unimproved parcels  in productivity = [a 12 – a 11 ] + [a 23 – a 22 ] + [a 31 – a 33 ] Since there is no improvement,  in productivity = [a 12 – a 11 ] + [a 23 – a 22 ] + [a 31 – a 33 ] From the equilibrium conditions: (2.3) a ij  p j AND (2.4) a ij - p j  a ik - p k [a jj+1 – a jj ]  p j+1 – p j AND [a g1 – p 1 ]  [a gg – p g ] New rents

Suppose we have 3 unimproved parcels [a jj+1 – a jj ]  p j+1 – p j AND [a g1 – p 1 ]  [a gg – p g ] ALSO [a jj+1 – a jj ]  p j+1 – p j AND [a g1 – p 1 ]  [a gg – p g ] New rents Old rents

Suppose we have 3 unimproved parcels a 12 – a 11  p 2 – p 1 a 23 – a 22  p 3 – p 2 a 31 – a 33  p 1 – p’ 3 Sum  0 New rents Old rents a 12 – a 11  p 2 – p 1 a 23 – a 22  p 3 – p 2 a 31 – a 33  p 1 – p 3 Sum  0 Benefits must equal 0!

Let’s improve a parcel (#1) D = Benefits. Assume activity 1 moves to parcel 2, activity 2 to parcel 3, etc. With no improvement on parcels 2 through g: p j, a ij “Winning” a ij changes; Eq’m rent p j changes.

From eq’m for j th firm Why they’re here nowWhy they weren’t before So, for g-1 firms: We know:

From eq’m for j th firm Increased profit at new pricesIncreased profit at old prices If we’re operating on the margin, we get equalities above:

Earlier Problem Activity is on polluted land p rather than unpolluted land u. a ip – p p  a iu – p u p u – p p  a iu – a ip If pollution is eliminated, all land is same and net benefits are:  (for half of parcels) (a iu – a ip ) From above,  (for half of parcels) (a iu – a ip )  (n/2)(p 2 – p 1 ) Here, with 200 parcels, 100 polluted, 100 not  (for half of parcels) (a iu – a ip )  100 (200 – 100) = 10000

Another example Two types of land Demand for unpolluted land: P = 250 – 0.5Q Demand for polluted land: P = 110 –0.1Q 100 acres of each. P u = 200; P p = 100. S u = 2500; S p = 500. Total surplus = If all land is now unpolluted, bidders will use first demand curve  Q = 200; P = 150. Property values unchanged. New surplus = From (2.5) (2.9) A  s j  (j) - s j  j ) +  p j - p j ) A  +  From above,  (for half of parcels) (a iu – a ip )  You should graph this and do the calculations

Polinsky and Shavell © Allen C. Goodman 2009

Polinsky and Shavell Examine the distinction between closed and open cities when looking at the measurement of benefits. Take a little different tack in the modeling but with similar results. They use an indirect utility function: V = V (y - T(k), p(k), a(k)) wherek = distance, y = income, T = transportation costs, a(k) is an amenity. We have V 1 > 0, V 2 0. Why?

What can we do with this? V = V (y - T(k), p(k), a(k)) Within a city dV = 0. dV/dk = -V 1 T´ + V 2 p´ +V 3 a´ = 0. Leads to p´ = (V 1 /V 2 )T´- (V 3 /V 2 )a´. (V 1 /V 2 ) = [Utility/$]/[Utility/(acres/$)]  (1/Land). We have negative price-distance function. With an open city V is fixed at V*, so suppose there is an increase in a(k). For V to stay equal to V*, p(k) must rise.

What can we do with this? Suppose we have a closed city. V** = V (y - T(k), p(k), a(k)) V starts at V**. Suppose amenities increase everywhere but k. V** must rise. Since amenities haven’t improved at k, p(k) must fall relative to elsewhere. This is an indirect effect. Now increase a(k). p(k) must rise to maintain V**. This is the direct effect.

Regression analysis w/ PS Cobb-Douglas Example U = Ax  q  a(k)  ;  +  = 1.  x(k) =  (y – T(k)) q(k) =  (y – T(k))/p(k) Putting x and q into U  V(k) = C[y-T(k)]p(k) -  a(k)  C is a constant Solve for p(k) as: log p(k) = (1/  ) log (C/V*) + (1/  ) log [Y – T(k)] + (  ) log a(k) = b 0 + b 1 log [Y – T(k)] + b 2 log a(k)

Regression analysis w/ PS log p(k) = (1/  ) log (C/V*) + (1/  ) log [Y – T(k)] + (  ) log a(k) = b 0 + b 1 log [Y – T(k)] + b 2 log a(k) In an open city, since V* is fixed, a change in a(k) will predict change in log p(k). In closed city V*  V**. Must know what happens to a(k) all over city. Gen’l eq’m model is necessary. SO: Changes in aggregate land values correspond to WTP only with an open city model. Eq’m rent schedule will give enough information to identify demand for a(k), all else equal; in “closed city” all else may not be equal.