Command-and-Control Strategies: The Case of Standards

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Getting More for Four Principles for Comprehensive Emissions Trading Jan Mazurek, Director Center for Innovation and the Environment 2002 Environmental.
Advertisements

Copyright © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 16 Stationary-Source Local Air Pollution.
The Economics of Environmental Regulations Pollution Tax and Markets for Transferable Pollution Permits.
1 Chapter 14 Practice Quiz Environmental Economics.
Incentive-Based Strategies: Emission Charges and Subsidies
Incentive-Based Strategies: Transferable Discharge Permits Chapter 13.
Ch 14 Part III. 2 Cost-Effective Policies for Fund Pollutants Defining a Cost-Effective Allocation.
THE ECONOMICS OF ENVIRONMENTAL QUALITY
Criteria for Evaluating Environmental Policies
Topic 3.b: Emissions taxes
1 Module 2: Promoting Compliance with Environmental Law.
10 Externalities.
Economic Solutions to Environmental Problems: The Market Approach
1 Topic 2: Production Externalities Examples of types of abatement activities analyzed: –Output reduction –Cleaner production involving  VC (ex: input-switching)
Policy for Market failure Prescriptive/Command and Control Strategies: “Standards”
Chapter 4 Conventional Solutions to Environmental Problems Command-and-Control Approach © 2007 Thomson Learning/South-Western Callan and Thomas, Environmental.
1 Topic 2: Production Externalities So far we have only considered policies that reduce pollution by reducing output. Indirect way to reduce environmental.
1 Topic 3.c: Transferable emission permits We will start analyzing the last policy we will look at for pollution control. –Tradable/transferable emission.
ERE10: Instruments of Environmental Policy Criteria, incl. cost-effectiveness Instruments –Institutional –Command and control –Market based A comparison.
 Homework #3 Due Thursday  Quiz #2 Next Thursday Sept. 29th  Homework #4 Due Tuesday Oct. 11  Exam #2 Tuesday Oct. 11  Writing Assignment Due Oct.
Uncertainty, Monitoring & Enforcement Using economic models to help inform which instruments are most effective at controlling pollution.
26 Prepared by: Fernando Quijano and Yvonn Quijano © 2004 Prentice Hall Business PublishingPrinciples of Economics, 7/eKarl Case, Ray Fair The Labor Market,
Economics of Pollution Control: An Overview
Spatial Dimensions of Environmental Regulations What happens to simple regulations when space matters? Hotspots? Locational differences?
Regulatory Options & Efficiency What guidance can economics provide about how to regulate polluting industries or firms?
The Economics of Environmental Regulation Public Regulation or the Market.
Chapter 4 Conventional Solutions to Environmental Problems: The Command-and-Control Approach © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western.
Environmental Economics Class 7. Incentive Based Regulation: Basic Concepts Up to this point, the focus has been on resource allocation. Since the use.
1 Topic 3.a: Introduction At the end of Topic 2 we identified the efficient level of abatement/emissions. The question of policy is: What policies can.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin © 2006 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., All Rights Reserved. The Competitive Firm Chapter 7.
Chapter 11 Pricing Issues in Channel Management.
Class 7 Environmental Policy Tools
Market-Based Instruments with Chinese Characteristics: The Feasibility of Cap-and-Trade Implementation to Reduce SO 2 Emissions in China and the Role of.
Research on ‘Emissions Trade’ By Sarah Jang Research on ‘Emissions Trade’ By Sarah Jang.
Chapter 4 Conventional Solutions to Environmental Problems: Command-and-Control Approach.
Policy for Market failure Prescriptive/Command and Control Strategies: “Standards”
Copyright © 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 17 The Economics of Environmental Protection.
Reclaimed Wastewater Quality Criteria, Standards, and Guidelines
Command-and-Control Strategies: The Case of Standards Chapter 11.
Across the country, countless people have protested, even risking arrest, against the Keystone XL Pipeline. (Credit: modification of image by “NoKXL”/Flickr.
Air Quality Management Comparison of Cap-and-Trade, Command-and Control and Rate-Based Programs Dr. Ruben Deza Senior Environmental Engineer Clean Air.
Unit 7 Vote for Pedro!!!. Who should control environmental- quality decision making??? Public sector (government)? Private sector (businesses & individuals)?
Lecture: 5 Development and Environmental Economics By Miss Pratiti Singha, Assistant Professor(Part Time), Department of Economics, Radhamadhab College,
© 2013 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license.
SM Sec.1 Dated 13/11/10 STRATEGY & STRUCTURE Group 3.
Command And Control Strategies: The Case of Standards Lecture 18.
Copyright © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 13 Economics of Pollution Control: An Overview.
> > > > The Behavior of Profit-Maximizing Firms Profits and Economic Costs Short-Run Versus Long-Run Decisions The Bases of Decisions: Market Price of.
FACULTY OF LAW, UNIVERSITY OF OSLO The principle of integration and its dilemmas Hans Chr. Bugge Professor of Environmental Law University of Oslo.
Uncertainty, Monitoring & Enforcement Using economic models to help inform which instruments are most effective at controlling pollution.
1 Environmental taxation under imperfect competition within electricity auctions with dominant firm Francesco Gullì Università Bocconi, Milano International.
Topic 6 : Incentive Based Strategies
Topic 7 Transferable Discharge Permits. CASE-AGAINST-CAP-AND-TRADE.HTML The Case For and Against.
An Intro to the Economics of Climate Policy
A General Model of Pollution Control
Gov’t Solutions for Pollution
Topic 5: Public Policy Instruments
Effluents Standards In Pakistan Environmental protection agency (EPA) is responsible for all aspects of the environment; regulation of sanitation and.
Production and Cost in the Firm
Economics of Pollution Control: An Overview
C h a p t e r 3 EXTERNALITIES AND GOVERNMENT POLICY
A General Model of Pollution Control
Environmental and Natural Resource Economics
Environmental and Natural Resource Economics 3rd ed. Jonathan M
Economics of Pollution Control: An Overview
AIR Quality Control Concepts
Incentive Based Strategies: Transferable Discharge Permits
The Economics of Environmental Quality
Session 7: Public Policy Instruments
Presentation transcript:

Command-and-Control Strategies: The Case of Standards Chapter 11

Command and Control A command-and-control (CAC) approach mandates the behavior in law, then uses whatever enforcement machinery—courts, police, fines, and so on—are necessary to get people to obey the law. In the case of environmental policy, the command-and-control approach consists of relying on standards of various types to bring about improvements in environmental quality.

Standards An emission (performance) standard is a maximum rate of emissions that is legally allowed. If you want people not to do something, simply pass a law that makes it illegal, then send out the authorities to enforce the law.

Illustrating Standards Figure 11-1 shows marginal abatement costs and marginal damages related to the rate at which some production residual is emitted. Suppose that initially the actual level of effluent is at e1, a rate substantially above the efficient rate of e*. To achieve e* the authorities set an emission standard at that level; e* becomes a mandated upper limit for the emissions of this firm.

Compliance Costs Assuming the firm reduces emissions in accordance with the standard, it would be incurring an amount equivalent to area a per year in total abatement costs. These total abatement costs are the compliance costs of meeting the standard.

Popularity of Standards Standards are popular for a number of reasons. They appear to be simple and direct. They apparently set clearly specified targets. Standards also appear to be congenial to our ethical sense that pollution is bad and ought to be declared illegal. The legal system is geared to operate by defining and stopping illegal behavior, and the standards approach conforms to this mindset.

Types of Standards There are three main types of environmental standards: ambient, emission, and technology. Ambient Standards Ambient environmental quality refers to the qualitative dimensions of the surrounding environment. Ambient standards are normally expressed in terms of average concentration levels over some period of time.

Emission Standards Emission standards are never-exceed levels applied directly to the quantities of emissions coming from pollution sources. Emission (or effluent) standards are normally expressed in terms of quantity of material per some unit of time; for example, grams per minute or tons per week. Standards may set upper limits on the quantity of flow per minute the average flow over some time period.

Link Between Emissions and Ambient Quality The link between emissions and ambient quality also can be vitally affected by human decisions. A classic case is automobiles. As part of the mobile-source air-pollution program, emission standards have been set for new cars in terms of emissions per mile of operation. No effective way of controlling either the number of cars on the roads or the total number of miles each is driven, so total pollution and, thus, ambient air quality, is not directly controlled.

Variety of Emission Standards 1) Emission rate (e.g., pounds per hour). 2) Emission concentration (e.g., parts per million of biochemical oxygen demand, or BOD, in wastewater). 3) Total quantity of residuals (rate of discharge times concentration times duration). 4) Residuals produced per unit of output (e.g., SO2 emissions per kilowatt-hour of electricity produced). 5) Residuals content per unit of input (e.g., SO2 emissions per ton of coal burned in power generation). 6) Percentage removal of pollutant (e.g., 60 percent removal of waste material before discharge).

Performance Standards In the language of regulation, emission standards are a type of performance standard because they refer to end results that are meant to be achieved by the polluters who are regulated.

Technology Standards There are numerous standards that don't actually specify some end result, but rather the technologies, techniques, or practices that potential polluters must adopt. The requirement that cars be equipped with catalytic converters, or seat belts, is a technology standard. If all electric utilities were required to install stack-gas scrubbers to reduce SO2 emissions, these would be in effect technology standards because a particular type of technology is being specified by central authorities.

Emission vs. Technology Standards The basic point of differentiation is that a performance standard, such as an emission standard, sets a constraint on some performance criterion and then allows people to choose the best means of achieving it. A technology standard actually dictates certain decisions and techniques to be used, such as particular equipment or operating practices to be used by polluters.

The Economics of Standards It would seem to be a simple and straightforward thing to achieve better environmental quality by applying standards of various types. Standards appear to give regulators a degree of positive control to get pollution reduced, but standards turn out to be more complicated than they first appear.

Any Hope of Finding e*? Standards are established through a political/administrative process that may account for all kinds of considerations. The most fundamental question is whether, in setting standards, authorities should take into account only damages or both damages and abatement costs.

“Zero-Risk” is Not Efficient A principle used in some environmental laws has been to set the standard at a "zero-risk" level—a level that would protect everyone, no matter how sensitive, from damage. This would imply setting emission standards at the threshold level, labeled et in Figure 11-1.

Balancing with Abatement Costs The standard might instead be set at a level that accepts a "reasonably small" amount of damages, for example, e0, the point where the marginal damage function begins to increase very rapidly. Again, this would be setting the standard without regard to abatement costs. A different logic might suggest that in setting the standard, damages ought to be balanced with abatement costs.

Uniformity of Standards A very practical problem in standard setting is whether it should be applied uniformly to all situations or varied according to circumstances. This can be illustrated by using the problem of the spatial uniformity of standards. The ambient air-quality standards in the United States, for example, are essentially national. The problem with this is that regions may differ greatly in terms of the factors affecting damage and abatement cost relationships.

Seeking Efficiency? A single, uniform standard cannot be efficient simultaneously in the two regions. If it is set at eU it will be overly stringent for the rural area, and if it is set at er it will not be tight enough for the urban region. The only way to avoid this would be to set different standards in the two areas. Policy trade-offs: The more a policy is tailored so that it applies to different and heterogeneous situations, the more efficient it will be in terms of its impacts, but also the more costly it will be to set and enforce them.

Standards and the Equimarginal Principle We need to remember that the efficient level itself is defined by the minimum marginal abatement cost function. This means that, where there are multiple emissions sources producing the same effluent, the equimarginal principle must hold.

Marginalism In order to get the greatest reductions in total emissions for a given total abatement cost, the different sources of emissions must have the same marginal abatement costs. This means that different sources of a pollutant would normally be controlled to different degrees, depending on the shape of the marginal abatement cost curve at each source.

Problem of Standards A major problem with standards is that there is almost always an overwhelming tendency for authorities to apply the same standards to all sources. It makes their regulatory lives much simpler, and it gives the impression of being fair to everyone because all are apparently being treated alike. But identical standards will be cost-effective only in the unlikely event that all polluters have the same marginal abatement costs.

Standards and Incentives in the Short Run Standards are likely to be neither efficient nor cost effective. A basic problem is that standards are all-or- nothing—either they are being met or they are not. If they are being met, there is no incentive to do better than the standard, even though the costs of further emission reductions may be quite modest. By the same token, the incentives are to meet the standards, even though the last few units of emission reduction may be much more costly than the damages reduced.

Perverse Incentives Standards in practice tend to take decision flexibility away from polluters. This is certainly the case with technology standards, which dictate the procedures that polluters must follow, even though other procedures may be available to achieve the goal at lower cost. Polluters will avoid other techniques in order to protect themselves against charges of non-compliance, even if these other approaches show considerable promise.

Standards and Incentives in the Long Run Technology Standards provide no incentive to find cheaper ways of reducing emissions. Emission (performance) Standards provide strong incentives to find cheaper ways of reducing emissions. See Figure 11-4.

Political-Economic Aspects of Standards Standards are often set under political give- and-take. Technology forcing is to set standards that are costly with today's technology in the hope that it will motivate the pollution-control industry to invent ways of meeting the standard at reasonable cost. But stricter standards also create another incentive: the incentive for polluters to seek relief from public authorities by delaying the date when they become applicable.

Pollution Control Industry The incentives of pollution-control policy for technological change depend on policies. Technology standards substantially reduce incentives for entrepreneurs in the pollution-control industry to develop new ideas. Representatives of the pollution-control industry favor stricter emission (performance) standards, as their fortunes are tied directly to the degree of stringency in the emissions standards set by public authorities.

The Economics of Enforcement The typical pollution-control law calls for emissions reduction from current levels or the adoption of specified pollution-control technologies. Ex ante, penalties will be sufficient to produce complete compliance, but this is in fact never the case. Pollution-control laws, like any others, require enforcement.

Enforcing Emission Standards Consider Figure 11.5. Crossing the MAC function is a marginal penalty function. MPC represents the expected penalties that firms can be expected to face for violating an emission standard. Penalties arise when firms are detected to be exceeding their emission standard.

Avoiding Penalty? Suppose a standard is set at e*. MPC is zero below e*, the firm is only penalized for emissions in excess of the standard, and the shape of the MPC curve shows how penalties would increase as the size of the violation increases. If current emissions are at e0, the firm will clearly reduce them because marginal abatement costs at this point are well below the marginal penalty costs currently in effect.

Noncompliance Firm stops reducing emissions at e1. Abatement costs are higher than penalties. Unless something changes, the firm's emissions will end up at e1, and the amount of noncompliance will be e* - e1. In many cases, fines have been set too low—lower than the abatement costs required to meet the standards.

Enforcing Technology Standards Initial compliance means a polluter installs the appropriate equipment. Inspectors visit the site, check to see that the equipment is installed, and make sure it will operate in accordance with the conditions of the standard. The administering agency can then give the firm the necessary operating permit. Does not ensure that the equipment will continue to be operated in the future in accordance with the terms of the permit.

Monitoring Compliance Device may deteriorate through normal use, it may not be maintained properly, future operating personnel may not be properly trained, and so on. Without some amount of monitoring, there is no assurance that the source will continue to be in compliance.

Trade-Offs Standards often are set by national authorities; enforcement is usually done by local authorities. There can be a great deal of informal give-and-take between the authorities and local plant managers, with participation by local environmental groups as well. One of the advantages (some might say disadvantages) of policies using standards is that they permit flexibility in enforcement.

Summary Standards (especially technology standards) are not cost-effective. Pollution control can be cost-effective only when marginal abatement costs are equalized across sources. In practice, differences among sources in their marginal abatement costs may be recognized informally by local administrators in applying a uniform national standard.