1 The Psychology and Economics of Household Investment Decisions David Laibson Harvard University and NBER July 2008.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Chapter 16 Retirement Planning Looking Ahead Sound retirement planning involves understanding: –Threats to secure retirement –Options available to protect.
Advertisements

Decision Theory. Plan for today (ambitious) 1.Time inconsistency problem 2.Riskiness measures and gambling wealth  Riskiness measures – the idea and.
PROCRASTINATION, PRESENT-BIASED PREFERENCES AND FINANCIAL BEHAVIORS Jeffrey R. Brown University of Illinois and NBER Alessandro Previtero Ivey Business.
1 The Psychology and Economics of Household Investment Decisions David Laibson Lecture 3 AEA January 2010.
1 Household finance David Laibson July 8, Nine claims about household finance Households: 1. Have low levels of financial literacy 2. Have very.
Social Security Literacy and Retirement Well-Being Hugo Benítez-Silva (SUNY-Stony Brook) Berna Demiralp (Old Dominion University) Zhen Liu (SUNY-Buffalo)
1 Who Chooses Defined Contribution Plans? Jeffrey R. Brown University of Illinois and NBER Scott J. Weisbenner University of Illinois and NBER RRC Annual.
Retirement Benefit Seminar
John Beshears James J. Choi Christopher Clayton Christopher Harris David Laibson Brigitte C. Madrian August 8, 2014.
MBAO Executive Compensation Executive Retirement Benefits Purpose of Retirement Benefits Income replacement at retirement Maintain standard of living.
Behavioral Finance David Laibson Robert I. Goldman Professor of Economics Harvard College Professor Harvard University National Bureau of Economic Research.
Highlights of Your Company Retirement Plan. 2 Eligibility Who Is Eligible for the Plan? You can join the Plan when you are age age or older and have completed.
Chapter 22: TAXATION AND SAVINGS – THEORY AND EVIDENCE
Dividend Policy and Retained Earnings (Chapter 18) Optimal Dividend Policy Conflicting Theories Other Dividend Policy Issues Residual Dividend Theory Stable.
Can We Control Our Selves? David Laibson Robert I. Goldman Professor of Economics Harvard University March 27, 2013.
Lesson 16 Investing for Retirement. Key Terms  401(k) Plan  Annuity  Defined-Benefit Plan  Defined- Contribution Plan  Employer- Sponsored Retirement.
Sample XYZ Company Employee 401(k) Retirement Plan Transamerica Insurance & Investments.
0 Conference on “How to Increase the Effectiveness of Financial Education” at Dartmouth College Published in the Journal of Behavioral Finance, 2005, Vol.
L9: Consumption, Saving, and Investments 1 Lecture 9: Consumption, Saving, and Investments The following topics will be covered: –Consumption and Saving.
What Must You Know to Determine Retirement Savings Needs? 6 key questions.
Basic Tools of Finance Finance is the field that studies how people make decisions regarding the allocation of resources over time and the handling of.
Behavioral Finance: Investment mistakes and solutions David Laibson Professor of Economics Harvard University National Bureau of Economic Research June,
David Laibson Robert I. Goldman Professor of Economics Harvard University Behavioral Economics and Behavior Change Second National Summit on Pension Reform.
Your Retirement Your Retirement: Plan Today. Play Tomorrow About this presentation: This presentation includes the following plan: FedEx Kinko’s.
Save More Tomorrow Nudge, Chapter 6 Behavioral Economics Udayan Roy.
PERSONAL FINANCE EDUCATION AND LIFE-CYCLE WEALTH AN ESSENTIAL LITERACY.
5.1 Savings and Investing 5.2 The Rule of 72 Getting Started.
The Age of Reason: Financial Decisions Over the Lifecycle Sumit Agarwal Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago John Driscoll Federal Reserve Board Xavier Gabaix.
Welcome. Workshop Objectives Introduce Introduce Educate Educate Illustrate Illustrate.
CHAPTER 14: MEETING RETIREMENT GOALS 14-2 Pitfalls in Retirement Planning  Starting too late.  Putting away too little.  Investing too conservatively.
Taxes, Inflation, and Investment Strategy
Lecture 1: Instant Gratification
PENSIONS IN TRANSITION: United States and Japan Robert L. Clark Professor of Economics North Carolina State University 19 September, 2002.
 Saving is income not spent.  Saving also includes reducing spending, such as recurring costs.  Savings can include a relatively low-risk investment.
Pay Yourself First.
401(k)’s can partially solve two more public policy problems Brookings Institution September 18, 2015 John Beshears, Harvard Business School James Choi,
Take Charge of Your Money when you leave your job LFD [Presenter's Name] [Presenter's Title] [Presenter's Firm Information] [Date of Presentation]
Planning INFLATION- the general rise in price of goods and services (savings must exceed) You have to have a plan for retirement Years ago companies had.
Estimating pension discount rates David McCarthy.
Introduction to Saving. Saving Basics Savings is the portion of current income not spent on consumption. Recommended to have a minimum of 3-6 months salary.
Copyright © 2004 South-Western 27 The Basic Tools of Finance.
Chapter 3 Arbitrage and Financial Decision Making
The Role of Annuities in Public Retirement Systems Jeffrey R. Brown Presentation to World Bank May 3, 2002.
$100 Dollar Bills on the Sidewalk: Sub Optimal Savings in 401(k) Plans (Choi et al., 2005) Presented By Sylvia Sirivar and Ruth Gbor.
What is a 401K plan? It is a savings account in which employers can help their employee save for retirement while reducing taxable income, and workers.
© 2008 Morningstar, Inc. All rights reserved. 3/1/2008 LCN Role of Immediate Annuities in Retirement.
Optimal Defaults David Laibson Harvard University July, 2008.
Understanding Employer's Stock Holdings in the French Company Savings Plans (CSP) Using the Literature on the American 401(k) plans III rd Performance.
MORE FACTS ABOUT INVESTING PERSONAL FINANCE. EMERGENCY FUNDS  An ___________account needs to have a high degree of _______ and __________.  High safety.
Switching from NEST to PFG Retirement Plan David Berry Group Pensions Manager.
Shares of Oppenheimer funds are not deposits or obligations of any bank, are not guaranteed by any bank, are not insured by the FDIC or any other agency.
HIDDEN DESCRIPTION SLIDE — NOT TO BE SHOWN TO THE PUBLIC Financial Facts Catalogue code: B07 Full presentation or module? Presentation Slide numbers: B07-1.
1 Individual Account Investment Options and Portfolio Choice: Behavioral Lessons from 401(k) Plans.
Is There Evidence Workers Are Rational in Preparing for Retirement? by Gary Burtless Senior Fellow and Whitehead Chair in Economics The Brookings Institution.
Investment Strategies for Women Robin Kahl Vice President Davenport & Company, LLC
Chapter 1 Overview of a Financial Plan. Copyright ©2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All rights reserved.1-2 Chapter Objectives Explain how you benefit from.
Presentation to the Oregon Retirement Security Board Anek Belbase and Geoffrey Sanzenbacher Center for Retirement Research at Boston College March 2015.
Discussion of Thaler and Benartzi, Save More Tomorrow: Using Behavioral Economics to Increase Employee Saving JOURNAL OF POLITICAL ECONOMY, 2004.
Ratio Analysis…. Types of ratios…  Performance Ratios: Return on capital employed. (Income Statement and Balance Sheet) Gross profit margin (Income Statement)
1 Household finance David Laibson April 13, 2016.
Revolutionizing Global Leadership
Frames, Defaults, and Nudges with Applications to Household Finance
Types of Financial Institutions, Interest Spread, Risk/Return Relationship, and Savings options SSEPF2:a-d.
David Laibson Harvard University January, 2010 AEA Mini-course
How are preferences revealed?
How Are Preferences Revealed? Beshears, Choi, Laibson, Madrian (2008)
The Fundamentals of Investing
How to Plan Your Retirement Retirement Planning. Planning Your Retirement Retiring past your full retirement age allows you to receive full Social Security.
Financial Institutions
Presentation transcript:

1 The Psychology and Economics of Household Investment Decisions David Laibson Harvard University and NBER July 2008

Should Defaults Influence Economic Outcomes? Standard neoclassical theory: If transactions costs are small and stakes are large, defaults should not influence rational consumers. In practice, defaults make an enormous difference: Organ donation (Johnson and Goldstein 2003) Car insurance Car purchase options Consent to receive marketing Savings Asset allocation

3 US: Rising Role of DC Plans Private-Sector Workers Only 10% 30% 50% 70% Pension type (as a proportion of all pensioned workers) Only

Outline 1. Defaults affect all saving and asset allocation outcomes 2. Four psychological factors jointly contribute to the default effect 3. Alternative interventions are much less influential than defaults This morning’s lecture: facts quasi-positive, since some facts have a normative flavor This afternoon’s lecture: normative mechanism design

1. Defaults Affect Saving and Asset Allocation i. Participation ii. Contribution rates iii. Asset allocation iv. Pre-retirement distributions v. Decumulation / annuitization

Participation, Contribution rates, and Asset Allocation Automatic Enrollment in a US 401(k) plan Welcome to the company If you don’t do anything… You are automatically enrolled in the 401(k) You save 2% of your pay Your contributions go into a money market fund Call this phone number to opt out of enrollment or change your investment allocations

Madrian and Shea (2001) Choi, Laibson, Madrian, Metrick (2004) Hired before AE Hired after AE ended Hired during AE

Employees enrolled under auto-enrollment cluster at the default contribution rate. Default contribution rate under automatic enrollment

Participants stay at the automatic enrollment defaults for a long time.

Automatic enrollment: Conclusions Automatic enrollment dramatically increases 401(k) participation Participants hired under automatic enrollment tend to stay at the automatic enrollment defaults Similar default effects are observed for cash distributions at separation saving rates at match thresholds Auto-escalation and SMART (Benartzi and Thaler)

11 Do workers “like” automatic enrollment? In firms with standard 401(k) plans (no auto-enrollment), 2/3 of workers say that they should save more Opt-out rates under automatic enrollment are typically only 15% (opt-out rates rarely exceed 20%) Under automatic enrollment employers report “no complaints” in 401(k) plans 97% of employees in auto-enrollment firms approve of auto- enrollment. Even among workers who opt out of automatic enrollment, approval is 79%. Even the glacial US government is about to adopt automatic enrollment.

Additional evidence on Asset Allocation Private account component of Swedish Social Security system (Cronqvist and Thaler, 2004) At inception, one-third of assets are invested in the default fund Subsequent enrollees invest 90% of assets in the default fund Company match in employer stock (Choi, Laibson and Madrian, 2005b, 2007)

The Flypaper Effect in Individual Investor Asset Allocation (Choi, Laibson, Madrian 2007) Studied a firm that used several different match systems in their 401(k) plan. I’ll discuss two of those regimes today: Match allocated to employer stock and workers can reallocate Call this “default” case (default is employer stock) Match allocated to an asset actively chosen by workers; workers required to make an active designation. Call this “no default” case (workers must choose) Economically, these two systems are identical. They both allow workers to do whatever the worker wants.

14 Consequences of the two regimes Default ES No Default Own Balance in Employer Stock 24%20% Matching Balance in Employer Stock 94%27% Total Balance in Employer Stock 56%22% Balances in employer stock

Cash Distributions What happens to savings plan balances when employees leave their jobs? Employees can request a cash distribution or roll balances over into another account Balances >$5000: default leaves balances with former employer Balances <$5000: default distributes balances as cash transfer Vast majority of employees accept default (Choi et al. 2002, 2004a and 2004b) When employees receive small cash distributions, balances typically consumed (Poterba, Venti and Wise 1998)

Post-Retirement Distributions Social Security Joint and survivor annuity (reduced benefits) Defined benefit pension Annuity Lump sum payout if offered Defined contribution savings plan Lump sum payout Annuity if offered

Defined Benefit Pension Annuitization Annuity income and economic welfare of the elderly Social Security replacement rate relatively low on average 17% of women fall into poverty after the death of their spouse (Holden and Zick 2000) For married individuals, three distinct annuitization regimes Pre-1974: no regulation ERISA I (1974): default joint-and-survivor annuity with option to opt-out ERISA II (1984 amendment): default joint-and-survivor annuity, opting out required notarized permission of spouse

Defined Benefit Pension Annuitization Effect of joint-and-survivor default on annuitization Pre-1974: Less than half of married men have joint-and-survivor annuity Post-ERISA (I + II): joint-and-survivor annuitization increases 25 percentage points (Holden and Nicholson 1998) Post-1984 amendments: joint-and-survivor annuitization increases 5 to 10 percentage points (Saku 2001)

i. Financial illiteracy ii. Endorsement iii. Complexity iv. Present-bias Four psychological factors contribute to the default effect

i. Financial illiteracy John Hancock Financial Services Defined Contribution Plan Survey (2002) 38% of respondents report that they have little or no financial knowledge 40% of respondents believe that a money market fund contains stocks Two-thirds of respondents don’t know that it is possible to lose money in government bonds Respondents on average believe that employer stock is less risky than a stock mutual fund Two-thirds report that they would be better off working with an investment advisor than managing investments solo

Subjects allocate $10,000 among four funds Randomly choose two subjects to receive any positive portfolio return during the subsequent year Eliminate variation in pre-fee returns Choose among S&P 500 index funds Unbundle services from returns Experimenters pay out portfolio returns, so no access to investment company services Financial illiteracy among Wharton MBA’s Choi, Laibson, Madrian (2006)

One year of index fund fees on a $10,000 investment

Experimental conditions Control Subjects receive only four prospectuses Prospectuses are often the only information investors receive from companies Fees transparency treatment Eliminate search costs by also distributing fee summary sheet (repeats information in prospectus) Returns treatment Highlight extraneous information by distributing summary of funds’ annualized returns since inception (repeats information in prospectus)

Fees paid by control groups (prospectus only) Minimum Possible Fee Maximum Possible Fee t-test: p= N = 83 N = 30 $443: average fee with random fund allocation 0% of College Controls put all funds in minimum-fee fund 6% of MBA Controls put all funds in minimum-fee fund

Ranking of factor importance MBA controls 1. Fees 2. 1-year performance 3. Performance since inception 4. Investment objectives 5. Desire to diversify among funds 6. Brand recognition 7. Performance over different horizon 8. Past experience with fund companies 9. Quality of prospectus 10. Customer service of fund 11. Minimum opening balance College controls 1. 1-year performance 2. Performance since inception 3. Desire to diversify among funds 4. Investment objectives 5. Quality of prospectus 6. Performance over different horizon 7. Brand recognition 8. Fees 9. Customer service of fund 10. Minimum opening balance 11. Past experience with fund companies

Effect of fee treatment (prospectus plus 1-page sheet highlighting fees) t-tests: MBA: p= College: p= N = 83 N = 30N = 29N = 85 ** 10% of College treatment put all funds in minimum-fee fund 19% of MBA treatment put all funds in minimum-fee fund

Ranking of factor importance MBA fee treatment 1. Fees 2. 1-year performance 3. Performance since inception MBA controls 1. Fees 2. 1-year performance 3. Performance since inception College fee treatment 1. Fees 2. 1-year performance 3. Performance since inception College controls 1. 1-year performance 2. Performance since inception 3. Desire to diversify among funds

Returns treatment effect on average returns since inception N = 83 N = 30N = 28N = 84 t-tests MBA: p= College: p= **

Returns treatment effect on fees N = 83 N = 30N = 28N = 84 t-tests MBA: p= College: p= **

Ranking of factor importance MBA return treatment 1. 1-year performance 2. Performance since inception 3. Fees MBA controls 1. Fees 2. 1-year performance 3. Performance since inception College return treatment 1. Performance since inception 2. 1-year performance 3. Desire to diversify among funds College controls 1. 1-year performance 2. Performance since inception 3. Desire to diversify among funds

Lack of confidence and fees N = 64N = 46N = 36N = 136 t-tests: MBA 1 vs. 2, p=0.2013; MBA 1 vs. 3, p=0.0479; College 1 vs. 2, p=0.2864; College 1 vs. 3, p= N = 50N = 5 *

32 We conducted a similar experiment with Harvard staff as subjects In this new version we have 400 subjects (administrators, faculty assistants, technical personal, but not faculty) We give every one of our subjects $10,000 and rewarded them with any gains on their investment $4,000,000 short position in stock market

33 Data from Harvard Staff Control Treatment Fee Treatment 3% of Harvard staff in Control Treatment put all $$$ in low-cost fund 9% of Harvard staff in Fee Treatment put all $$$ in low-cost fund $494 $518 Fees from random allocation $431

ii. Endorsement A non-zero default is perceived as advice Evidence Elective employer stock allocation in firms that do and do not match in employer stock (Benartzi 2001, Holden and Vanderhei 2001, and Brown, Liang and Weisbenner 2006) Asset allocation of employees hired before automatic enrollment (Choi, Laibson, Madrian 2006)

Asset Allocation Outcomes of Employees Who are Not Subject to Automatic Enrollment Any balances in default fund All balances in default fund Company D Hired before, participated before AE13%2% Choi, Laibson, and Madrian (2007)

Asset Allocation Outcomes of Employees Who are Not Subject to Automatic Enrollment Any balances in default fund All balances in default fund Company D Hired before, participated before AE13%2% Hired before, participated after AE29%16% Choi, Laibson, and Madrian (2007)

Automatic Enrollment and Asset Allocation Outcomes Any balances in default fund All balances in default fund Company A Hired before AE9.8%1.4% Hired after AE: non-default Company D Hired before AE18.2%5.2% Hired after AE: non-default

Automatic Enrollment and Asset Allocation Outcomes Any balances in default fund All balances in default fund Company A Hired before AE9.8%1.4% Hired after AE: non-default86.1%61.1% Company D Hired before AE18.2%5.2% Hired after AE: non-default71.3%30.8%

iii. Complexity Complexity  delay Psychology literature (Tversky and Shafir 1992, Shafir, Simonson and Tversky 1993, Dhar and Knowlis 1999, Iyengar and Lepper 2000 ) Savings literature: each additional 10 funds produces a 1.5 to 2.0 percentage point decline in participation (Iyengar, Huberman and Jiang 2004) Also results on complexity generating more conservative asset allocation (Iyengar and Kamenica 2007). Quick enrollment experiments

Complexity and Quick Enrollment Conceptual Idea Simplify the savings plan enrollment decision by giving employees an easy way to elect a pre-selected contribution rate and asset allocation bundle Implementation at Company D New hires at employee orientation: 2% contribution rate invested 50% money market & 50% stable value Implementation at Company E Existing non-participants: 3% contribution rate invested 100% in money market fund

41 Complexity and Quick Enrollment Conceptual Idea Simplify the savings plan enrollment decision by giving employees an easy way to elect a pre-selected contribution rate and asset allocation bundle Implementation at Company D New hires at employee orientation: 2% contribution rate invested 50% money market / 50% stable value Existing non-participants: employee selects contribution rate invested 50% money market / 50% stable value Implementation at Company E Existing non-participants: 3% contribution rate invested 100% in money market fund

Quick Enrollment and Savings Plan Participation

Simplified enrollment raises participation Beshears, Choi, Laibson, Madrian (2006)

iv. Present-Biased Preferences Self control problems undermine good savings intentions Why do today what you can put off until tomorrow Strotz (1957), Phelps and Pollak (1968), Akerlof (1991), Laibson (1997), O’Donoghue and Rabin (1999), Diamond and Koszegi (2003)

45 Formal Model Quasi-hyperbolic discounting Phelps and Pollak 1968, Laibson 1997 D(t) = 1,      U t = u t +  u t+1   u t+2   u t+3  U t = u t +  u t+1   u t+2   u t+3    uniformly discounts all future periods.   exponentially discounts all future periods.  Short-run rate of decline is approximately 1 – .  Long-run rate of decline is approximately 1- .

46 Building intuition To build intuition, assume that  = ½ and  = 1. Discounted utility function becomes U t = u t + ½  u t+1  u t+2  u t+3  Discounted utility from the perspective of time t+1. U t+1 = u t+1 + ½  u t+2  u t+3  Discount function reflects dynamic inconsistency: preferences held at date t do not agree with preferences held at date t+1.

47 Procrastination Akerlof 1991, O’Donoghue and Rabin 1999 Assume that  = ½ and  = 1. Suppose exercise (cost 6) generates delayed benefits (value 8). When will you exercise? Exercise Today: -6 + ½ [8] = -2 Exercise Tomorrow: 0 + ½ [-6 + 8] = 1 Agent would like to make plans today to exercise tomorrow. Agent won’t follow through without commitment.

48 Beliefs about the future? Sophisticates: know that their plans to be patient tomorrow won’t pan out (Strotz, 1957). “I won’t quit smoking next week, though I would like to do so.” Naifs: mistakenly believe that their plans to be patient will be perfectly carried out (Strotz, 1957). Think that β=1 in the future. “I will quit smoking next week, though I’ve failed to do so every week for five years.” Partial naifs: mistakenly believe that β=β * in the future where β < β * < 1 (O’Donoghue and Rabin, 2001).

49 Naifs vs. sophisticates Continue to analyze the earlier exercise example. How often would a naif exercise? How often would a naif predict she would exercise? How often would a sophisticate exercise? How often would a sophisticate predict she would exercise? Would a sophisticate join a gym? What else would a sophisticate do?

50 Self-regulation Ariely and Wertenbroch (2002) Three proofreading tasks: "Sexual identity is intrinsically impossible," says Foucault; however, according to de Selby[1], it is not so much sexual identity that is intrinsically impossible, but rather the dialectic, and some would say the satsis, of sexual identity. Thus, D'Erlette[2] holds that we have to choose between premodern dialectic theory and subcultural feminism imputing the role of the observer as poet. Evenly spaced deadlines. [$20 earnings] Self-imposed deadlines --- subjects in this condition could adopt costly deadlines ($1/day) and most did so. [$13 earnings] End deadline. [$5 earnings]

51 A formal model of procrastination Doing a job costs c units of effort in current period. Each period c is drawn from a uniform distribution on [0,1]. Until job is done, agent losses θ units per period. Suppose δ = 1. Timing: 1. Pay delay cost θ 2. Realize current value of c (drawn from uniform) 3. Decide whether or not to do the task at current cost c 4. If task is not done, period ends and return to step 1.

52 Sophisticated procrastination There are many equilibria of this game. Let’s study the equilibrium in which sophisticates act whenever c < c *. We need to solve for c *. This is sometimes called the action threshold. Let V represent the expected undiscounted cost of waiting (until at least the next period): V = θ + (c * )(c * /2) + (1- c * )V In equilibrium, the sophisticate needs to be exactly indifferent between acting now and waiting. c * = βV = β[θ + (c * )(c * /2) + (1- c * )V] Solving for c *, we find: c * = [θ/(1/β -1/2)] 1/2 So expected delay is 1/ c * = [(1/β -1/2)/θ] 1/2

53 Naive procrastination There is a unique equilibrium of this game. Act whenever c < c N*. We need to solve for c N*. This is sometimes called the action threshold. Let c N** represent the expected future action threshold of the naïve agent. Let V represent the (naively) expected undiscounted cost of waiting (until at least the next period): V = θ + (c N** )(c N** /2) + (1- c N** )V (from last slide) c N** = (2θ) 1/2 (from last slide w/ β=1) V = (2θ) 1/2 (substituting for c N** ) In equilibrium, the naive action threshold is given by c N* = βV = β(2θ) 1/2 So average delay is 1/c N* = 1/β[1/(2θ)] 1/2 > [(1/β -1/2)/θ] 1/2

Laibson, Repetto, and Tobacman (2004) Use MSM to estimate discounting parameters: Substantial illiquid retirement wealth: W/Y = 3.9. Extensive credit card borrowing: 68% didn’t pay their credit card in full last month Average credit card interest rate is 14% Credit card debt averages 13% of annual income Consumption-income comovement: Marginal Propensity to Consume = 0.25 (i.e. consumption tracks income)

LRT Simulation Model Stochastic Income Lifecycle variation in labor supply (e.g. retirement) Social Security system Life-cycle variation in household dependents Bequests Illiquid asset Liquid asset Credit card debt Numerical solution (backwards induction) of 90 period lifecycle problem.

LRT Results: U t = u t +  u t+1   u t+2   u t+3   = 0.70 (s.e. 0.11)  = 0.96 (s.e. 0.01) Null hypothesis of  = 1 rejected (t-stat of 3). Specification test accepted. Moments: Empirical Simulated (Hyperbolic) %Visa: 68%63% Visa/Y: 13%17% MPC: 23%31% f(W/Y):

Illustrative Application without stochastics (assume  ½,  = 1). Suppose you can join the plan today (effort cost $50) to gain delayed benefits $20,000 (e.g. value of match) Every period you delay, total benefits fall by $10. What are the discounted costs of joining at different periods? Join Today: 50 + ½ [0] = 50 Join t+1: 0 + ½ [ ] = 30 Join t+2: 0 + ½ [ ] = 35 Join t+3: 0 + ½ [ ] = 40

58 Interaction with financial illiteracy Consider someone with a high level of financial literacy, so effort cost is only $10 (not $50) As before, every period of delay, total benefits fall by $10. What are the discounted costs of joining at different periods? Join Today: 10 + ½ [0] = 10 Join t+1: 0 + ½ [ ] = 10 Join t+2: 0 + ½ [ ] = 15 Join t+3: 0 + ½ [ ] = 20

59 Interaction with endorsement and complexity Consider a plan with a simple form, or an endorsed form, so the effort cost is again only $10 (not $50) As before, every period of delay, total benefits fall by $10. What are the discounted costs of joining at different periods? Join Today: 10 + ½ [0] = 10 Join t+1: 0 + ½ [ ] = 10 Join t+2: 0 + ½ [ ] = 15 Join t+3: 0 + ½ [ ] = 20

Procrastination in retirement savings Choi, Laibson, Madrian, Metrick (2002) Survey Mailed to 590 employees (random sample) 195 usable responses Matched to administrative data on actual savings behavior Consider a population of 100 employees 68 report saving too little 24 of 68 plan to raise 401(k) contribution in next 2 months Only 3 of 24 actually do so in the next 4 months

4. Alternative Policies Paying employees to save Educating employees

$100 bills on the sidewalk Choi, Laibson, Madrian (2004) Employer match is an instantaneous, riskless return on investment Particularly appealing if you are over 59½ years old Have the most experience, so should be savvy Retirement is close, so should be thinking about saving Can withdraw money from 401(k) without penalty We study seven companies and find that on average, half of employees over 59½ years old are not fully exploiting their employer match Average loss is 1.6% of salary per year Educational intervention has no effect

Financial education Choi, Laibson, Madrian, Metrick (2004) Seminars presented by professional financial advisors Curriculum: Setting savings goals, asset allocation, managing credit and debt, insurance against financial risks Seminars offered throughout 2000 Linked data on individual employees’ seminar attendance to administrative data on actual savings behavior before and after seminar

Effect of education is positive but small Seminar attendeesNon-attendees % planning to make change % actually made change % actually made change Those not in 401(k) Enroll in 401(k) Plan100%14%7% Those already in 401(k) Increase contribution rate28%8%5% Change fund selection47%15%10% Change asset allocation36%10%6%

65 Effect of education is positive but small Seminar attendeesNon-attendees % planning to make change % actually made change % actually made change Those not in 401(k) Enroll in 401(k) Plan100%14%7% Those already in 401(k) Increase contribution rate28%8%5% Change fund selection47%15%10% Change asset allocation36%10%6%

66 Effect of education is positive but small Seminar attendeesNon-attendees % planning to make change % actually made change % actually made change Those not in 401(k) Enroll in 401(k) Plan100%14%7% Those already in 401(k) Increase contribution rate28%8%5% Change fund selection47%15%10% Change asset allocation36%10%6%

Financial education effects are small Seminar attendees have good intentions to change their 401(k) savings behavior, but most do not follow through Financial education alone will not dramatically improve the quality of 401(k) savings outcomes Choi et al (2005) study the effect of the Enron, Worldcom, and Global Crossing scandals on employer stock holding No net sales of employer stock in reaction to these news stories These scandals did not affect the asset allocation decisions of new hires. These hires did not affect the asset allocation decisions of new hires at other Houston firms.

Conclusion Defaults are not neutral for four key reasons: Investors are not financially literate Investors display an endorsement effect Investors respond adversely to complexity Investors are prone to procrastinate There may be other reasons: loss aversion? Employers/institutions will influence savings outcomes through the choice of defaults (whether the institution wants to do this or not) We should devote considerable effort to the analysis of how we pick defaults.

69 END HERE

70 3. Optimal Defaults – public policy Mechanism design problem in which policy makers set a default for agents with present bias (Carrol, Choi, Laibson, Madrian and Metrick 2007) Defaults are sticky for three reasons Cost of opting-out of the default Cost varies over time  option value of waiting Present-biased preferences  procrastination

71 Basic set-up of problem Specify behavioral model of households Flow cost of staying at the default Effort cost of opting-out of the default Effort cost varies over time  option value of waiting to leave the default Present-biased preferences  procrastination Specify (dynamically consistent) social welfare function of planner (e.g., set β=1) Planner picks default to optimize social welfare function

72 Optimal ‘Defaults’ Two classes of optimal defaults Automatic enrollment Optimal when employees have relatively homogeneous savings preferences (e.g. match threshold) and relatively little propensity to procrastinate “Active Decision” — require individuals to make a decision (eliminate the option to passively accept a default) Optimal when employees have relatively heterogeneous savings preferences and relatively strong tendency to procrastinate Key point: sometimes the best default is no default.

1 0 Beta Active Decision Center Default Offset Default 30% 0% Low Heterogeneity High Heterogeneity

74 Lessons from theoretical analysis of defaults Defaults should be set to maximize average well- being, which is not the same as saying that the default should be equal to the average preference. Endogenous opting out should be taken into account when calculating the optimal default. The default has two roles: causing some people to opt out of the default (which generates costs and benefits) implicitly setting savings policies for everyone who sticks with the default

75 The power of deadlines: Active decisions Choi, Laibson, Madrian, Metrick (2007) Active decision mechanisms require employees to make an active choice about 401(k) participation. Welcome to the company You are required to submit this form within 30 days of hire, regardless of your 401(k) participation choice If you don’t want to participate, indicate that decision If you want to participate, indicate your contribution rate and asset allocation Being passive is not an option

76

77 Active decisions: conclusions Active decision raises 401(k) participation. Active decision raises average savings rate by 50 percent. Active decision doesn’t induce choice clustering. Under active decision, employees choose savings rates that they otherwise would have taken three years to achieve. (Average level as well as the entire multivariate covariance structure.)

78 New directions for defaults Defaults for savings rate escalation Defaults with high savings rates Defaults for lifecycle rebalancing Defaults for annual rebalancing Defaults for employer stock Defaults at separation Defaults for annuitization Individualized defaults (savings rate and asset allocation) Defaults for employees not covered by DB/DC plans Defaults for investment of tax refunds

79 Public Policy and Defaults: Annuitization Interesting aspects of the joint-and-survivor Social Security annuity default discussed earlier Differentiated default: singles vs. marrieds Annuity election irrevocable Implicit deadline—must either accept or opt-out of the default before receiving pension payments Note Largely homogenous preferences Similarities to active decision approach Reduced scope for procrastination Those who do opt-out of joint-and-survivor annuity appear to have economically sound reasons for doing so (Johnson, Uccello and Goldwyn 2003)

80 Public Policy and Defaults: Annuitization Thinking more generally about retirement income annuitization and defaults in a defined contribution world Understanding annuitization options is complicated for financial novices  strong endorsement effect likely Taking a lump-sum is the only way to preserve option value BUT, lump-sums  potential self-control problems Annuitization and defined contribution savings plans Required annuitization up to $200,000? Default annuitization up to $200,000? Active decision? (Due to irreversibility.)

81 Public Policy and Defaults: Pre-Retirement Cash Distributions Cash distribution default for balances of less than $5000  leakage from retirement savings Response: for balances of $1000-$5000 Employers can maintain these balances, or Employers can roll them over into an IRA Default asset allocation for IRA rollover must preserve principal

82 Public Policy and Defaults: Match in Employer Stock Employer stock in defined contribution savings plan is only weakly regulated Employer stock in defined benefit pension plan is capped at 10% of total assets Strong evidence that employees misperceive the risks of employer stock (familiarity bias) Policy alternatives Preclude employers from defaulting matching contributions into employer stock (e.g., preclude companies from choosing a single life annuity as a default for married individuals) Create annual default rebalancing out of company stock