Office Hours: Monday 3:00-4:00 – LUMS C86

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Policy & the Perfectly Competitive Model: Consumer & Producer Surplus
Advertisements

Sales and Excise taxes.
4 Economic Efficiency, Government Price Setting, and Taxes CHAPTER
1 Excise Tax. 2 Change in supply If non-price determinants of supply should change the supply curve will shift and we say there has been a change in supply.
Competition and the Market
Supply, Demand, and Government Policies
Chapter Price 6. Objectives: Students will learn… How the market establishes an equilibrium price How the equilibrium price balances supply & demand How.
Combining Supply and Demand (Ch. 6-1)
FALL 2013 Government Intervention in Supply and Demand.
7 Government Influences on Markets CHAPTER
Supply, Demand, and the Price System. Quick Review – the following information should be in your notes already.
Today is your lucky day! You just won $1000!!! Write down at least 5 things that you will buy with your money. ~WARM UP~ WARM UP.
Role of Prices Economics Koehn/Molter. Review A demand schedule shows: – How much consumers are willing to buy a various prices. A supply schedule shows:
An Introduction to International Economics
International Trade Policy
Elasticity! Boingy, boingy, boingy!
Copyright © 2007, Nelson, a division of Thomson Canada Ltd.. A Lecture Presentation in PowerPoint to accompany Exploring Economics by Robert L. Sexton.
Elasticity of Demand and Supply
Market Power: Monopoly and Monopsony
Do You Know How to Calculate on a Graph …?
Office Hours: Monday 3:00-4:00 – LUMS C86
Office Hours: Monday 3:00-4:00 – LUMS C85
Elasticity: Concept & Applications For Demand & Supply.
office hours: 8:00AM – 8:50AM tuesdays LUMS C85
Chapter Sixteen Equilibrium. Market Equilibrium  A market is in equilibrium when total quantity demanded by buyers equals total quantity supplied by.
Chapter 16 Equilibrium.
1 Equilibrium Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 – Spring 2009.
Equilibrium. Market Equilibrium  A market is in equilibrium when total quantity demanded by buyers equals total quantity supplied by sellers.  An equilibrium.
Economic Policies and Efficiency: Exercises and Applications Lecture 6 – academic year 2014/15 Introduction to Economics Fabio Landini.
CHAPTER 7 ANALYSIS OF A TARIFF.
LECTURE #5: MICROECONOMICS CHAPTER 6 Government Intervention Policy Objectives Policy Tools.
M ARKET EQUILIBRIUM. Market equilibrium exists when quantity demanded (Qd) equals quantity supplied (Qs). It can be determined by the intersection between.
1 Analyzing the Economic Impact of Taxes Module 7.
Chapter 1 Supply, Demand and Equilibrium
Chapter Sixteen Equilibrium. Market Equilibrium  A market clears or is in equilibrium when the total quantity demanded by buyers exactly equals the total.
Chapter 9 Use tools of competitive markets to analyze effects of government intervention. Tools (See Figure 9.1): Consumer Surplus = CS: –Difference between.
Chapter Sixteen Equilibrium. Market Equilibrium  A market is in equilibrium when total quantity demanded by buyers equals total quantity supplied by.
Economics Winter 14 February 5 th, 2014 Lecture 11 Ch. 4 Ch. 6 (up to p. 138)
Principles of Microeconomics
Consumer and Producter Surplus Microeconomics. Consumer Surplus  Consumer Surplus is ….  when a consumer pays of price LESS than their maximum willingness.
1 Chapter 4 Supply and Demand: Applications and Extensions.
Chapter 4: Economic Efficiency, Government Price Setting, and Taxes 1 of 33 © 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Economics R. Glenn Hubbard, Anthony.
Chapter 8 The Costs of Taxation Ratna K. Shrestha.
Application: The Cost of Taxation
Micro Chapter 4 Supply and Demand: Applications and Extensions.
Economic Efficiency, Government Price Setting, and Taxes
Chapter 3: Competitive Dynamics How Competitive Markets Operate Market Equilibrium:  The stable point at which demand and supply curves intersect PRICE.
Chapter 6 Supply, Demand and Government Policies
Climbing the Economic Mountain! Section 1 Twelve Key Elements of Economics Supply and Demand Supply and Demand: Applications and Extensions Supply and.
Chapter 8 The Costs of Taxation. Objectives 1. Understand how taxes reduce consumer and producer surplus 2. Learn the causes and significance of the deadweight.
Supply, Demand & Government Policies Chapter 6. In a free market system, market forces establish equilibrium prices and exchange quantities. One of the.
Quiz III Consumer and Producer Surplus. 1. Determine the consumer surplus at the equilibrium price shown below
MARKET EQUILIBRIUM  Market equilibrium exists when quantity demanded (Qd) equals quantity supplied (Qs).
APPLICATIONS OF WELFARE ECONOMICS: THE COST OF TAXATION
Chapter 14 Equilibrium and Efficiency McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved.
Copyright © 2004 South-Western/Thomson Learning Application: The Costs of Taxation Recall that welfare economicsRecall that welfare economics is the study.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 16 Equilibrium.
1 An Introduction to International Economics Second Edition Trade Restrictions: Tariffs Dominick Salvatore John Wiley & Sons, Inc. CHAPTER F I V E.
1 Analyzing the Economic Impact of Taxes Module 7.
©2001Claudia Garcia-Szekely1 The Effect of a Tax Levied on the Producer.
The costs of taxation. Tax Usually taxes are collected because government wants to run the country. Some people believe that all taxation creates market.
Supply and Demand. Making Choices In a market economy like the United States the forces of supply and demand work together to set prices – Demand= the.
Chapter Supply, Demand, and Government Policies 6.
Supply, Demand, and Government Policies
Analyzing the Economic Impact of Taxes
Economic Policies and Efficiency: Exercises and Applications
ALGEBRAIC REPRESENTATION OF SUPPLY, DEMAND, AND EQUILIBRIUM
Chapter 16 Equilibrium.
Chapter Sixteen Equilibrium.
Consumer Surplus Consumer surplus is the value the consumer gets from buying a product, less its price (paying less than you are willing to pay) It is.
Presentation transcript:

Office Hours: Monday 3:00-4:00 – LUMS C86 ECON 101 Tutorial: Week 3 Shane Murphy s.murphy5@lancaster.ac.uk Office Hours: Monday 3:00-4:00 – LUMS C86

Outline Roll Call Problems Discussion

Chapter 7: Exercise 7 Why might we want to think about market price as the outcome of a bargaining model? Market price is really an outcome of the bargaining model. Suppliers are offering goods to consumers at different prices and consumers have to make decisions about whether the prices they are offered represents a net economic benefit to them. There is an interaction between suppliers and consumers, therefore, which can be seen as a bargaining process – an agreed outcome between two interested and competing economic agents. For example suppliers respond to the decisions made by consumers – if too few people buy their product then they will be forced to take action to improve the product offering, lower the price or even drop out of the market altogether.

Chapter 8: Exercise 2 The government has decided that the free market price of tobacco is too low. Suppose the government imposes a binding price floor in the tobacco market. Use a diagram to show the effect on the price and quantity. Is there a shortage or surplus? What does the market outcome depend on? Tobacco producers complain that he price floor has reduced their total revenue. Is this possible? Why? In response to producers’ complaints, the government agrees to purchase all of the surplus tobacco at the price floor. Compared to the basic price floor, who benefits from this new policy? Who loses?

Chapter 8: Exercise 2 The government has decided that the free market price of tobacco is too low. Suppose the government imposes a binding price floor in the tobacco market. Use a diagram to show the effect on the price and quantity. Is there a shortage or surplus? What does the market outcome depend on? The imposition of a binding price floor in the tobacco market is shown. In the absence of the price floor, the price would be P1 and the quantity would be Q1. With the floor set at Pf, which is greater than P1, the quantity demanded is Q2, while quantity supplied is Q3, so there is a surplus of cheese in the amount Q3 – Q2.

Chapter 8: Exercise 2 The government has decided that the free market price of tobacco is too low. Tobacco producers complain that he price floor has reduced their total revenue. Is this possible? Why? The tobacco producers complaint that their total revenue has declined is correct if demand is price elastic. With price elastic demand, the percentage decline in quantity would exceed the percentage rise in price, so total revenue would decline.

Chapter 8: Exercise 2 The government has decided that the free market price of tobacco is too low. In response to producers’ complaints, the government agrees to purchase all of the surplus tobacco at the price floor. Compared to the basic price floor, who benefits from this new policy? Who loses? If the government purchases all the surplus tobacco at the price floor, producers benefit and taxpayers lose. Producers would produce quantity Q3 of tobacco, and their total revenue would increase substantially. But consumers would buy only quantity Q2 of tobacco, so they are in the same position as before. Taxpayers lose because they would be financing the purchase of the surplus tobacco through higher taxes.

Chapter 9: Exercise 6 Suppose that the government subsidizes a good: for each unit of the good sold, the government pays 2 to the buyer. How does the subsidy affect CS, PS, TR, TS? Is the a DL? Figure illustrates the effects of the €2 subsidy on a good. Without the subsidy, the equilibrium price is P1 and the equilibrium quantity is Q1. With the subsidy, buyers pay price PB, producers receive price PS (where PS = PB + €2), and the quantity sold is Q2. The following table illustrates the effect of the subsidy on consumer surplus, producer surplus, government revenue, and total surplus. Since total surplus declines by area D+H, the subsidy leads to a deadweight loss in that amount.

Chapter 9: Exercise 6 Suppose that the government subsidizes a good: for each unit of the good sold, the government pays 2 to the buyer. How does the subsidy affect CS, PS, TR, TS? Is the a DL? Figure illustrates the effects of the €2 subsidy on a good. Without the subsidy, the equilibrium price is P1 and the equilibrium quantity is Q1. With the subsidy, buyers pay price PB, producers receive price PS (where PS = PB + €2), and the quantity sold is Q2. The following table illustrates the effect of the subsidy on consumer surplus, producer surplus, government revenue, and total surplus. Since total surplus declines by area D+H, the subsidy leads to a deadweight loss in that amount.

Chapter 9: Exercise 9 Suppose the market is described by: Qs = 2P Qd = 300-P Solve for the equilibrium price and quantity. Suppose that a tax of T is placed on buyers so demand is Qd = 300 – (P+T). Solve for the new equilibrium. What happens to the price receivd by sellers, the price paid by buyers, and the quantity? Tax revenue is TxQ. Use your answer to part (b) to solve for tax revenue as a function of T. Graph the relationship for T between 0 and 300. The deadweight loss of a tax is the area of the triangle between the supply and demand curves. Graph the relationship between DL and T between 0 and 300. The government now levies a tax on this good of 200 per unit. Is this a good policy? Why or why not? Can you propose a better policy?

Chapter 9: Exercise 9 Suppose the market is described by: Qs = 2P Qd = 300-P Solve for the equilibrium price and quantity. Setting quantity supplied equal to quantity demanded gives 2P = 300 – P. Adding P to both sides of the equation gives 3P = 300. Dividing both sides by 3 gives P = 100, which is the equilibrium price. Plugging P = 100 back into either equation for quantity demanded or supplied gives Q = 200 as the equilibrium quantity.

Chapter 9: Exercise 9 Suppose the market is described by: Qs = 2P Qd = 300-P Suppose that a tax of T is placed on buyers so demand is Qd = 300 – (P+T). Solve for the new equilibrium. What happens to the price received by sellers, the price paid by buyers, and the quantity? Now P is the price received by sellers and P+T is the price paid by buyers. Equating quantity demanded to quantity supplied gives 2P = 300 - (P+T). Adding P to both sides of the equation gives 3P = 300 – T. Dividing both sides by 3 gives P = 100 - T/3. This is the price received by sellers, and is clearly less than before the tax was imposed. The buyers pay a price equal to the price received by sellers plus the tax (P+T = 100 + 2T/3). The quantity sold is now Q = 2P = 200 – 2T/3.

Chapter 9: Exercise 9 Suppose the market is described by: Qs = 2P Qd = 300-P Tax revenue is TxQ. Use your answer to part (b) to solve for tax revenue as a function of T. Graph the relationship for T between 0 and 300. Since tax revenue is equal to T x Q and Q = 200 - 2T/3, tax revenue equals 200T - 2T2/3. Tax revenue is zero at T = 0 and at T = 300.

Chapter 9: Exercise 9 Suppose the market is described by: Qs = 2P Qd = 300-P The deadweight loss of a tax is the area of the triangle between the supply and demand curves. Graph the relationship between DL and T between 0 and 300. The area of the triangle (laid on its side) that represents the deadweight loss is 1/2 x base x height, where the base is the change in the price, which is the size of the tax (T) and the height is the amount of the decline in quantity (2T/3). So the deadweight loss equals 1/2 x T x 2T/3 = T2/3. This rises exponentially from 0 (when T = 0) to 45,000 when T = 300.

Chapter 9: Exercise 9 Suppose the market is described by: Qs = 2P Qd = 300-P The government now levies a tax on this good of 200 per unit. Is this a good policy? Why or why not? Can you propose a better policy? A tax of €200 per unit is a bad idea, because it's in a region in which tax revenue is declining. Tax revenue is calculated as 200T - 2T2/3 = 2002 – 2/3(2002) = 40,000 – 26,666 = €13,333. The government could reduce the tax to €150 per unit and get more tax revenue (€15,000). The lower tax would also cause a smaller deadweight loss. The deadweight loss is calculated as T2/3 so when T is €200 the deadweight loss is €13,333 and when T is €150 the deadweight loss is only €7,500. A tax of €150 per unit is therefore a better policy.

Discussion Is deadweight loss always bad? How much should we concern ourselves with avoiding deadweight loss? When is deadweight loss acceptable? How can Santa be described as a deadweight loss?