Inferring a worker’s productivity In theory, a firm should hire a worker only if the value of his marginal product exceeds the pay he receives. (Marginal.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
1 Signalling Often a player wants to convey his private information to other players. It might be information about his own payoffs (My costs are low,
Advertisements

Price Discrimination RESERVATION PRICE: A customer's reservation price is the most he is willing to pay for a unit of purchase. If I will pay up to 12.
“A little knowledge is a dangerous thing. So is a lot.”
Factor Markets Unit IV.
Government Intervention: When Uncle Sam steps in to flex some muscles in the marketplace.
Labor Market Discrimination Troy Tassier Fordham University.
Hal Varian Intermediate Microeconomics Chapter Thirty-Six
Chapter 37 Asymmetric Information In reality, it is often the case that one of the transacting party has less information than the other. Consider a market.
What are the causes of age discrimination in employment?
Chapter 14 Markets with Asymmetric Information. Chapter 17Slide 2 Topics to be Discussed Quality Uncertainty and the Market for Lemons Market Signaling.
Controversies in Trade Policy
Factor Markets and the Distribution of Income
Adverse Selection Asymmetric information is feature of many markets
CHAPTER 6 The Medium Run CHAPTER 6 Prepared by: Fernando Quijano and Yvonn Quijano Copyright © 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
A Tour of the Labor Market
Human Capital.
1 Models of Discrimination. 2 Prejudice is a feeling or emotion. Discrimination is an action. An economic definition of discrimination is unequal treatment.
Asymmetric Information ECON 370: Microeconomic Theory Summer 2004 – Rice University Stanley Gilbert.
Copyright©2004 South-Western 19 Earnings and Discrimination.
1 Schooling as a Signal. 2 The Schooling Model we saw in a previous section assumed that education really increases a worker’s productivity. Here we will.
Chapter 4 Multiple Regression.
Copyright©2004 South-Western 19 Earnings and Discrimination.
1 Human Capital. 2 In economics we talk about the 4 basic resource groups Land, Labor, Capital (things made to make other things), and Entrepreneurship.
Wages and Work.
1 Economic Models of Discrimination Sendhil Mullainathan Economics 1035 Fall 2007.
Earnings and Discrimination Chapter 19 Copyright © 2001 by Harcourt, Inc. All rights reserved. Requests for permission to make copies of any part of the.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western. Earnings and Discrimination Differences in Earnings in the United States Today –The typical physician earns about $200,000.
Introduction to the economics of education
Slides prepared by Thomas Bishop Chapter 11 Controversies in Trade Policy.
Labor Market Equilibrium
Part 7 Further Topics © 2006 Thomson Learning/South-Western.
CHAPTER 6 © 2006 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Macroeconomics, 4/e Olivier Blanchard The Labor Market Prepared by: Fernando Quijano and Yvonn Quijano.
Labor Markets and Earnings Economics 230 J.F. O’Connor.
Ch 26: Factor Markets With Emphasis on the Labor Market Del Mar College John Daly ©2003 South-Western Publishing, A Division of Thomson Learning.
The Medium Run. United States A Tour of the Labor Market  The noninstitutional civilian population is the number of people potentially available.
Screening and Signaling Edition 7: Chapter 12, pages Edition 6: Chapter 12, pages
Investments in Human Capital: Education and Training
Principal - Agent Games. Sometimes asymmetric information develops after a contract has been signed In this case, signaling and screening do not help,
Defining Competitiveness
Factor Markets: A review
How much does the economy produce? The quantity that an economy will produce depends on two things-  The quantity of inputs utilized in the production.
Copyright©2004 South-Western 19 Earnings and Discrimination.
Unit 4 : Reading Quiz # 12 : 6 points
Chapter 37 Asymmetric Information. Information in Competitive Markets In purely competitive markets all agents are fully informed about traded commodities.
Asymmetric Information
Chapter 15: Job Search: External and Internal
PART FOUR Resource Markets
McGraw-Hill/Irwin © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. 7-1 Defining Competitiveness Chapter 7.
Harcourt, Inc. items and derived items copyright © 2001 by Harcourt, Inc. ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION 1. Definition of asymmetric information 2. Sources of.
1 Raiding and Signaling in the Academic Labor Market Timothy Perri.
© 2010 McGraw Hill Ryerson 7-1 COMPENSATION Third Canadian Edition Milkovich, Newman, Cole.
Chapter 5 Signalling Stefan P. Schleicher University of Graz Economics of Information Incentives and Contracts.
Lecture 8 Producer Theory. Objective of a Firm The main objective of firm is to maximize profit Firms engage in production process But when firm choose.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 37 Asymmetric Information.
Asymmetric Information
1 Theories of Discrimination. 2 What do we generally mean by “discrimination”?
Investment in Human Capital Model-Part I Topic 3 Part III.
ETP Economics 102 Jack Wu. Identifying Unemployment Categories of Unemployment The problem of unemployment is usually divided into two categories. The.
Chapter 9-1 Chapter Nine Human Capital Theory: Applications to Education and Training Modified from Slides Created by Erica Morrill.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. 7-1 Defining Competitiveness Chapter 7.
Signaling in Education ECON 381. Signaling in education Suppose there are two types of workers – low productivity workers and high productivity workers.
Business and Management HL: Human Resources.  When a business hires people who already work within the company to fill a vacant spot.  Happens when:
The Demand and Supply of Resources 14. Big Questions 1.What are the factors of production? 2.Where does the demand for labor come from? 3.Where does the.
19 Earnings and Discrimination. Differences in Earnings in the United States Today – The typical physician earns about $200,000 a year. – The typical.
Signaling Game Problems. Signaling game. Two players– a sender and receiver. Sender knows his type. Receiver does not. It is not necessarily in the sender’s.
Production and Costs Ch. 19, R.A. Arnold, Economics 9 th Ed.
Wage Determination How much should you get paid?.
Earnings and Discrimination
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
Earnings and Discrimination
Presentation transcript:

Inferring a worker’s productivity In theory, a firm should hire a worker only if the value of his marginal product exceeds the pay he receives. (Marginal benefit vs. marginal cost) Ideally, the marginal product of each worker is known. For example, if you believe that hiring Mr. Doe as a manager will increase your profit by $50,000 a year, then $50,000 is the maximum amount you should be paying him. In most real-world cases, however, the future MP of a worker is unknown. Issues in personnel economics

Worker’s marginal product depends on his inherent characteristics (talent, skills, physical strength, etc.) and the effort he decides to put in the job. All those variables are known to the worker but not to the firm – an example of asymmetric information. Keeping a worker who is not fit for the job is costly even when it is done for a limited time. If the firm wants to increase its chances of hiring the right person, it can use remedies common to any market with asymmetric information.

1.Screening – the uninformed party (the firm) does something that gives it a better idea about the future productivity of a worker. This effort is usually costly. (Keep in mind that future productivity cannot be determined with certainty. We can only measure some characteristic that we believe is correlated with abilities.)

Form of screeningWhat is measuredRationale Personal interviewGeneral impression of the person; handling of difficult questions, ethical dilemmas, etc. To determine how well the person would fit into the company culture Drug testingWhether the person used drugs in the last two weeks Some people using drugs are addicted therefore less dependable Criminal recordWhether the person … well, has a criminal record (and what kind of record) There is a correlation between the criminal record and person’s responsibility / dependability Recommendation letters What some other people think about the applicant

Screening applicants is more justified when The degree of correlation between the measured variable and the abilities is high. The cost of screening is low. A large portion of applicants will be refused employment as a result. The spread in applicants’ abilities is large.

2. Signaling – the informed party does something to signal their “type” to the uninformed party. In the labor market, high-ability workers signal their ability to the firm, thus distinguishing themselves from low-ability individuals. Examples: Credentials (extra lines on the resume) Education (CPA, Ph.D., bar exam, MBA,…)

As always, a signal has to be credible. Therefore, it has to be hard for the other type(s) to mimic it. The signal is more credible when: Obtaining the credential is easier for high-ability workers but more difficult for low-ability workers. Also note that low-ability workers will try the harder to mimic the signal of high ability the more worthwhile it is to do so. Hence the signal is more credible when the difference in pay between high- and low-ability workers is small.

Education as a signal Model developed by Spence (a 2001 Nobel laureate). What do we learn in college? How relevant is the knowledge gained in college for our future career? If it is, then why do many firms, upon hiring college graduates, send them to some sort of job-specific training? What if a college degree (or our GPA) is nothing more than a signal of our abilities or our commitment to hard work?

Let us take this hypothesis to an extreme and assume (for the purpose of this model) that college, or any other form of education does not affect our innate abilities. Instead, it is sort of a tryout. Let’s say there are two different types of individuals in the economy, those of high ability and those of low ability. Once hired, they are capable of producing different marginal product, the high-ability types being more productive. Each worker is paid the value of his marginal product. Each worker knows his own type, but the firms don’t (hence we are dealing with asymmetric information).

IF firms HAD perfect information, they would pay each type what that type deserves, w H and w L, respectively. w H > w L Since firms cannot distinguish between high and low type workers, they pay everyone the same wage, equal to the expected value of the marginal product. Let us assume that the shares of the two types in the population are equal, α H = α L = 0.5. Then the average wage, equal to the expected value of the marginal product, is w AV = α H · w H + α L · w L = (w H + w L )/2. Because of incomplete information, high type workers are underpaid while low type are overpaid.

Now, suppose anyone can signal his ability by getting a college degree (or another form of education). Education is obtained at a cost. (This cost is not necessarily monetary – it can be expressed in the time spent and the amount of misery a person has to go through to get a degree.) This cost is different for the two types, c H < c L.

Low type Get educationNo High type Get educ.,, No,, The selection of an equilibrium depends on model parameters.

Low type Get educationNo High type Get educ. 240, , 200 No200, , 300 Example 1. w H = 400w L = 200(w H > w L ) c H = 60c L = 120(c H < c L )

Low type Get educationNo High type Get educ. 240, , 200 No200, , 300 Under these parameters, everything works as it should – High ability individuals get education and get recognized as high ability; Low-ability don’t Example 1. w H = 400w L = 200(w H > w L ) c H = 60c L = 120(c H < c L )

Low type Get educationNo High type Get educ. 260, , 200 No200, , 300 Example 2. w H = 400w L = 200(w H > w L ) c H = 40c L = 60(c H < c L ) (getting education gets easier)

Low type Get educationNo High type Get educ. 260, , 200 No200, , 300 Both types choose to get education. Education is no longer a signal of abilities. Example 2. w H = 400w L = 200(w H > w L ) c H = 40c L = 60(c H < c L ) (getting education gets easier)

Formal definitions of the two types of equilibria: Separating equilibrium – a situation when it is possible to differentiate between the two types of people (or products, as in the lemons model). – see Example 1. Pooling equilibrium – different types behave alike and are therefore treated alike, as in Example 2.

It is possible to show that, If w H - w L > 2 c L, then both types get education. A pooling equilibrium occurs. – Ex.2 If 2 c L > w H - w L > 2 c H, then all high-ability individuals choose to get a degree, thus separating themselves from low-ability types. – Ex.1 A separating equilibrium occurs. If 2 c H > w H - w L > c H, then either of the two equilibria may occur. If w H - w L < c H, then none of the types chooses to get a degree. Another pooling equilibrium.

c H 2c H 2c L w H - w L Which type gets degree: none none or H only both H only Type of equilibrium: Pooling Pooling or SeparatingPooling separating w H – w L :

Separating equilibrium leads to higher efficiency (think of an analogy with the lemons model). In order for education to serve as a signal, the cost of getting it has to be neither too high nor too low. This model raises several interesting issues. What happens as getting a degree gets easier? (See example 2 above.) Top schools and “regular” schools: In which case a degree is a more credible signal? Why?