Congestion Pricing Economic Models and international experience

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Elasticity and Its Applications
Advertisements

Calculate TR and Marginal Revenue
In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:
C HAPTER Elasticity of Demand and Supply price elasticities of demand and supply, income and cross elasticities of demand, and using elasticity to forecast.
What Is Perfect Competition? Perfect competition is an industry in which Many firms sell identical products to many buyers. There are no restrictions.
Pricing for Utility-driven Resource Management and Allocation in Clusters Chee Shin Yeo and Rajkumar Buyya Grid Computing and Distributed Systems (GRIDS)
Chapter 6 Elasticity and Demand.
© 2008 Pearson Addison Wesley. All rights reserved Chapter Seven Costs.
Supply and Demand The goal of this chapter is to explain how supply and demand really work. What determines the price of a good or service? How does the.
Part 3 Probabilistic Decision Models
Chapter 4 Individual and Market Demand
Externalities from Autos
Chapter 6 From Demand to Welfare McGraw-Hill/Irwin
1 Introduction to Transportation Systems. 2 PART I: CONTEXT, CONCEPTS AND CHARACTERIZATI ON.
Smarter Travel Programmes– Financial impacts for Transport for London COLIN BUCHANAN
1 Performance indicators, targets, steering Technical Interchange meeting Toulouse, May 2002 Xavier FRON Head Performance Review Unit.
Minnesotas Congestion Pricing Program Road User Charging Conference January, 2009 By Bernie Arseneau Minnesota (USA) Department of Transportation.
1 Innovative Tools October 27, 2011 Chi Mai. 2 Presentation Overview VISSIM Corridors VISSIM Protocol Hours of Congestion.
Part 6 Perfect Competition
Evaluating Window Joins over Unbounded Streams Author: Jaewoo Kang, Jeffrey F. Naughton, Stratis D. Viglas University of Wisconsin-Madison CS Dept. Presenter:
1 Trip-timing decisions with traffic incidents in the bottleneck model Mogens Fosgerau (Technical University of Denmark; CTS Sweden; ENS Cachan) Robin.
Traffic Analysis Toolbox & Highway Capacity Manual Transition
The Price System The market system, also called the price system, performs two important and closely related functions: Price Rationing Resource Allocation.
© 2009 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Essentials of Economics Hubbard/OBrien, 2e. Fernando & Yvonn Quijano Prepared by: Chapter 4 Market Efficiency.
KOOTHS | BiTS: Economic Policy and Market Regulation (winter term 2013/2014), Part 2 1 Economic Policy and Market Regulation Part 2 Dr. Stefan Kooths BiTS.
An Introduction to International Economics
The Impact of Trade Policies Copyright © 2010 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin Chapter 14.
Chapter 18 Pricing Policies McGraw-Hill/Irwin
Perfect Competition 12.
office hours: 3:45PM to 4:45PM tuesday LUMS C85
Chapter 12 Capturing Surplus.
Price Discrimination A monopoly engages in price discrimination if it is able to sell otherwise identical units of output at different prices Whether a.
15 Monopoly.
The evening commute with cars and transit: Duality results and user equilibrium for the combined morning and evening peaks 20 th International Symposium.
SCATTER workshop, Milan, 24 October 2003 Testing selected solutions to control urban sprawl The Brussels case city.
Copyright © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 25 Money and Economic Stability in the ISLM World.
Money, Interest Rates, and Exchange Rates
Capacity Planning For Products and Services
Capacity Planning For Products and Services
A Key to Economic Analysis
2009 Foster School of Business Cost Accounting L.DuCharme 1 Decision Making and Relevant Information Chapter 11.
Elasticity of Demand and Supply
Market Power: Monopoly and Monopsony
Perfect Competition.
Monopoly Profit Maximization Chapter A Model of Monopoly How much should the monopolistic firm choose to produce if it wants to maximize profit?
1 Chapter 11 APPLIED COMPETITIVE ANALYSIS Copyright ©2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.
Copyright © 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 12 Keynesian Business Cycle Theory: Sticky Wages and Prices.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2010 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
PSSA Preparation.
Copyright © 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 11 Market-Clearing Models of the Business Cycle.
All Rights ReservedMicroeconomics © Oxford University Press Malaysia, – 1.
Firms in Competitive Markets
© 2010 South-Western, a part of Cengage Learning, all rights reserved C H A P T E R 2010 update Firms in Competitive Markets M icroeconomics P R I N C.
1 © ©1999 South-Western College Publishing PowerPoint Slides prepared by Ken Long Principles of Economics 2nd edition by Fred M Gottheil.
CONGESTION KSG HUT251/GSD 5302 Transportation Policy and Planning, Gomez-Ibanez OUTLINE OF CLASS: 1.NATURE AND SEVERITY 2.MENU OF REMEDIES 3.ENGINEER’S.
Voting, Spatial Monopoly, and Spatial Price Regulation Economic Inquiry, Jan, 1992, MH Ye and M. J. Yezer Presentation Date: 06/Jan/14.
Monopoly Outline: Outline: Characteristics of a monopoly Characteristics of a monopoly Why monopolies arise? Why monopolies arise? Production and pricing.
Monopoly A monopoly is a single supplier to a market
Perfect Competition & Welfare. Outline Derive aggregate supply function Short and Long run equilibrium Practice problem Consumer and Producer Surplus.
Externalities on highways Today: We apply externalities to a real-life example.
Competitive Markets for Goods and Services
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2013 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
Economic Applications of Functions and Derivatives
State and Local Public Finance Spring 2013, Professor Yinger Lecture 11 User Fees (=Public Prices)
Perfect Competition *MADE BY RACHEL STAND* :). I. Perfect Competition: A Model A. Basic Definitions 1. Perfect Competition: a model of the market based.
Perfect Competition Chapter 7
Externalities on highways Today: We apply externalities to a real-life example.
Traffic Congestion and Congestion Pricing- Time independent and time dependent analysis.
Modeling the Market Process: A Review of the Basics Chapter 2 © 2007 Thomson Learning/South-WesternCallan and Thomas, Environmental Economics and Management,
Generated Trips and their Implications for Transport Modelling using EMME/2 Marwan AL-Azzawi Senior Transport Planner PDC Consultants, UK Also at Napier.
Presentation transcript:

Congestion Pricing Economic Models and international experience Aya Aboudina, PhD Student Civil Engineering Dept, University of Toronto

Outline Introduction Congestion Pricing Models Motivation Microeconomic foundations Congestion Pricing Models Static vs. dynamic pricing Profit-maximizing vs. social-welfare maximizing pricing Social-welfare maximizing pricing Congestion pricing models: a conclusion International Experience and Research Vision

Motivation Users/consumers should pay the full cost of whatever they consume Otherwise, they are subsidized Therefore, they unnecessarily consume more to the detriment of all i.e. “Tragedy of the Commons” Garrett Hardin, journal Science in 1968 Add to Motivation: Boosting traffic flow up to capacity Reducing trip delay through departure time rescheduling

Tragedy of the Commons A dilemma arising from the situation in which multiple individuals, acting independently and rationally consulting their own self-interest, will ultimately deplete a shared limited resource even when it is clear that it is not in anyone's long-term interest for this to happen. Examples: Overgrazing Congestion Criticized for promoting privatization Used here to encourage “control”

Motivation (cont’d) Recent research conducted at UofT eliminates both capacity expansions and extensions to public transit as policies to combat traffic congestion. On the other hand, it indicates that vkt (vehicle kilometres travelled) is quite responsive to price. Together these findings strengthen the case for congestion pricing as a policy response to traffic congestion. As mentioned, extensions to public transit may not be the optimum solution to combat congestion (Durantor, Turner). Additionally, investing the pricing revenue back in transit may cause social welfare loss. It needs a case-by-case specific study to find the optimum allocation of revenues (transit or roads or rebating taxes).

Microeconomic Foundations I: Demand, Cost, Revenue, and Profit Demand (aka Marginal Benefit) The change in the quantity purchased to the price. Downward slopping curve Demand Output (Q) $ Demand: Downward slopping curve (demand increases as the price falls since more consumers can afford (more of) the good).

Microeconomic Foundations I: Demand, Cost, Revenue, and Profit (cont’d) Costs Average Cost (AC) = Total Cost (TC)/Total Production (Q) Marginal Cost (MC): the change in total cost required to increase output by one unit = ΔTC/ ΔQ → d(TC)/d(Q) MC AC Demand Output (Q) $

Microeconomic Foundations I: Demand, Cost, Revenue, and Profit (cont’d) Total Revenue (TR) = Price (p) * Total Production (Q) Marginal Revenue (MR) = ΔTR/ ΔQ → d(TR)/d(Q) Profit = TR – TC (maximized when MR = MC) MC AC Demand MR Output (Q) P Q $ Profit

Microeconomic Foundations I: Demand, Cost, Revenue, and Profit (cont’d) In Transportation AC = Monetary Expenses + VOT * Travel Time The AC increases with the level of road use. This implies that the MC exceeds the AC. This is because the MC includes both the cost incurred by the traveler himself (AC) and the additional cost (s)he imposes on all other travelers. This additional cost is known as the marginal external congestion cost (mecc). Monetary expenses: for ex. fuel consumption and maintenance Travel Time = free-flow travel time + excess delay Level of Road Use: traffic flow (V) in static models, or total number of travelers over the peak (Q) in dynamic models The physical meaning of the difference between the AC and the MC will be illustrated (through a numerical example) later in this presentation. MC AC Flow $ V mecc

Microeconomic Foundations I: Demand, Cost, Revenue, and Profit (cont’d) Numerical Example When the flow entering some bridge is 10,999 veh/hr, it takes 1.07 min to cross bridge. Whereas it takes 1.09 min when the flow is 11,000 veh/hr. Then we have the following cost values at flow = 11,000: TC = 11,000 *(1.09 min * VOT) AC = TC/Flow = 1.09 min * VOT MC = TC (11,000) –TC (10,999) = 11,000*(1.09 min*VOT) –10,999 *(1.07 min*VOT) = (1*1.09min*VOT) +10,999 ((1.09-1.07)min*VOT) = AC + externality cost MC AC Flow Travel Time externality = 10,999* 0.02 min 1.09 Notes: The relation obtained between MC and AVC indicates that the extra cost added when a new vehicle enters the HYWY is composed of two parts: the variable private cost incurred by the new vehicle itself in addition to an extra cost (due to the increase in travel time caused by the new vehicle) incurred by the existing vehicles on the HYWY. As flow increases, the gap between MC and AVC (i.e., the externality cost) increases. Because: 1. The no. of existing vehicles (that are badly affected by entrance of new vehicle) is high 2. The difference in travel time increases (since AVC curve is highly deteriorating as flow increases) 1.07 10,999 11,000

Microeconomic Foundations II: Consumer ,Producer, and Social Surpluses Consumer Surplus (CS) = Total Benefit – Amount Paid Producer Surplus (PS) = Total Revenue – Total Cost = Profit Social Surplus (SS) = CS + PS = Total Benefit – Total Cost P Q Consumer Surplus Producer Surplus Demand $ Quantity MC Social Surplus When computing the above values, we should consider the Total Cost, not just the Total Variable Cost (which is the area under the MC curve). However, the fixed costs do not vary with the Quantity produced and hence will not affect the computation of Quantity that maximizes any surplus (consumer, producer, or social). Note: the Total Benefit is the area under the Marginal Benefit (Demand) curve

Microeconomic Foundations III: Engineers vs Microeconomic Foundations III: Engineers vs. Economists Definition of Congestion Economists: system is congested if the performance of the system (e.g. travel time) rises with the intensity of use (e.g. flow levels). Traffic engineers: system is congested when traffic density exceeds the critical density, resulting in traffic breakdown. Economists Traffic Engineers Capacity Critical density Density (veh/km) Flow (veh/hr) Breakdown AC p Cost (1/speed) Flow (veh/hr) Capacity (max flow) Economists Traffic Engineers Critical density: is the density corresponding to capacity (maximum flow) as shown on Figure.

Microeconomic Foundations III: Engineers vs Microeconomic Foundations III: Engineers vs. Economists Definition of Congestion “Congestion” for traffic engineers is termed “hyper- congestion” for economists. Hyper-congestion causes a significant drop in capacity (at critical density). Eliminating hyper-congestion allows the sustenance of the original capacity. Critical density Density (veh/km) Flow (veh/hr) Uncongested capacity Congested capacity Breakdown Normal- Congestion Hyper- Congestion For instance, if capacity is 2200 veh/hr/lane on a freeway, this capacity drops to about 1700~1800 veh/hr/lane under hyper-congestion, causing some 25% or so loss in capacity at rush hours, the time we need capacity most!

Outline Introduction Congestion Pricing Models Motivation Microeconomic foundations Congestion Pricing Models Static vs. dynamic pricing Profit-maximizing vs. social-welfare maximizing pricing Social-welfare maximizing pricing Congestion pricing models: a conclusion International Experience and Research Vision

Static vs. Dynamic Pricing Congestion Pricing Dynamic Static Open Loop Vary according to fixed schedule (based on typical conditions per time of day) Closed Loop vary depending on time of day and level of congestion (based on real-time system state) This categorization determines the nature of tolls (not how to set toll values) We can further classify each of the tolling strategies (that we will consider later in this presentation) according to the above categorization. For ex: First-best and second-best static ->static First-best (multiple time periods) -> quasi dynamic open-loop First-best and second-best dynamic -> dynamic open-loop Mahmassani -> dynamic closed-loop Reactive Predictive

Profit-Maximizing vs. Social-welfare Maximizing Pricing Q* Consumer Surplus Producer Surplus Demand $ Output MC Social Welfare maximized Social-Welfare Maximizing Price Pm Qm Consumer Surplus shrinks Monopolist maximizes its Producer Surplus Demand MR $ Output MC Profit Maximizing (Monopoly) Price Dead weight loss But total social welfare declines by yellow area- “dead weight loss” They differ in the objective function to be maximized while formulating pricing Social-Welfare maximizing pricing: each economic agent faces a price equal to its activity’s social marginal cost Profit-maximizing price: the price is determined by the demand curve Producer Surplus maximized Set to maximize the social welfare. Achieved when the “Demand” equals the MC. Set to maximize profits (PS). It is the price consistent with the output where the MR equals the MC.

Social-Welfare Maximizing Pricing First-best pricing Second-best pricing Set to maximize the social welfare. No constraints on congestion prices. It is often impossible! It optimizes welfare given some constraints on policies (e.g. the inability to price all links on a network and the inability to distinguish between classes of users). Rules are more complex. Relative efficiency less than one. Static congestion Dynamic congestion

First-Best Pricing with Static Congestion This is the conventional diagram of optimal congestion pricing. The un-priced equilibrium occurs at the intersection of demand and AC curves; it involves traffic flow V0 and cost c0. The optimal flow V1 occurs at the intersection of demand and MC; it can be achieved by imposing a toll τ (marginal-cost pricing). The gain in the social surplus is depicted by the shaded triangle, which gives the difference between social cost saved (under MC curve) and benefit forgone (under demand curve) when reducing traffic flow from V0 to V1. Flow (V) $ AC Toll Revenue MC Social Subsidy MC1 AC1 τ = mecc V1 V0 Demand

First-Best Pricing with Static Congestion Static models limitations: Assumes static demand and cost curves for each congested link and time period. Appropriate when traffic conditions do not change too quickly or when it is sufficient to focus attention on average traffic levels over extended periods. Cannot explain whether or not hyper-congestion will occur in equilibrium (i.e., whenever demand intersects the AC curve in its hyper-congested segment).

First-Best Pricing from a Dynamic Perspective The basic bottleneck model Alternative dynamic congestion technologies Chu 1995 Verhoef 2003

The Basic Bottleneck Model The most widely used conceptual model of dynamic congestion pricing Assumptions: No delay if inflow is below capacity Queue exit rate equals capacity (when a queue exists) Single desired queue exit time t* (for all users) Total demand for passages Q is inelastic Two costs in un-priced equilibrium: Travel delay cost cT(t) Schedule delay cost cs(t) (early and late arrival costs) Queue forms Time Cumulative queue exits (slope: Vk) Cumulative queue entries Queue disperses Number of vehicles tq tq’ t* tq tq’ Exit time (t) t* cs(t) cT(t) c(t) Average cost

The Basic Bottleneck Model (cont’d) The optimum toll τ(t): Replicates travel delay costs (it has a triangular shape). Affects the patterns of entries (queue entry rate will equal capacity) (flattening the peak). Results in the same pattern of schedule-delay cost. Produces zero travel delay costs. The main source of efficiency gains from optimal dynamic pricing is the rescheduling of departure times from the trip origin This illustrates that the reallocation of departure times may be a greater source of benefit from time-of-day pricing than the reduction in total trips tq tq’ Exit time (t) t* cs(t) τ(t) c(t) Average cost

Alternative Dynamic Congestion Technologies: Chu 1995 Chu extends the same basic logic of (marginal-cost) toll to a dynamic setting in which traffic flow varies with time. The optimal time-varying toll is a dynamic generalization of the standard toll for static congestion. Hyper-congestion is absent in this model and both inflow and outflow from the road are assumed to have equal sub-critical value. Chu investigates optimal pricing for a road that is characterized by no-propagation flow congestion (no hyper-congestion or spreading of the congestion upstream) in which the travel time depends only on the flow at the road's entrance (or exit) at the time the trip is started (or completed) (as opposed to bottleneck where tt depends on inflow + enter time) Flow $ AC Toll Revenue MC MC1 AC1 τ = mecc V1 V0 Demand

Alternative Dynamic Congestion Technologies: Verhoef 2003 It uses the car-following model to investigate optimal time-varying tolls on a road with a sudden reduction in the number of lanes by half (which produces hyper- congestion in the un-priced equilibrium). The study provides a time- and location-specific version of Chu's toll; it extends the basic “marginal-cost" toll to more realistic cases where congestion varies both temporally and spatially in a continuous manner. Verhoef’s model uses the car-following model to investigate optimal time-varying tolls on a road with a sudden reduction in the number of lanes by half, which produces hyper-congestion in the un-priced equilibrium, in the form of queue immediately upstream of the bottleneck. Copying the triangular toll schedule from the basic bottleneck model, to eliminate all travel delays, is a disastrous policy in Verhoef’s simulations, as it attempts to create a road system running at free-flow speed in which case pricing will be excessive as it produces a welfare loss. Verhoef’s pricing model eliminates hyper-congestion but it does not fully eliminate travel delays (delay in this model is defined relative to free-flow speed and not capacity speed).

Congestion Pricing: a Conclusion Two types of models may be considered to set socially optimal prices, namely, static and dynamic methods. Static pricing models: Assume static demand and cost curves and hence come out with static (time-independent) tolls. The main benefit from static pricing is to force vehicles to pay their full congestion externalities to the road (spatial distribution). Dynamic pricing models Take into account the variations of demand (arrival rates) with time (how peak demand evolves then subsides); accordingly they produce dynamic (time-varying) tolls. A main source of efficiency gains from optimal pricing would be the rescheduling of departure times (temporal distribution) from the trip origin, which can produce significant benefits going beyond those produced by static tolls.

Outline Introduction Congestion Pricing Models Motivation Microeconomic foundations Congestion Pricing Models Static vs. dynamic pricing Profit-maximizing vs. social-welfare maximizing pricing Social-welfare maximizing pricing Congestion pricing models: a conclusion International Experience and Research Vision

International Experience USA, UK, France, Norway, Sweden, Germany, Switzerland, Singapore, and Australia have implemented major road pricing projects.

London Congestion Pricing In service since 2003. The first congestion pricing program in a major European city. £10 daily cordon fee (flat price) for driving in “Central London Congestion Pricing Zone” during weekdays (from 7am to 6pm) (one time per chargeable day). Bus and taxi service improved. Accidents and air pollution declined in city center. After 1 year of cordon tolls and during charging: Traffic circulating within the zone decreased by 15%. Traffic entering the zone decreased by 18%. Congestion (measured as the actual minus the free-flow travel time per km) decreased by 30% within the zone. LEZ: to encourage the most polluting heavy diesel vehicles driving in the Capital to become cleaner. The LEZ covers most of Greater London. To drive within it without paying a daily charge these vehicles must meet certain emissions standards that limit the amount of particulate matter (a type of pollution) coming from their exhausts. note this was an original sign, the hours shown are no longer accurate

London Congestion Pricing (cont’d) The Central London Congestion Pricing Zone

I-15 HOT Lanes, San Diego, CA First significant value pricing project. Implemented in 1996 along the 13-km HOV section of I-15 in San Diego. Convert HOV to HOT; solo drivers pay a monthly pass ($50 to $70) to use HOV during peak periods. In 1998, automated and dynamic pricing scheme.

I-15 HOT Lanes, San Diego (cont’d) Toll levels determined from congestion level to maintain “free- flow” conditions in the HOV lane. Tolls updated every 6 minutes ($0.5 to $4) (closed-loop regulator). Toll level displayed on real-time sign. 48% increase in HOV volumes. Success in congestion minimization. Note (Kenn Small): Toll values are most probably “reactive”, they are determined as follows: Toll values are determined by comparing aggregated volumes (on tolled facilities) obtained from two observation intervals against volume thresholds prescribed in a look-up table. The tolls are then displayed on variable message signs.

407 ETR (Express Toll Route) Multi-lane, electronic HYWY running 69 km across the top of the GTA from HYWY 403 (in Oakville) to HYWY 48 (in Markham). Constructed in a partnership between “Canadian Highways International Corporation” and the Province of Ontario. Currently owned by 407-ETR International Inc. In the figure above: Blue parts: regular zone Yellow parts: light zone (lower rates)

407 ETR (Express Toll Route) (cont’d) Fees at the regular zone (open-loop regulator): Monday-Friday: Peak period (6-7:30am, 8:30-10am, 3-4pm, 6-7pm): 22.75¢/km Peak hours (7:30-8:30am, 4-6pm ): 22.95¢/km Off-peak rates: 22.95¢/km Weekends and holidays: 19.35¢/km Speeds on HYWY 407 ~ double free HYWYs. High level of user satisfaction. Monopoly price! Note: I think the pricing scheme used in HYWY 407 is open loop, i.e. it is determined a priori based on the above schedule. About 70% of tolls are collected using electronic transponder cards that deduct charges from prepaid accounts, and 30% using a license plate photography billing system.

Research Vision The purpose is to develop a comprehensive predictive real- time dynamic congestion pricing model for the GTHA. The tolls will be set dynamically and adaptively according to location, time-of-day, distance driven (, and if possible, the level of pollution emitted from the vehicle). The tolling system will target full cost pricing in the case of sub-critical traffic conditions and eliminating hyper-congestion and maintaining flow at the maximum capacity in case of super-critical traffic conditions. Additionally, this research will attempt an extra step of basing the toll on the predicted (anticipated), rather than the prevailing, traffic conditions. This is to prevent traffic breakdown before it occurs.

Research Vision (cont’d) To consider how our envisioned systems will be applied to: Freeway only with HOT lanes. Freeway corridor (e.g. Gardiner-lakeshore, where Gardiner would be tolled).  Cordoned network, e.g. downtown Toronto.   The concern with the first two examples is that the impact will be mostly on routing and less on departure time choice. The cordoned area will have to have an impact on departure time choice and much less on routing (I guess an impact on mode choice as well).

Thank You Questions, suggestions and comments are always welcome!

References The Fundamental Law of Road Congestion, Evidence from US Cities (UofT Economists)2009 CIV 1310 Infrastructure Economics lecture notes Kenneth A. Small and Erik T. Vehoef.The Economics of Urban Transportation. Jing Dong, Hani S. Mahmassani, Sevgi Erdoğan, and Chung-Cheng Lu. “State-Dependent Pricing for Real- Time Freeway Management: Anticipatory versus Reactive Strategies”. TRB Annual Meeting 2007 Paper #07-2109.

Price Elasticity of Demand Note: When a demand curve is horizontal (or very close to), this means that a small change in price will cause a substantial change in demand, so the demand in this case is said to be “perfectly elastic”, that is demand is very sensitive to price. For the extreme case, in which demand is vertical, any change in price doesn’t alter demand at all, so demand is said to be “perfectly inelastic” to price changes.