Session 6: Capital Structure I

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Theory Behind the Discounted Cash Flow approach
Advertisements

MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS An Analysis of Business Issues
Chapter Outline 15.1 The Capital-Structure Question and The Pie Theory
NPV.
Capital Structure Decisions Chapter 15 and 16
Capital Structure Debt versus Equity. Advantages of Debt Interest is tax deductible (lowers the effective cost of debt) Debt-holders are limited to a.
Capital Structure Theory
Corporate Financial Theory
Debt and Taxes Chapter 15.
Corporate Valuation Free cash flow approach
Last Lecture.. Cost of Equity Cost of Preferred Stock Cost of Debt
McGraw-Hill © 2004 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Leverage and Capital Structure Chapter 13.
Chapter Outline The Capital Structure Decision
Financial Leverage and Capital Structure Policy
Capital Structure Refers to the mix of debt and equity that a company uses to finance its business Capital Restructuring Capital restructuring involves.
Cash Flows in Capital Budgeting Three approaches:  Free Cash Flow and WACC  Adjusted Present Value  Cash Flows to Equity.
Chapter 16 Capital Structure Decisions: Part II Topics in Chapter MM models: Without corporate taxes (1958) With corporate taxes (1963) Miller model:
Goal of the Lecture: Understand how to determine the proper mix of debt and equity to use to fund corporate investments.
Capital Structure Decisions: Part II
CHAPTER 18: CAPITAL BUDGETING WITH LEVERAGE
Capital Structure Decision
Capital Structure: Basic Concepts
Corporate Financial Policy Introduction
J. K. Dietrich - FBE 432 – Fall 2002 Module I: Investment Banking: Capital Structure and Valuation Week 3 – September 11, 2002.
Capital Structure (Ch. 12)
Corporate Finance Lecture 17 INTRODUCTION TO CAPITAL STRUCTURE (continued) Ronald F. Singer FINA 4330 Fall, 2010.
Session 7: Capital Structure C Corporate Finance Topics.
12-1 CHAPTER 14 Capital Structure and Leverage Leverage and risk Optimal capital structure Compare profit, return and risk for leverage and un-leveraged.
CHAPTER 16: CAPITAL STRUCTURE – BASIC CONCEPTS
Capital Structure and Value Optimal capital structure is the mix of debt and equity that maximizes the value of the firm or minimizes the weighted average.
© 2010 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly accessible Web site, in whole or in part.
Capital Structure.
Ch 16 Financial Leverage and Capital Structure. 1. Capital structure question Financial managers want to set up a capital structure that will maximize.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2004by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved Corporate Finance Ross  Westerfield  Jaffe Seventh Edition.
Capital Structure. Introduction How are projects and firms financed? This choice determines the capital structure Capital structure is mix of types of.
Advanced Project Evaluation
Capital Restructuring
FIN 351: lecture 12 The Capital Structure Decision MM propositions.
Capital Structure Modigliani-Miller
Capital Structure and Valuation Example.
Financial Leverage and Capital Structure Policy
FINANCIAL LEVERAGE AND CAPITAL STRUCTURE POLICY Chapter 16.
1 Finance School of Management FINANCE Review of Questions and Problems Part V: Chapter 16 & 17.
GROUP MEMBER HENRY EBUN ASMARAH RIKUN NOORINA ABD HAMID BUDIRMAN DAUD
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2002 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved Corporate Finance Ross  Westerfield  Jaffe Sixth Edition.
Capital Structure with Taxes
Capital Structure. Effect of Corporate Taxes So far capital structure was irrelevant. What if we introduces corporate taxes? Corporate taxes are paid after.
Advanced Corporate Finance FINA 7330 Capital Structure Issues and Financing Lecture 07 and 08 Fall, 2010.
McGraw-Hill © 2004 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Leverage and Capital Structure Chapter 13.
6- 1 Outline 6: Capital Structure 6.1 Debt and Value in a Tax Free Economy 6.2 Capital Structure and Corporate Taxes 6.3 Cost of Financial Distress 6.4.
Chapter 16 - Planning the Firm’s Financing Mix. Balance Sheet Balance Sheet Current Current Current Current Assets Liabilities Assets Liabilities Debt.
Chapter 12: Leverage and Capital Structure
Prepared by Professor Wei Wang Queen’s University © 2011 McGraw–Hill Ryerson Limited Capital Structure: Basic Concepts Chapter Sixteen.
Advanced Corporate Finance FINA 7330
Capital Structure Theory (1)
Capital Structure I: Basic Concepts.
Session 8: DCF Valuation
Chapter 13 Learning Objectives
Capital Structure (1).
Capital Structure Debt versus Equity.
Out of the perfect capital market: Role of taxes
Chapter 9 Theory of Capital Structure
Capital Structure (1).
Financial Analysis, Planning and Forecasting Theory and Application
Capital Structure Byers.
Capital Structure Determination
Capital Structure I: Basic Concepts.
Capital Structure Decisions
Capital Structure Decisions: Modigliani and Miller 1958 JF
Presentation transcript:

Session 6: Capital Structure I C15.0008 Corporate Finance Topics

Outline Basic capital structure theory—irrelevance Debt and equity as options Tax effects Valuation The first part should be review!

Introduction to Capital Structure Problem: What is the optimal mix of debt and equity, i.e., the capital structure that maximizes the value of the firm? Approach: Begin with a simple model (a framework) that identifies the relevant issues, then add realism.

A Road Map Perfect markets (no taxes)  capital structure is irrelevant +corporate taxes  more debt is better +financial distress and agency costs  optimal capital structure This whole process will take 2 weeks!

Options and Corporate Finance Consider a firm that will liquidate in 1 year, with $10 million of 1-year zero coupon debt outstanding. If the firm is worth less than $10 million in 1 year, the debtholders receive everything and the stockholders receive nothing. Otherwise, the debtholders receive $10 million and the stockholders receive the residual. Assumes absolute priority rules are followed (we’ll talk about this later!)

Equity and Debt Payoffs Firm value 10 Firm value V=B+S debt and equity sum to the firm Simple apllication of put-call parity 10 Equity: a call option on the firm Debt: firm - call = risk-free bond - put

An example A firm undertakes a risky, zero NPV project and will be worth either $99 mill. or $44 mill. in 1 year. Value of the unlevered firm is $60 mill. Risk free rate is 10% Firm 60 99 44 Zero NPV implies V is unchanged. Spreadsheet available.

Introducing Debt The firm finances itself through Debt of $55 million to be paid after 1 year. Firm 60 99 44 Debt ? 55 44 Equity ? 44 Zero NPV implies V is unchanged. Spreadsheet available.

Replicating Equity Replicate equity with a position in the firm financed by borrowing: 99 H - 1.1 B* = 44 44 H - 1.1 B* = 0  H = 0.8, B* = 32  S = 0.8(60) - 32 = $16 million Increasing volatility increases the value of the equity (and decreases the value of the debt). This is the agency conflict that generates the agency costs we will talk about later.

Replicating Debt Replicate debt with a position in the firm and a position in risk-free debt: 99 H - 1.1 B* = 55 44 H - 1.1 B* = 44  H = 0.2, B* = -32 B = 0.2(60) + 32 = $44 million V = S + B = 16 + 44 = $60 mill. Remained the same! H(S)+H(B)=1, B*(S)+B*(B)=0 YTM=55/44-1=25% E(r)=0.5(55/44-1)+0.5(44/44-1)=12.5% Expected return is less than promised yield because this is risky debt, I.e., expected cash flows are not promised cash flows.

Assumptions Perfect capital markets (no taxes or transaction costs) Personal and corporate borrowing at the same rate No information effects Personal and corporate borrowing at the same rate is a result of the other assumptions NOT an additional assumption.

The Primary Result The value of the firm is independent of its capital structure, i.e., the financing mix is irrelevant (Miller & Modigliani). Proposition I: VU = VL U-unlevered (no debt) V-levered (with debt)

Intuition Buying equity in the levered firm is firm-generated leverage Buying equity in the unlevered firm and borrowing is do-it-yourself leverage Conclusion: no one is willing to pay the firm for levering up when they are “free” to lever up individually You need to borrow at the same rate as the company. Why is this reasonable? Borrowing secured by unlevered equity (i.e., assets), which is the same thing that the company is doing (and in the same proportions). What is do-it-yourself unleverage, i.e., how do you generate unlevered equity payoffs when the firm is levered? Buy levered equity and debt in proportion to their market values.

Discount Rates The value result also has implications for discount rates (r0 is the cost of unlevered equity). Proposition II: rS = r0 + (B/S)(r0 - rB) WACC = r0 The WACC is constant and the cost of equity can be decomposed into business risk and financial risk. Under DCF there are 3 variables—cash flows, discount rates, and value. If cash flows are fixed, then values and discount rates must move together. If you plug r(S) into the definition of WACC you get WACC=r(0). These equations are saying the same thing.

Valuation: The Dividend Discount Model The stock price today should be the discounted value of expected future dividends P = t Dt/(1+rS)t If dividends are growing at a constant rate, then the price of the stock (not including current dividend) is P0 = D1 / (rS - g) Think about dividends defined broadly as all cash flows to the equity holders, i.e., dividends, stock repurchases, cash acquisitions. Watch the timing—price today, next period’s dividend

Expected Returns, Growth and P/E Ratios The valuation formula can be inverted to get expected returns: rS = (D1 / P0) + g Where does growth come from? g = bROE b — earnings retention rate, i.e., D=(1-b)E ROE—return on equity What are the implied P/E ratios? P0 = D1 / (rS - g) = (1-b) E1 / (rS – b ROE) P0 / E1 = (1-b) / (rS – b ROE) The expected return formulation can be used at the market level to get expected returns and hence the market risk premium (although they usually use the earnings/payout version). ROE is accounting ROE (on a cash flow basis), i.e., the denominator is book equity not market value equity. Why? What we want is the return on the actual dollars of equity invested in the projected. Market value includes not just the amount invested but also the NPV of the investment. An aside—when should you retain more earnings, i.e., increase b? When doing so increases the stock price. dP/db > 0 when ROE > r(S). ROE > r(S) is the same thing as the IRR rule (for equity investments) and hence the same thing as the NPV rule.

Equity Valuation The value of all the equity is just the aggregate value of all the shares outstanding, i.e., the discounted value of aggregate dividends. All the previous results apply.

Introducing Corporate Taxes Earnings are taxed at the corporate rate Interest expense is tax deductible Dividends are not tax deductible Tax rate: TC

Example..

Value Implications Proposition I: VL = VU + PV(tax shield) PV(tax shield) = t [TC(interest expense)t] / (1+ rB)t Debt reduces the firm’s tax liability and therefore increases value The more debt, the higher the value of the firm Total cash flows are fixed (i.e., the projects are fixed). All we are doing is dividing these cash flows among claimants. Reduce the value of the governments claim, and the residual value goes up.

An Example All equity firm with pre-tax earnings (cash flow) of $X in year 1, a retention rate of b, and growth rate g in perpetuity: VU = [(1-b)(1- TC)X] / (r0-g) If this firm adds $B of perpetual debt: PV(tax shield) = [TC (rB B)] / rB = TC B VL = VU + TC B This is just an example. These formulas do not apply generally!

Discount Rates Prop. II: rS = r0 + (1- TC)(B/S)(r0 - rB) WACC = [(S+(1- TC)B)/(S+B)] r0 Equity risk increases with leverage (but more slowly than in the no tax case) WACC decreases as the amount of debt increases Business risk/financial risk. B=0, WACC=r(0) S=0, WACC=(1-T)r(0) As before plugging r(S) into WACC definition gives WACC formula.

Recapitalization: An Example Firm characteristics: EBIT: 50% prob. of $1 million, 50% prob. of $2 million (in perpetuity) Depreciation = Cap. Ex. ΔNWC=0 100% payout (no growth, dividends = earnings) r0 = 10% (required return on unlevered equity) TC = 40% Standard no growth assumptions: Depr=capex, dNWC=0, 100% payout.

Unlevered Value VU = [(1- TC)EBIT] / r0 = [(1-0.4)1.5] / 0.1 = $9 mill. n = 1 million (shares outstanding) Share price: P = VU / n = $9.00 E[EBIT]=0.5(1)+0.5(2)=1.5

Income Statement EPS=NI/n E[EPS]=E[DPS] (100% payout) P=E[DPS]/r(0)=0.9/0.1=9 (forward looking so it is constant) Stock return=dividend yield (no capital gains) E[return]=required return Coincidence? I don’t think so. How does it work? Stock price depends on required return and determines expected return. Try it yourself, spreadsheet available.

Recapitalization Firm issues $5 million of perpetual debt (rB = 8%) and uses the proceeds to repurchase equity. On announcement: Shareholders revalue the firm: VL = VU + TC B = 9 + 0.4 (5) = $11 million Share price moves to $11/share $ 5 million repurchases 454.5 shares (n = 545.5) Time line Announce Stock price moves Sell debt and use proceeds to buy back equity at new price

Income Statement r(S)=D(1)/P(0)=1.21/11=11% Leverage increases risk (return more volatile) and increases value (less tax)

Assignments Reading Problem sets Cases RWJ: Chapters 16.1-16.9, Appendix 16B Problems: 16.2, 16.6, 16.8 Problem sets Problem Set 2 due monday Cases AHP due in 1 week