Class 2 – Revenue equivalence

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Yossi Sheffi Mass Inst of Tech Cambridge, MA ESD.260J/1.260J/15.
Advertisements

(Single-item) auctions Vincent Conitzer v() = $5 v() = $3.
Network Economics -- Lecture 4: Auctions and applications Patrick Loiseau EURECOM Fall 2012.
Auction Theory Class 5 – single-parameter implementation and risk aversion 1.
Class 4 – Some applications of revenue equivalence
Approximating optimal combinatorial auctions for complements using restricted welfare maximization Pingzhong Tang and Tuomas Sandholm Computer Science.
The Structure of Networks with emphasis on information and social networks T-214-SINE Summer 2011 Chapter 9 Ýmir Vigfússon.
CPS Bayesian games and their use in auctions Vincent Conitzer
Seminar in Auctions and Mechanism Design Based on J. Hartline’s book: Approximation in Economic Design Presented by: Miki Dimenshtein & Noga Levy.
Auctions. Strategic Situation You are bidding for an object in an auction. The object has a value to you of $20. How much should you bid? Depends on auction.
Intermediate Microeconomics Midterm (50%) (4/27) Final (50%) (6/22) Term grades based on relative ranking. Mon 1:30-2:00 ( 社科 757)
An Approximate Truthful Mechanism for Combinatorial Auctions An Internet Mathematics paper by Aaron Archer, Christos Papadimitriou, Kunal Talwar and Éva.
Auctions Auction types: –First price, sealed bid auction –Second price, sealed bid auction –English auction (ascending bid auction) –Dutch auction (descending.
Multi-item auctions with identical items limited supply: M items (M smaller than number of bidders, n). Three possible bidder types: –Unit-demand bidders.
Game Theory in Wireless and Communication Networks: Theory, Models, and Applications Lecture 6 Auction Theory Zhu Han, Dusit Niyato, Walid Saad, Tamer.
Auction. Types of Auction  Open outcry English (ascending) auction Dutch (descending) auction  Sealed bid First-price Second-price (Vickrey)  Equivalence.
Private-value auctions: theory and experimental evidence (Part I) Nikos Nikiforakis The University of Melbourne.
Auction Theory Class 3 – optimal auctions 1. Optimal auctions Usually the term optimal auctions stands for revenue maximization. What is maximal revenue?
Optimal auction design Roger Myerson Mathematics of Operations research 1981.
Game Theory 1. Game Theory and Mechanism Design Game theory to analyze strategic behavior: Given a strategic environment (a “game”), and an assumption.
Introduction to Game Theory
1. problem set 12 from Binmore’s Fun and Games. p.564 Ex. 41 p.565 Ex. 42.
Yang Cai Sep 15, An overview of today’s class Myerson’s Lemma (cont’d) Application of Myerson’s Lemma Revelation Principle Intro to Revenue Maximization.
Auction Theory Class 2 – Revenue equivalence 1. This class: revenue Revenue in auctions – Connection to order statistics The revelation principle The.
© 2009 Institute of Information Management National Chiao Tung University Lecture Note II-3 Static Games of Incomplete Information Static Bayesian Game.
Sequences of Take-It-or-Leave-it Offers: Near-Optimal Auctions Without Full Valuation Revelation Tuomas Sandholm and Andrew Gilpin Carnegie Mellon University.
Auction Seminar Optimal Mechanism Presentation by: Alon Resler Supervised by: Amos Fiat.
More on Social choice and implementations 1 TexPoint fonts used in EMF. Read the TexPoint manual before you delete this box.: AAA A Using slides by Uri.
6.853: Topics in Algorithmic Game Theory Fall 2011 Constantinos Daskalakis Lecture 21.
Mechanism Design CS 886 Electronic Market Design University of Waterloo.
Auction Theory תכנון מכרזים ומכירות פומביות Topic 7 – VCG mechanisms 1.
Yang Cai Oct 08, An overview of today’s class Basic LP Formulation for Multiple Bidders Succinct LP: Reduced Form of an Auction The Structure of.
Topic 2: Designing the “optimal auction” Reminder of previous classes: Discussed 1st price and 2nd price auctions. Found equilibrium strategies. Saw that.
Auctions serve the dual purpose of eliciting preferences and allocating resources between competing uses. A less fundamental but more practical reason.
6.853: Topics in Algorithmic Game Theory Fall 2011 Constantinos Daskalakis Lecture 22.
Advanced Subjects in GT Prepared by Rina Talisman Introduction Revenue Equivalence The Optimal Auction (Myerson 1981) Auctions.
1 TexPoint fonts used in EMF. Read the TexPoint manual before you delete this box.: A AAA A AA A.
Comp/Math 553: Algorithmic Game Theory Lecture 10
Comp/Math 553: Algorithmic Game Theory Lecture 11
Chapter 18 Auctions Key Concept: Honesty is the best policy in a private-value second price auction. However in a common-value auction, winner’s curse.
Bayesian games and their use in auctions
Comp/Math 553: Algorithmic Game Theory Lecture 08
CPS Mechanism design Michael Albert and Vincent Conitzer
Shyam Sunder, Yale University Kozminski Academy Warsaw, June 23, 2012
Comp/Math 553: Algorithmic Game Theory Lecture 09
Market/Agent-Oriented Programming
Tuomas Sandholm Computer Science Department Carnegie Mellon University
Internet Economics כלכלת האינטרנט
Class 6 – Common Values, Winner’s curse and Interdependent Values.
Implementation in Bayes-Nash equilibrium
Laddered auction Ashish Goel tanford University
Game Theory in Wireless and Communication Networks: Theory, Models, and Applications Lecture 6 Auction Theory Zhu Han, Dusit Niyato, Walid Saad, Tamer.
Market Design and Analysis Lecture 4
Implementation in Bayes-Nash equilibrium
Auctions: Basic Theory & Applications
Economics and Computation Week #13 Revenue of single Item auctions
Vincent Conitzer Mechanism design Vincent Conitzer
Auctions An auction is a mechanism for trading items by means of bidding. Dates back to 500 BC where Babylonians auctioned of women as wives. Position.
Vincent Conitzer CPS 173 Mechanism design Vincent Conitzer
Preference elicitation/ iterative mechanisms
Auctions Lirong Xia. Auctions Lirong Xia Sealed-Bid Auction One item A set of bidders 1,…,n bidder j’s true value vj bid profile b = (b1,…,bn) A sealed-bid.
CPS Preference elicitation/ iterative mechanisms
Implementation in Bayes-Nash equilibrium
Bayes Nash Implementation
Information, Incentives, and Mechanism Design
Auction Theory תכנון מכרזים ומכירות פומביות
Vincent Conitzer CPS Mechanism design Vincent Conitzer
CPS Bayesian games and their use in auctions
Information, Incentives, and Mechanism Design
Presentation transcript:

Class 2 – Revenue equivalence Auction Theory Class 2 – Revenue equivalence

This class Revenue in auctions The revelation principle Connection to order statistics The revelation principle The revenue equivalence theorem Example: all-pay auctions.

English vs. Vickrey The English Auction: Price starts at 0 Price increases until only one bidder is left. Vickrey (2nd price) auction: Bidders send bids. Highest bid wins, pays 2nd highest bid. Private value model: each person has a privately known value for the item. We saw: the two auctions are equivalent in the private value model. Auctions are efficient: dominant strategy for each player: truthfulness.

Dutch vs. 1st-price The Dutch Auction: Price starts at max-price. Price drops until a bidder agrees to buy. 1st-price auction: Bidders send bids. Highest bid wins, pays his bid. Dutch auctions and 1st price auctions are strategically equivalent. (asynchronous vs simple & fast) No dominant strategies. (tradeoff: chance of winning, payment upon winning.) Analysis in a Bayesian model: Values are randomly drawn from a probability distribution. Strategy: a function. “What is my bid given my value?”

Bayes-Nash eq. in 1st-price auctions We considered the simplest Bayesian model: n bidders. Values drawn uniformly from [0,1]. Then: In a 1st-price auction, it is a (Bayesian) Nash equilibrium when all bidders bid An auction is efficient, if in (Bayes) Nash equilibrium the bidder with the highest value always wins. 1st price is efficient!

Optimal auctions Usually the term optimal auctions stands for revenue maximization. What is maximal revenue? We can always charge the winner his value. Maximal revenue: optimal expected revenue in equilibrium. Assuming a probability distribution on the values. Over all the possible mechanisms. Under individual-rationality constraints (later).

Example: Spectrum auctions One of the main triggers to auction theory. FCC in the US sells spectrum, mainly for cellular networks. Improved auctions since the 90’s increased efficiency + revenue considerably. Complicated (“combinatorial”) auction, in many countries. (more details further in the course)

New Zealand Spectrum Auctions A Vickrey (2nd price) auction was run in New Zealand to sale a bunch of auctions. (In 1990) Winning bid: $100000 Second highest: $6 (!!!!) Essentially zero revenue. NZ Returned to 1st price method the year after. After that, went to a more complicated auction (in few weeks). Was it avoidable?

Auctions with uniform distributions A simple Bayesian auction model: 2 buyers Values are between 0 and 1. Values are distributed uniformly on [0,1] What is the expected revenue gained by 2nd-price and 1st price auctions?

Revenue in 2nd-price auctions In 2nd-price auction, the payment is the minimum of the two values. E[ revenue] = E[ min{x,y} ] Claim: when x,y ~ U[0,1] we have E[ min{x,y} ]=1/3

Revenue in 2nd-price auctions Proof: assume that v1=x. Then, the expected revenue is: We can now compute the expected revenue (expectation over all possible x): x 1

Order statistics Let v1,…,vn be n random variables. The highest realization is called the 1st-order statistic. The second highest is the called 2nd-order statistic. …. The smallest is the nth-order statistic. Example: the uniform distribution, 2 samples. The expected 1st-order statistic: 2/3 In auctions: expected efficiency The expected 2nd-order statistic: 1/3 In auctions: expected revenue

Expected order statistics 1 1/2 1/3 2/3 2/4 1/4 3/4 One sample Two samples Three samples In general, for the uniform distribution with n samples: k’th order statistic of n variables is (n+1-k)/n+1) 1st-order statistic: n/n+1

Revenue in 1st-price auctions We still assume 2 bidders, uniform distribution Revenue in 1st price: bidders bid vi/2. Revenue is the highest bid. Expected revenue = E[ max(v1/2,v2/2) ] = ½ E[ max(v1,v2)] = ½ × 2/3 = 1/3 Same revenue as in 2nd-price auctions.

1st vs. 2nd price Revenue in 2nd price: Revenue in 1st price: Bidders bid truthfully. Revenue is 2nd highest bid: Revenue in 1st price: bidders bid Expected revenue is What happened? Coincidence?

This class Revenue in auctions The revelation principle Connection to order statistics The revelation principle The revenue equivalence theorem Example: all-pay auctions.

Implementation Our general goal: given an objective (for example, maximize efficiency or revenue), construct an auction that achieves this goal in an equilibrium. "Implementation” Equilibrium concept: Bayes-Nash For example: 2nd-price auctions maximize efficiency in a Bayes-Nash equilibrium Even stronger solution: truthfulness (in dominant strategies). 1st price auctions also achieve this goal. Not truthful, no dominant strategies. Many other auctions are efficient (e.g., all-pay auctions).

Terminology Direct-revelation mechanism: player are asked to report their true value. Non direct revelation: English and dutch auction, most iterative auctions, concise menu of actions. Truthful mechanisms: direct-revelation mechanisms where revealing the truth is (a Bayes Nash) equilibrium. Other solution concepts may apply. What’s so special about revealing the truth? Maybe better results can be obtained when people report half their value, or any other strategy?

The revelation principle Problem: the space of possible mechanisms is often too large. A helpful insight: we can actually focus our attention to truthful (direct revelation) mechanisms. This will simplify the analysis considerably. “The revelation principle” “every outcome can be achieved by truthful mechanism” One of the simplest, yet trickiest, concepts in auction theory.

The revelation principle Theorem (“The Revelation Principle”): Consider an auction where the profile of strategies s1,…,sn is a Bayes-Nash equilibrium. Then, there exists a truthful mechanism with exactly the same allocation and payments (“payoff equivalent”). Recall: truthful = direct revelation + truthful Bayes-Nash equilibrium. Basic idea: we can simulate any mechanism via a truthful mechanism which is payoff equivalent.

The revelation principle Proof (trivial): The original mechanism: Auction protocol v1 v1s1(v1) s1(v1) Allocation (winners) v2 v2 s2(v2) s2(v2) payments v3 v3 s3(v3) s3(v3) v4 s4(v4) s4(v4) v4

The revelation principle Proof (trivial): A direct-revelation mechanism: Bidders reports their true types, The auction simulates their equilibrium strategies. Auction protocol v1 v1 v1s1(v1) Allocation (winners) v2 v2 v2 s2(v2) payments v3 v3 v3 s3(v3) v4 s4(v4) v4 v4 Equilibrium is straightforward: if a bidder had a profitable deviation here, he would have one in the original mechanism.

The revelation principle Example: In 1st-price auctions with the uniform distribution: bidders would bid truthfully and the mechanism will “change” their bids to be In English auctions (non direct revelation): people will bid truthfully, and the mechanism will raise hands according to their strategy in the auction. Bottom line: Due to the revelation principle, from now on we will concentrate on truthful mechanism.

This class Revenue in auctions The revelation principle Connection to order statistics The revelation principle The revenue equivalence theorem Example: all-pay auctions.

Revenue equivalence We saw examples where the revenue in 2nd-price and 1st-price auctions is the same. Can we have a general theorem?

Revenue Equivalence Theorem Assumptions: vi‘s are drawn independently from some F on [a,b] F is continuous and strictly increasing Bidders are risk neutral Theorem (The Revenue Equivalence Theorem): Consider two auction such that: (same allocation) When player i bids v his probability to win is the same in the two auctions (for all i and v) in equilibrium. (normalization) If a player bids a (the lowest possible value) he will pay the same amount in both auctions. Then, in equilibrium, the two auctions earn the same revenue.

Proof Idea: we will start from the incentive-compatibility (truthfulness) constraints. We will show that the allocation function of the auction actually determines the payment for each player. If the same allocation function is achieved in equilibrium, then the expected payment of each player must be the same. Due to the revelation principle, we will look at truthful auctions.

=ui(v’)+ ( v – v’) Qi(v’) Proof Consider some auction protocol A, and a bidder i. Notations: in the auction A, Qi(v) = the probability that bidder I wins when he bids v. pi(v) = the expected payment of bidder I when he bids v. ui(v) = the expected surplus (utility) of player I when he bids v and his true value is v. ui(v) = Qi(v) v - pi(v) In a truthful equilibrium: I gains higher surplus when bidding his true value v than some value v’. Qi(v) v - pi(v) ≥ Qi(v’) v - pi(v’) =ui(v) =ui(v’)+ ( v – v’) Qi(v’) We get: truthfulness  ui(v) ≥ ui(v’)+ ( v – v’) Qi(v’)

Proof We get: truthfulness  ui(v) ≥ ui(v’)+ ( v – v’) Qi(v’) or Similarly, since a bidder with true value v’ will not prefer bidding v and thus ui(v’) ≥ ui(v)+ ( v’ – v) Qi(v) or Let dv = v-v’ Taking dv  0 we get:

Proof Assume ui(a)=0 We saw: We know: And conclude: Of course: Interpretation: expected revenue, in equilibrium, depends only on the allocation. same allocation same revenue. integrating

Picture

Revenue equivalence theorem No coincidence! Somewhat unintuitively, revenue depends only on the way the winner is chosen, not on payments. Since 2nd-price auctions and 1st-price auctions have the same (efficient) allocation, they will earn the same revenue! One of the most striking results in mechanism design Applies in other, more general setting. Lesson: when designing auctions, focus on the allocation, not on tweaking the prices.

Remark: Individual rationality The following mechanism gains lots of revenue: Charge all players $10000000 Bidder will clearly not participate. We thus have individual-rationality (or participation) constraints on mechanisms: bidders gain positive utility in equilibrium . This is the reason for condition 2 in the theorem.

This class Revenue in auctions The revelation principle Connection to order statistics The revelation principle The revenue equivalence theorem Example: all-pay auctions.

Example: All-pay auction (1/3) Rules: Sealed bid Highest bid wins Everyone pay their bid Claim: Equilibrium with the uniform distribution: b(v)= Does it achieve more or less revenue? Note: Bidders shade their bids as the competition increases.

All-pay auction (2/3) expected payment per each player: her bid. Each bidder bids Expected payment for each bidder: Revenue: from n bidders Revenue equivalence!

All-pay auction (3/3) Examples: crowdsourcing over the internet: First person to complete a task for me gets a reward. A group of people invest time in the task. (=payment) Only the winner gets the reward. Advertising auction: Collect suggestion for campaigns, choose a winner. All advertiser incur cost of preparing the campaign. Only one wins. Lobbying War of attrition Animals invest (b1,b2) in fighting.

What did we see so far 2nd-price, 1st-price, all pay: all obtain the same seller revenue. Revenue equivalence theorem: Auctions with the same allocation decisions earn the same expected seller revenue in equilibrium. Constraint: individual rationality (participation constraint) Many assumptions: statistical independence, risk neutrality, no externalities, private values, …

Next topic Optimal revenue: which auctions achieve the highest revenue?