Introduction to Econometrics, 5th edition

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
CHOW TEST AND DUMMY VARIABLE GROUP TEST
Advertisements

EC220 - Introduction to econometrics (chapter 5)
EC220 - Introduction to econometrics (chapter 4)
Christopher Dougherty EC220 - Introduction to econometrics (chapter 5) Slideshow: slope dummy variables Original citation: Dougherty, C. (2012) EC220 -
1 THE DISTURBANCE TERM IN LOGARITHMIC MODELS Thus far, nothing has been said about the disturbance term in nonlinear regression models.
Christopher Dougherty EC220 - Introduction to econometrics (chapter 4) Slideshow: interactive explanatory variables Original citation: Dougherty, C. (2012)
HETEROSCEDASTICITY-CONSISTENT STANDARD ERRORS 1 Heteroscedasticity causes OLS standard errors to be biased is finite samples. However it can be demonstrated.
EC220 - Introduction to econometrics (chapter 7)
1 BINARY CHOICE MODELS: PROBIT ANALYSIS In the case of probit analysis, the sigmoid function F(Z) giving the probability is the cumulative standardized.
EC220 - Introduction to econometrics (chapter 2)
Christopher Dougherty EC220 - Introduction to econometrics (chapter 6) Slideshow: variable misspecification iii: consequences for diagnostics Original.
EC220 - Introduction to econometrics (chapter 1)
1 INTERPRETATION OF A REGRESSION EQUATION The scatter diagram shows hourly earnings in 2002 plotted against years of schooling, defined as highest grade.
TESTING A HYPOTHESIS RELATING TO A REGRESSION COEFFICIENT This sequence describes the testing of a hypotheses relating to regression coefficients. It is.
Chapter 4 – Nonlinear Models and Transformations of Variables.
SLOPE DUMMY VARIABLES 1 The scatter diagram shows the data for the 74 schools in Shanghai and the cost functions derived from a regression of COST on N.
BINARY CHOICE MODELS: LOGIT ANALYSIS
Christopher Dougherty EC220 - Introduction to econometrics (chapter 3) Slideshow: precision of the multiple regression coefficients Original citation:
Christopher Dougherty EC220 - Introduction to econometrics (chapter 4) Slideshow: semilogarithmic models Original citation: Dougherty, C. (2012) EC220.
Christopher Dougherty EC220 - Introduction to econometrics (chapter 4) Slideshow: nonlinear regression Original citation: Dougherty, C. (2012) EC220 -
Christopher Dougherty EC220 - Introduction to econometrics (chapter 10) Slideshow: maximum likelihood estimation of regression coefficients Original citation:
DERIVING LINEAR REGRESSION COEFFICIENTS
Christopher Dougherty EC220 - Introduction to econometrics (chapter 5) Slideshow: Chow test Original citation: Dougherty, C. (2012) EC220 - Introduction.
TOBIT ANALYSIS Sometimes the dependent variable in a regression model is subject to a lower limit or an upper limit, or both. Suppose that in the absence.
Christopher Dougherty EC220 - Introduction to econometrics (chapter 5) Slideshow: dummy variable classification with two categories Original citation:
Christopher Dougherty EC220 - Introduction to econometrics (chapter 5) Slideshow: two sets of dummy variables Original citation: Dougherty, C. (2012) EC220.
1 UNBIASEDNESS AND EFFICIENCY Much of the analysis in this course will be concerned with three properties of estimators: unbiasedness, efficiency, and.
Christopher Dougherty EC220 - Introduction to econometrics (chapter 5) Slideshow: the effects of changing the reference category Original citation: Dougherty,
Christopher Dougherty EC220 - Introduction to econometrics (chapter 5) Slideshow: dummy classification with more than two categories Original citation:
DUMMY CLASSIFICATION WITH MORE THAN TWO CATEGORIES This sequence explains how to extend the dummy variable technique to handle a qualitative explanatory.
1 INTERACTIVE EXPLANATORY VARIABLES The model shown above is linear in parameters and it may be fitted using straightforward OLS, provided that the regression.
THE FIXED AND RANDOM COMPONENTS OF A RANDOM VARIABLE 1 In this short sequence we shall decompose a random variable X into its fixed and random components.
Christopher Dougherty EC220 - Introduction to econometrics (chapter 10) Slideshow: binary choice logit models Original citation: Dougherty, C. (2012) EC220.
1 TWO SETS OF DUMMY VARIABLES The explanatory variables in a regression model may include multiple sets of dummy variables. This sequence provides an example.
Confidence intervals were treated at length in the Review chapter and their application to regression analysis presents no problems. We will not repeat.
ALTERNATIVE EXPRESSION FOR POPULATION VARIANCE 1 This sequence derives an alternative expression for the population variance of a random variable. It provides.
CONFLICTS BETWEEN UNBIASEDNESS AND MINIMUM VARIANCE
1 PROXY VARIABLES Suppose that a variable Y is hypothesized to depend on a set of explanatory variables X 2,..., X k as shown above, and suppose that for.
MULTIPLE RESTRICTIONS AND ZERO RESTRICTIONS
F TEST OF GOODNESS OF FIT FOR THE WHOLE EQUATION 1 This sequence describes two F tests of goodness of fit in a multiple regression model. The first relates.
MULTIPLE REGRESSION WITH TWO EXPLANATORY VARIABLES: EXAMPLE 1 This sequence provides a geometrical interpretation of a multiple regression model with two.
Simple regression model: Y =  1 +  2 X + u 1 We have seen that the regression coefficients b 1 and b 2 are random variables. They provide point estimates.
Christopher Dougherty EC220 - Introduction to econometrics (chapter 9) Slideshow: instrumental variable estimation: variation Original citation: Dougherty,
. reg LGEARN S WEIGHT85 Source | SS df MS Number of obs = F( 2, 537) = Model |
Christopher Dougherty EC220 - Introduction to econometrics (chapter 5) Slideshow: exercise 5.2 Original citation: Dougherty, C. (2012) EC220 - Introduction.
POSSIBLE DIRECT MEASURES FOR ALLEVIATING MULTICOLLINEARITY 1 What can you do about multicollinearity if you encounter it? We will discuss some possible.
(1)Combine the correlated variables. 1 In this sequence, we look at four possible indirect methods for alleviating a problem of multicollinearity. POSSIBLE.
1 We will continue with a variation on the basic model. We will now hypothesize that p is a function of m, the rate of growth of the money supply, as well.
COST 11 DUMMY VARIABLE CLASSIFICATION WITH TWO CATEGORIES 1 This sequence explains how you can include qualitative explanatory variables in your regression.
RAMSEY’S RESET TEST OF FUNCTIONAL MISSPECIFICATION 1 Ramsey’s RESET test of functional misspecification is intended to provide a simple indicator of evidence.
1 NONLINEAR REGRESSION Suppose you believe that a variable Y depends on a variable X according to the relationship shown and you wish to obtain estimates.
1 CHANGES IN THE UNITS OF MEASUREMENT Suppose that the units of measurement of Y or X are changed. How will this affect the regression results? Intuitively,
SEMILOGARITHMIC MODELS 1 This sequence introduces the semilogarithmic model and shows how it may be applied to an earnings function. The dependent variable.
GRAPHING A RELATIONSHIP IN A MULTIPLE REGRESSION MODEL The output above shows the result of regressing EARNINGS, hourly earnings in dollars, on S, years.
1 REPARAMETERIZATION OF A MODEL AND t TEST OF A LINEAR RESTRICTION Linear restrictions can also be tested using a t test. This involves the reparameterization.
F TESTS RELATING TO GROUPS OF EXPLANATORY VARIABLES 1 We now come to more general F tests of goodness of fit. This is a test of the joint explanatory power.
WHITE TEST FOR HETEROSCEDASTICITY 1 The White test for heteroscedasticity looks for evidence of an association between the variance of the disturbance.
1 COMPARING LINEAR AND LOGARITHMIC SPECIFICATIONS When alternative specifications of a regression model have the same dependent variable, R 2 can be used.
VARIABLE MISSPECIFICATION II: INCLUSION OF AN IRRELEVANT VARIABLE In this sequence we will investigate the consequences of including an irrelevant variable.
FOOTNOTE: THE COCHRANE–ORCUTT ITERATIVE PROCESS 1 We saw in the previous sequence that AR(1) autocorrelation could be eliminated by a simple manipulation.
VARIABLE MISSPECIFICATION I: OMISSION OF A RELEVANT VARIABLE In this sequence and the next we will investigate the consequences of misspecifying the regression.
Introduction to Econometrics, 5th edition
Introduction to Econometrics, 5th edition
Introduction to Econometrics, 5th edition
Introduction to Econometrics, 5th edition
Introduction to Econometrics, 5th edition
Introduction to Econometrics, 5th edition
Introduction to Econometrics, 5th edition
Introduction to Econometrics, 5th edition
Presentation transcript:

Introduction to Econometrics, 5th edition Type author name/s here Dougherty Introduction to Econometrics, 5th edition Chapter heading Chapter 4: Nonlinear Models and Transformations of Variables © Christopher Dougherty, 2016. All rights reserved.

SEMILOGARITHMIC MODELS This sequence introduces the semilogarithmic model and shows how it may be applied to an earnings function. The dependent variable is linear but the explanatory variables, multiplied by their coefficients, are exponents of e. 1

SEMILOGARITHMIC MODELS The differential of Y with respect to X simplifies to b2Y. 2

SEMILOGARITHMIC MODELS Hence the proportional change in Y per unit change in X is equal to b2. It is therefore independent of the value of X. 3

SEMILOGARITHMIC MODELS Strictly speaking, this interpretation is valid only for small values of b2. When b2 is not small, the interpretation may be a little more complex. 4

SEMILOGARITHMIC MODELS Suppose that X increases by an amount DX and that as a consequence Y increases by an amount DY. 5

SEMILOGARITHMIC MODELS We can rewrite the right side of the equation as shown. 6

SEMILOGARITHMIC MODELS We can simplify the right side of the equation as shown. 7

SEMILOGARITHMIC MODELS Now expand the exponential term using the standard expression for e to some power. 8

SEMILOGARITHMIC MODELS Subtract Y from both sides. 9

SEMILOGARITHMIC MODELS negligible We now consider two cases: where b2 and DX are so small that (b2 DX)2 is negligible, and the alternative. 10

SEMILOGARITHMIC MODELS negligible If (b2 DX)2 is negligible, we obtain the same interpretation of b2 as we did using the calculus, as one would expect. 11

SEMILOGARITHMIC MODELS not negligible If (b2 DX)2 is not negligible, the proportional change in Y given a DX change in X has an extra term. (We are assuming that b2 and DX are small enough that terms with higher powers of DX can be neglected.) 12

SEMILOGARITHMIC MODELS not negligible if DX is one unit Usually we talk about the effect of a one-unit change in X. If DX = 1, the proportional change in Y is as shown. The issue now becomes whether b2 is so small that the second and subsequent terms can be neglected. 13

SEMILOGARITHMIC MODELS b1 is the value of Y when X is equal to zero (note that e0 is equal to 1). 14

SEMILOGARITHMIC MODELS To fit a function of this type, you take logarithms of both sides. The right side of the equation becomes a linear function of X (note that the logarithm of e, to base e, is 1). Hence we can fit the model with a linear regression, regressing log Y on X. 15

SEMILOGARITHMIC MODELS . reg LGEARN S ---------------------------------------------------------------------------- Source | SS df MS Number of obs = 500 -----------+------------------------------ F( 1, 498) = 60.71 Model | 16.5822819 1 16.5822819 Prob > F = 0.0000 Residual | 136.016938 498 .273126381 R-squared = 0.1087 -----------+------------------------------ Adj R-squared = 0.1069 Total | 152.59922 499 .30581006 Root MSE = .52261 LGEARN | Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval] -----------+---------------------------------------------------------------- S | .0664621 .0085297 7.79 0.000 .0497034 .0832207 _cons | 1.83624 .1289384 14.24 0.000 1.58291 2.089571 Here is the regression output from a wage equation regression using Data Set 21. The estimate of b2 is 0.066. As an approximation, this implies that an extra year of schooling increases hourly earnings by a proportion 0.066. 16

SEMILOGARITHMIC MODELS . reg LGEARN S ---------------------------------------------------------------------------- Source | SS df MS Number of obs = 500 -----------+------------------------------ F( 1, 498) = 60.71 Model | 16.5822819 1 16.5822819 Prob > F = 0.0000 Residual | 136.016938 498 .273126381 R-squared = 0.1087 -----------+------------------------------ Adj R-squared = 0.1069 Total | 152.59922 499 .30581006 Root MSE = .52261 LGEARN | Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval] -----------+---------------------------------------------------------------- S | .0664621 .0085297 7.79 0.000 .0497034 .0832207 _cons | 1.83624 .1289384 14.24 0.000 1.58291 2.089571 In everyday language it is usually more natural to talk about percentages rather than proportions, so we multiply the coefficient by 100. It implies that an extra year of schooling increases hourly earnings by 6.6%. 17

SEMILOGARITHMIC MODELS . reg LGEARN S ---------------------------------------------------------------------------- Source | SS df MS Number of obs = 500 -----------+------------------------------ F( 1, 498) = 60.71 Model | 16.5822819 1 16.5822819 Prob > F = 0.0000 Residual | 136.016938 498 .273126381 R-squared = 0.1087 -----------+------------------------------ Adj R-squared = 0.1069 Total | 152.59922 499 .30581006 Root MSE = .52261 LGEARN | Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval] -----------+---------------------------------------------------------------- S | .0664621 .0085297 7.79 0.000 .0497034 .0832207 _cons | 1.83624 .1289384 14.24 0.000 1.58291 2.089571 not negligible If DX is one unit, If we take account of the fact that a year of schooling is not a marginal change, and work out the effect exactly, the proportional increase is 0.068 and the percentage increase 6.8%. 18

SEMILOGARITHMIC MODELS . reg LGEARN S ---------------------------------------------------------------------------- Source | SS df MS Number of obs = 500 -----------+------------------------------ F( 1, 498) = 60.71 Model | 16.5822819 1 16.5822819 Prob > F = 0.0000 Residual | 136.016938 498 .273126381 R-squared = 0.1087 -----------+------------------------------ Adj R-squared = 0.1069 Total | 152.59922 499 .30581006 Root MSE = .52261 LGEARN | Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval] -----------+---------------------------------------------------------------- S | .0664621 .0085297 7.79 0.000 .0497034 .0832207 _cons | 1.83624 .1289384 14.24 0.000 1.58291 2.089571 not negligible If DX is one unit, In general, if a unit change in X is genuinely marginal, the estimate of b2 will be small and one can interpret it directly as an estimate of the proportional change in Y per unit change in X. 19

SEMILOGARITHMIC MODELS . reg LGEARN S ---------------------------------------------------------------------------- Source | SS df MS Number of obs = 500 -----------+------------------------------ F( 1, 498) = 60.71 Model | 16.5822819 1 16.5822819 Prob > F = 0.0000 Residual | 136.016938 498 .273126381 R-squared = 0.1087 -----------+------------------------------ Adj R-squared = 0.1069 Total | 152.59922 499 .30581006 Root MSE = .52261 LGEARN | Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval] -----------+---------------------------------------------------------------- S | .0664621 .0085297 7.79 0.000 .0497034 .0832207 _cons | 1.83624 .1289384 14.24 0.000 1.58291 2.089571 not negligible If DX is one unit, However if a unit change in X is not small, the coefficient may be large and the second term might not be negligible. In the present case, a year of schooling is not marginal, but evem so the refinement makes only a small difference. 20

SEMILOGARITHMIC MODELS . reg LGEARN S ---------------------------------------------------------------------------- Source | SS df MS Number of obs = 500 -----------+------------------------------ F( 1, 498) = 60.71 Model | 16.5822819 1 16.5822819 Prob > F = 0.0000 Residual | 136.016938 498 .273126381 R-squared = 0.1087 -----------+------------------------------ Adj R-squared = 0.1069 Total | 152.59922 499 .30581006 Root MSE = .52261 LGEARN | Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval] -----------+---------------------------------------------------------------- S | .0664621 .0085297 7.79 0.000 .0497034 .0832207 _cons | 1.83624 .1289384 14.24 0.000 1.58291 2.089571 not negligible If DX is one unit, In general, when b2 is less than 0.1, there is little to be gained by working out the effect exactly. 21

SEMILOGARITHMIC MODELS . reg LGEARN S ---------------------------------------------------------------------------- Source | SS df MS Number of obs = 500 -----------+------------------------------ F( 1, 498) = 60.71 Model | 16.5822819 1 16.5822819 Prob > F = 0.0000 Residual | 136.016938 498 .273126381 R-squared = 0.1087 -----------+------------------------------ Adj R-squared = 0.1069 Total | 152.59922 499 .30581006 Root MSE = .52261 LGEARN | Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval] -----------+---------------------------------------------------------------- S | .0664621 .0085297 7.79 0.000 .0497034 .0832207 _cons | 1.83624 .1289384 14.24 0.000 1.58291 2.089571 . reg LGEARN S Source | SS df MS Number of obs = 540 -------------+------------------------------ F( 1, 538) = 140.05 Model | 38.5643833 1 38.5643833 Prob > F = 0.0000 Residual | 148.14326 538 .275359219 R-squared = 0.2065 -------------+------------------------------ Adj R-squared = 0.2051 Total | 186.707643 539 .34639637 Root MSE = .52475 ------------------------------------------------------------------------------ LGEARN | Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval] -------------+---------------------------------------------------------------- S | .1096934 .0092691 11.83 0.000 .0914853 .1279014 _cons | 1.292241 .1287252 10.04 0.000 1.039376 1.545107 The intercept in the regression is an estimate of log b1. From it, we obtain an estimate of b1 equal to e1.836, which is 6.27. 22

SEMILOGARITHMIC MODELS . reg LGEARN S ---------------------------------------------------------------------------- Source | SS df MS Number of obs = 500 -----------+------------------------------ F( 1, 498) = 60.71 Model | 16.5822819 1 16.5822819 Prob > F = 0.0000 Residual | 136.016938 498 .273126381 R-squared = 0.1087 -----------+------------------------------ Adj R-squared = 0.1069 Total | 152.59922 499 .30581006 Root MSE = .52261 LGEARN | Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval] -----------+---------------------------------------------------------------- S | .0664621 .0085297 7.79 0.000 .0497034 .0832207 _cons | 1.83624 .1289384 14.24 0.000 1.58291 2.089571 . reg LGEARN S Source | SS df MS Number of obs = 540 -------------+------------------------------ F( 1, 538) = 140.05 Model | 38.5643833 1 38.5643833 Prob > F = 0.0000 Residual | 148.14326 538 .275359219 R-squared = 0.2065 -------------+------------------------------ Adj R-squared = 0.2051 Total | 186.707643 539 .34639637 Root MSE = .52475 ------------------------------------------------------------------------------ LGEARN | Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval] -------------+---------------------------------------------------------------- S | .1096934 .0092691 11.83 0.000 .0914853 .1279014 _cons | 1.292241 .1287252 10.04 0.000 1.039376 1.545107 Literally this implies that a person with no schooling would earn $6.27 per hour. However it is dangerous to extrapolate so far from the range for which we have data. 23

SEMILOGARITHMIC MODELS Here is the scatter diagram with the semilogarithmic regression. 24

SEMILOGARITHMIC MODELS Here is the semilogarithmic regression line plotted in a scatter diagram with the untransformed data, with the linear regression shown for comparison. 25

SEMILOGARITHMIC MODELS There is not much difference in the fit of the regression lines, but the semilogarithmic regression is more satisfactory in two respects. 26

SEMILOGARITHMIC MODELS The linear specification predicts that hourly earnings will increase by a fixed amount, $1.27, with each additional year of schooling. This is implausible for high levels of education. The semi-logarithmic specification allows the increment to increase with level of education. 27

SEMILOGARITHMIC MODELS Second, the linear specification predicts very low earnings for an individual with no schooling. The semilogarithmic specification predicts hourly earnings of $6.27, which at least is not obvious nonsense. 28

Copyright Christopher Dougherty 2016. These slideshows may be downloaded by anyone, anywhere for personal use. Subject to respect for copyright and, where appropriate, attribution, they may be used as a resource for teaching an econometrics course. There is no need to refer to the author. The content of this slideshow comes from Section 4.2 of C. Dougherty, Introduction to Econometrics, fifth edition 2016, Oxford University Press. Additional (free) resources for both students and instructors may be downloaded from the OUP Online Resource Centre www.oxfordtextbooks.co.uk/orc/dougherty5e/. Individuals studying econometrics on their own who feel that they might benefit from participation in a formal course should consider the London School of Economics summer school course EC212 Introduction to Econometrics http://www2.lse.ac.uk/study/summerSchools/summerSchool/Home.aspx or the University of London International Programmes distance learning course EC2020 Elements of Econometrics www.londoninternational.ac.uk/lse. 2016.05.02