5 Choice.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
UTILITY MAXIMIZATION AND CHOICE
Advertisements

Chapter Five Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those.
Choice.
Properties of Demand Functions Comparative statics analysis of ordinary demand functions -- the study of how ordinary demands x 1 *(p 1,p 2,m) and x 2.
Economic Rationality The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available to it. The.
Chapter Five Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those.
Chapter Five Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those.
Chapter Three Preferences. Rationality in Economics u Behavioral Postulate: A decisionmaker always chooses its most preferred alternative from its set.
Choice. Q: What is the Optimal Choice? Budget constraint Indifference curves More preferred bundles.
Demand. Consumer Demand Consumer’s demand functions:
Choice Continued.
Chapter Five Choice.
Chapter Three Preferences. Rationality in Economics u Behavioral Postulate: An economic decisionmaker always chooses her most preferred alternative from.
Chapter Five Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those.
Chapter Five Choice 选择. Structure 5.1 The optimal choice of consumers 5.2 Consumer demand  Interior solution (内解)  Corner solution (角解)  “Kinky” solution.
Chapter 5 Choice.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 5 Choice. © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 2 Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that.
Rational Choice. CHOICE 1. Scarcity (income constraint) 2. Tastes (indifference map/utility function)
Chapter 5 Choice of consumption.
L03 Utility. Big picture u Behavioral Postulate: A decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from the set of affordable alternatives. u Budget.
Budgetary and Other Constraints on Choice
Chapter 5 CHOICE.
L04 Choice. Big picture u Behavioral Postulate: A decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from the set of affordable alternatives. u Budget.
L02 Preferences. Rationality in Economics u Behavioral Postulate: A decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from the set of affordable alternatives.
Chapter 5 CHOICE.
L03 Utility. Quiz How much do you like microeconomics A: I love it (unconditionally) B: I cannot live without it C: I would die for it D: All of the above.
Course: Microeconomics Text: Varian’s Intermediate Microeconomics
PREFERENCES. Rationality in Economics Behavioral Postulate: A decisionmaker always chooses its most preferred alternative from its set of available alternatives.
L02 Preferences.
Utility Maximization and Choice
L06 Demand.
L08 Buying and Selling.
Chapter 5 Choice Key Concept: Optimal choice means a consumer chooses the best he can afford. Tangency is neither necessary nor sufficient. The correct.
L03 Utility.
Choice.
Chapter 4 Individual Demands
Chapter 6 Demand.
L03 Utility.
3 Preferences.
L04 Choice.
L04 Choice.
Chapter 5 Theory of Consumer Behavior
Chapter 5 Choice.
L08 Buying and Selling.
Chapter Three Preferences.
Chapter Six Demand.
PREFERENCES.
Rational Choice.
L08 Buying and Selling.
L06 Demand.
L02 Preferences.
L09 Review.
L03 Utility.
L03 Utility.
L04 Choice.
RL1 Review.
L02 Preferences.
L04 Choice.
Choice.
Chapter 3 Preferences.
L03 Utility.
L08 Buying and Selling.
Utility Functions f ~ p p
L02 Preferences.
L02 Preferences.
Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 – Spring 2009
L02 Preferences.
Economic Rationality The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available to it. The.
Presentation transcript:

5 Choice

Economic Rationality The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available to it. The available choices constitute the choice set. How is the most preferred bundle in the choice set located?

Rational Constrained Choice x2 x1

Rational Constrained Choice Utility x1

Rational Constrained Choice Utility x2 x1

Rational Constrained Choice Utility x2 x1

Rational Constrained Choice Utility x2 x1

Rational Constrained Choice Utility x2 x1

Rational Constrained Choice Utility x2 x1

Rational Constrained Choice Utility x2 x1

Rational Constrained Choice Utility Affordable, but not the most preferred affordable bundle. x2 x1

Rational Constrained Choice Utility The most preferred of the affordable bundles. Affordable, but not the most preferred affordable bundle. x2 x1

Rational Constrained Choice Utility x2 x1

Rational Constrained Choice Utility x2 x1

Rational Constrained Choice x2 Utility x1

Rational Constrained Choice x2 Utility x1

Rational Constrained Choice x2 x1

Rational Constrained Choice x2 Affordable bundles x1

Rational Constrained Choice x2 Affordable bundles x1

Rational Constrained Choice x2 More preferred bundles Affordable bundles x1

Rational Constrained Choice x2 More preferred bundles Affordable bundles x1

Rational Constrained Choice x2 x2* x1* x1

Rational Constrained Choice x2 (x1*,x2*) is the most preferred affordable bundle. x2* x1* x1

Rational Constrained Choice The most preferred affordable bundle is called the consumer’s ORDINARY DEMAND at the given prices and budget. Ordinary demands will be denoted by x1*(p1,p2,m) and x2*(p1,p2,m).

Rational Constrained Choice When x1* > 0 and x2* > 0 the demanded bundle is INTERIOR. If buying (x1*,x2*) costs $m then the budget is exhausted.

Rational Constrained Choice x2 (x1*,x2*) is interior. (x1*,x2*) exhausts the budget. x2* x1* x1

Rational Constrained Choice x2 (x1*,x2*) is interior. (a) (x1*,x2*) exhausts the budget; p1x1* + p2x2* = m. x2* x1* x1

Rational Constrained Choice x2 (x1*,x2*) is interior . (b) The slope of the indiff. curve at (x1*,x2*) equals the slope of the budget constraint. x2* x1* x1

Rational Constrained Choice (x1*,x2*) satisfies two conditions: (a) the budget is exhausted; p1x1* + p2x2* = m (b) the slope of the budget constraint, -p1/p2, and the slope of the indifference curve containing (x1*,x2*) are equal at (x1*,x2*).

Computing Ordinary Demands How can this information be used to locate (x1*,x2*) for given p1, p2 and m?

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example. Suppose that the consumer has Cobb-Douglas preferences.

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example. Suppose that the consumer has Cobb-Douglas preferences. Then

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example. So the MRS is

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example. So the MRS is At (x1*,x2*), MRS = -p1/p2 so

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example. So the MRS is At (x1*,x2*), MRS = -p1/p2 so (A)

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example. (x1*,x2*) also exhausts the budget so (B)

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example. So now we know that (A) (B)

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example. So now we know that (A) Substitute (B)

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example. So now we know that (A) Substitute (B) and get This simplifies to ….

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example.

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example. Substituting for x1* in then gives

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example. So we have discovered that the most preferred affordable bundle for a consumer with Cobb-Douglas preferences is

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example.

Rational Constrained Choice When x1* > 0 and x2* > 0 and (x1*,x2*) exhausts the budget, and indifference curves have no ‘kinks’, the ordinary demands are obtained by solving: (a) p1x1* + p2x2* = y (b) the slopes of the budget constraint, -p1/p2, and of the indifference curve containing (x1*,x2*) are equal at (x1*,x2*).

Rational Constrained Choice But what if x1* = 0? Or if x2* = 0? If either x1* = 0 or x2* = 0 then the ordinary demand (x1*,x2*) is at a corner solution to the problem of maximizing utility subject to a budget constraint.

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case MRS = -1 x1

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case MRS = -1 Slope = -p1/p2 with p1 > p2. x1

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case MRS = -1 Slope = -p1/p2 with p1 > p2. x1

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case MRS = -1 Slope = -p1/p2 with p1 > p2. x1

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case MRS = -1 Slope = -p1/p2 with p1 < p2. x1

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case So when U(x1,x2) = x1 + x2, the most preferred affordable bundle is (x1*,x2*) where if p1 < p2 and if p1 > p2.

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case MRS = -1 Slope = -p1/p2 with p1 = p2. x1

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case All the bundles in the constraint are equally the most preferred affordable when p1 = p2. x1

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Non-Convex Preferences Case Better x1

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Non-Convex Preferences Case

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Non-Convex Preferences Case Which is the most preferred affordable bundle? x1

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Non-Convex Preferences Case The most preferred affordable bundle x1

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Non-Convex Preferences Case Notice that the “tangency solution” is not the most preferred affordable bundle. x2 The most preferred affordable bundle x1

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2} x2 x2 = ax1 x1

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2} x2 x2 = ax1 MRS = 0 x1

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2} x2 ¥ MRS = - x2 = ax1 MRS = 0 x1

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2} x2 ¥ MRS = - MRS is undefined x2 = ax1 MRS = 0 x1

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2} x2 x2 = ax1 x1

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2} x2 Which is the most preferred affordable bundle? x2 = ax1 x1

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2} x2 The most preferred affordable bundle x2 = ax1 x1

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2} x2 x2 = ax1 x2* x1* x1

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2} x2 (a) p1x1* + p2x2* = m x2 = ax1 x2* x1* x1

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2} x2 (a) p1x1* + p2x2* = m (b) x2* = ax1* x2 = ax1 x2* x1* x1

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case (a) p1x1* + p2x2* = m; (b) x2* = ax1*.

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case (a) p1x1* + p2x2* = m; (b) x2* = ax1*. Substitution from (b) for x2* in (a) gives p1x1* + p2ax1* = m

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case (a) p1x1* + p2x2* = m; (b) x2* = ax1*. Substitution from (b) for x2* in (a) gives p1x1* + p2ax1* = m which gives

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case (a) p1x1* + p2x2* = m; (b) x2* = ax1*. Substitution from (b) for x2* in (a) gives p1x1* + p2ax1* = m which gives

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case (a) p1x1* + p2x2* = m; (b) x2* = ax1*. Substitution from (b) for x2* in (a) gives p1x1* + p2ax1* = m which gives A bundle of 1 commodity 1 unit and a commodity 2 units costs p1 + ap2; m/(p1 + ap2) such bundles are affordable.

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2} x2 x2 = ax1 x1