The Analysis of Competitive Markets

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Market Intervention under Competitive Market Conditions
Advertisements

Competition and the Market
Market Distortions Caused by Government Policies All such programs cause a net loss to the economy. Gain is usually to the producers who lobby Congress.
The Analysis of Competitive Markets
Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Consumer and Producer Surplus When government controls price,
Chapter 9 Use tools of competitive markets to analyze effects of government intervention. Tools (See Figure 9.1): Consumer Surplus = CS: –Difference between.
Chapter Nine Applying the Competitive Model. © 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.9–2 Applying the Competitive Model In this chapter, we.
CHAPTER 9 OUTLINE 9.1 Evaluating the Gains and Losses from Government Policies—Consumer and Producer Surplus 9.2 The Efficiency of a Competitive Market.
Government Intervention in Agriculture
Chapter 15 Market Interventions McGraw-Hill/Irwin
Evaluating the Welfare Effects of Government Policy: CS & PS
The Analysis of Competitive Markets
Evaluating Impacts of Market Intervention In this lecture, we analyze the welfare effects of government policies to “intervene” the competitive markets.
Fernando & Yvonn Quijano Prepared by: The Analysis of Competitive Markets 9 C H A P T E R Copyright © 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice.
Economic Efficiency, Government Price Setting, and Taxes
Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. Chapter 9Slide 2 The Efficiency of a Competitive Market When do competitive markets generate an inefficient.
Market Equilibrium Price Quantity S D Pm Qm At a Price Above Equilibrium Price Quantity S D Pm Qm P1 QsQd Qs > QD Surplus Too many goods and services.
The Analysis of Competitive Markets
Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Topics to be Discussed Evaluating the Gains and Losses from Government.
Chapter Nine Applying the Competitive Model. © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 9-2 Topics  Consumer Welfare.  Producer Welfare. 
Oct The Analysis of Competitive Markets.
$2.50 $2.00 Price Frozen pizzas per week $3.00 $3.50 MB 4 MB 3 MB 2 MB 1
Government Influences on Markets CHAPTER 7 C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to 1Explain.
The Analysis of Competitive Markets. Chapter 9Slide 2 Topics to be Discussed Evaluating the Gains and Losses from Government Policies--Consumer and Producer.
Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 92 Topics to be Discussed Evaluating the Gains and Losses from Government.
Econ 201 Spring 2009 Lecture 4.1 Elasticity Taxes & Subsidies
Market Equilibrium Price Quantity S D Pm Qm At a Price Above Equilibrium Price Quantity S D Pm Qm P1 QsQd Qs > QD Surplus Too many goods and services.
CHAPTER 6 LECTURE – GOVERNMENT ACTIONS IN MARKETS.
MICROECONOMICS by Robert S. Pindyck Daniel Rubinfeld Ninth Edition
Markets: Applications
Competitive Markets: Applications.
Chapter 15 Market Interventions McGraw-Hill/Irwin
Demand and Supply Applications
Supply, Demand, and Government Policies
Ch. 6: Markets in Action. Price ceiling and inefficiencies.
Taxes & Subsidies Economic Welfare Supplement
APPLIED COMPETITIVE ANALYSIS
Supply, Demand, and Government Policies
16 Equilibrium.
Econ 200: Lecture 7 October 19, 2017 Poll Everywhere
Chapter 16 Equilibrium.
The Analysis of Competitive Markets
Chapter Sixteen Equilibrium.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2010 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
CHAPTER 3 MARKET EQUILIBRIUM. CHAPTER 3 MARKET EQUILIBRIUM.
Demand & Supply Dr. Alok Kumar Pandey Dr. Alok Pandey.
Consumer Surplus Consumer surplus is the value the consumer gets from buying a product, less its price (paying less than you are willing to pay) It is.
CHAPTER 9 OUTLINE 9.1 Evaluating the Gains and Losses from Government Policies—Consumer and Producer Surplus 9.2 The Efficiency of a Competitive Market.
Gains from Trade. Gains from Trade The Gains from Trade Figure 8.2 At the free trade price of PW, Home supply will fall to S1 and Home demand will.
Government Policy & Economic Welfare
Supply, Demand, and Government Policies
Elasticity and Its Application
Ch. 6: Markets in Action. Price ceiling and inefficiencies.
CHAPTER 9 OUTLINE 9.1 Evaluating the Gains and Losses from Government Policies—Consumer and Producer Surplus 9.2 The Efficiency of a Competitive Market.
The Analysis of Competitive Markets
Application: The Costs of Taxation
Supply, Demand, and Government Policies
Applications of Welfare
The Welfare Effects of Import Tariff and Quota: “Small” Country
Government Policy & Economic Welfare Week 4
Costs and Benefits of a Tariff
Supply, Demand, and Government Policies
The Analysis of Competitive Markets
CHAPTER 6 Consumer and Producer Surplus
Supply, Demand, and Government Policies
CHAPTER 3 MARKET EQUILIBRIUM. CHAPTER 3 MARKET EQUILIBRIUM.
Taxes & Subsidies Economic Welfare Supplement
CHAPTER 9 OUTLINE 9.1 Evaluating the Gains and Losses from Government Policies—Consumer and Producer Surplus 9.2 The Efficiency of a Competitive Market.
International Trade and Tariff
Indirect Taxes, Subsidies and Price Controls
Presentation transcript:

The Analysis of Competitive Markets Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets 1

Topics to be Discussed Evaluating the Gains and Losses from Government Policies--Consumer and Producer Surplus The Efficiency of a Competitive Market Minimum Prices Chapter 9 2

Topics to be Discussed Price Supports and Production Quotas Import Quotas and Tariffs The Impact of a Tax or Subsidy Chapter 9 3

Evaluating the Gains and Losses from Government Policies--Consumer and Producer Surplus Review Consumer surplus is the total benefit or value that consumers receive beyond what they pay for the good. Producer surplus is the total benefit or revenue that producers receive beyond what it cost to produce a good. Chapter 9 5

Consumer and Producer Surplus Price Consumer Surplus D 10 7 Consumer B Consumer A Between 0 and Q0 consumers A and B receive a net gain from buying the product-- consumer surplus S 5 Q0 Consumer C Producer Surplus Between 0 and Q0 producers receive a net gain from selling each product-- producer surplus. Quantity 9

Evaluating the Gains and Losses from Government Policies--Consumer and Producer Surplus To determine the welfare effect of a governmental policy we can measure the gain or loss in consumer and producer surplus. Welfare Effects Gains and losses caused by government intervention in the market. Chapter 9 10

Change in Consumer and Producer Surplus from Price Controls Pmax Q1 Q2 Suppose the government imposes a price ceiling Pmax which is below the market-clearing price P0. Price S D The loss to producers is the sum of rectangle A and triangle C. Triangle B and C together measure the deadweight loss. B A C The gain to consumers is the difference between the rectangle A and the triangle B. Deadweight Loss P0 Q0 Chapter 9 Quantity 13

Change in Consumer and Producer Surplus from Price Controls Observations: The total loss is equal to area B + C. The total change in surplus = (A - B) + (-A - C) = -B - C The deadweight loss is the inefficiency of the price controls or the loss of the producer surplus exceeds the gain from consumer surplus. Chapter 9 14

Change in Consumer and Producer Surplus from Price Controls Observation Consumers can experience a net loss in consumer surplus when the demand is sufficiently inelastic Chapter 9 15

Effect of Price Controls When Demand Is Inelastic B A Pmax C Q1 If demand is sufficiently inelastic, triangle B can be larger than rectangle A and the consumer suffers a net loss from price controls. Example Oil price controls and gasoline shortages in 1979 Price S D P0 Q2 Quantity Chapter 9 17

The Efficiency of a Competitive Market When do competitive markets generate an inefficient allocation of resources or market failure? 1) Externalities Costs or benefits that do not show up as part of the market price (e.g. pollution) Chapter 9 30

The Efficiency of a Competitive Market When do competitive markets generate an inefficient allocation of resources or market failure? 2) Lack of Information Imperfect information prevents consumers from making utility- maximizing decisions. Chapter 9 30

The Efficiency of a Competitive Market Government intervention in these markets can increase efficiency. Government intervention without a market failure creates inefficiency or deadweight loss. Chapter 9 31

Welfare Loss When Price Is Held Below Market-Clearing Level Q0 P1 Q1 A B C When price is regulated to be no higher than P1, the deadweight loss given by triangles B and C results. Chapter 9 Quantity 34

Welfare Loss When Price Is Held Above Market-Clearing Level Q3 A B C Q2 What would the deadweight loss be if QS = Q2? When price is regulated to be no lower than P2 only Q3 will be demanded. The deadweight loss is given by triangles B and C Price S D P0 Q0 Chapter 9 Quantity 37

Minimum Prices Periodically government policy seeks to raise prices above market-clearing levels. We will investigate this by looking at a price floor and the minimum wage. Chapter 9 49

Price Minimum Pmin Q3 Q2 S D P0 Q0 If producers produce Q2, the amount Q2 - Q3 will go unsold. Price S D P0 Q0 B A The change in producer surplus will be A - C - D. Producers may be worse off. C D Quantity Chapter 9 52

Firms are not allowed to results in unemployment. The Minimum Wage A wmin L1 L2 Unemployment Firms are not allowed to pay less than wmin. This results in unemployment. w S D w0 L0 B The deadweight loss is given by triangles B and C. C L Chapter 9 55

Price Supports and Production Quotas Much of agricultural policy is based on a system of price supports. This is support price is set above the equilibrium price and the government buys the surplus. This is often combined with incentives to reduce or restrict production Chapter 9 63

Price Supports S D P0 Q0 D + Qg Qg B D Ps Q2 Q1 Price A To maintain a price Ps the government buys quantity Qg . The change in consumer surplus = -A - B, and the change in producer surplus is A + B + D Ps Q2 Q1 Quantity Chapter 9 66

Price Supports D + Qg Qg S Ps P0 D Q1 Q0 Q2 The cost to the government is the speckled rectangle Ps(Q2-Q1) Price D + Qg Qg S Ps Total welfare loss D-(Q2-Q1)ps A B D P0 Total Welfare Loss D Q1 Q0 Q2 Quantity Chapter 9 66

Price Supports Question: Is there a more efficient way to increase farmer’s income by A + B + D? Chapter 9 68

Price Supports and Production Quotas The government can also cause the price of a good to rise by reducing supply. Chapter 9 69

Price Supports and Production Quotas What is the impact of: 1) Controlling entry into the taxicab market? 2) Controlling the number of liquor licenses? Chapter 9 69

Supply Restrictions PS S’ Q1 D P0 Q0 S Supply restricted to Q1 Price Supply shifts to S’ @ Q1 Price D P0 Q0 S B A CS reduced by A + B Change in PS = A - C Deadweight loss = BC C D Quantity Chapter 9 71

Supply Restrictions PS S’ Q1 D P0 Q0 S Ps is maintained with Price and incentive Cost to government = B + C + D Price D P0 Q0 S A B D C Quantity Chapter 9 71

Supply Restrictions = A - C + B + C + D = A + B + D. The change in consumer and producer surplus is the same as with price supports. = -A - B + A + B + D - B - C - D = -B - C. B A Quantity Price D P0 Q0 PS S S’ C Chapter 9 73

Supply Restrictions Questions: How could the government reduce the cost and still subsidize the farmer? Which is more costly: supports or acreage limitations? B A Quantity Price D P0 Q0 PS S S’ C Chapter 9 74

Import Tariff or Quota That Eliminates Imports D P0 Q0 S In a free market, the domestic price equals the world price PW. Price QS QD PW Imports A B C By eliminating imports, the price is increased to PO. The gain is area A. The loss to consumers A + B + C, so the deadweight loss is B + C. How high would a tariff have to be to get the same result? Quantity Chapter 9 92

Import Tariff or Quota (general case) The increase in price can be achieved by a quota or a tariff. Area A is again the gain to domestic producers. The loss to consumers is A + B + C + D. D S Price D C B QS QD Q’S Q’D A P* Pw Quantity Chapter 9 94

Import Tariff or Quota (general case) If a tariff is used the government gains D, so the net domestic product loss is B + C. If a quota is used instead, rectangle D becomes part of the profits of foreign producers, and the net domestic loss is B + C + D. D C B QS QD Q’S Q’D A P* Pw Quantity S Price Chapter 9 94

Import Tariff or Quota (general case) Question: Would the U.S. be better off or worse off with a quota instead of a tariff? (e.g. Japanese import restrictions in the 1980s) D S Price D C B QS QD Q’S Q’D A P* Pw Quantity Chapter 9 95

The Sugar Quota The world price of sugar has been as low as 4 cents per pound, while in the U.S. the price has been 20-25 cents per pound. Chapter 9 96

The Sugar Quota The Impact of a Restricted Market (1997) U.S. production = 15.6 billion pounds U.S. consumption = 21.1 billion pounds U.S. price = 22 cents/pound World price = 11 cents/pound Chapter 9 97

The Sugar Quota The Impact of a Restricted Market U.S. ES = 1.54 U.S. ED = -0.3 U.S. supply: QS = -7.83+ 1.07P U.S. demand: QD = 27.45 - 0.29P P = .23 and Q = 13.7 billion pounds Chapter 9 98

Sugar Quota in 1997 SUS DUS D A B Price PW = 11 PUS = 21.9 C QS = 4.0 (cents/lb.) PW = 11 PUS = 21.9 C D B QS = 4.0 Q’S = 15.6 Q’d = 21.1 Qd = 24.2 A The cost of the quotas to consumers was A + B + C + D, or $2.4b. The gain to producers was area A, or $1b. 20 16 11 8 4 5 10 15 20 25 30 Quantity (billions of pounds) 100

Sugar Quota in 1997 SUS DUS D A B Price PW = 11 PUS = 21.9 C 20 16 11 (cents/lb.) PW = 11 PUS = 21.9 B D C Rectangle D was the gain to foreign producers who obtained quota allotments, or $600 million. Triangles B and C represent the deadweight loss of $800 million. 20 A 16 11 8 4 Qd = 24.2 5 10 15 20 25 30 Quantity (billions of pounds) QS = 4.0 Q’S = 15.6 Q’d = 21.1 100

The Impact of a Tax or Subsidy The burden of a tax (or the benefit of a subsidy) falls partly on the consumer and partly on the producer. We will consider a specific tax which is a tax of a certain amount of money per unit sold. Chapter 9 103

Incidence of a SpecificTax Q1 PS Pb t Pb is the price (including the tax) paid by buyers. PS is the price sellers receive, net of the tax. The burden of the tax is split evenly. Price D S B D A Buyers lose A + B, and sellers lose D + C, and the government earns A + D in revenue. The deadweight loss is B + C. C P0 Q0 Quantity Chapter 9 106

Incidence of a Specific Tax Four conditions that must be satisfied after the tax is in place: 1) Quantity sold and Pb must be on the demand line: QD = QD(Pb) 2) Quantity sold and PS must be on the supply line: QS = QS(PS) Chapter 9 107

Incidence of a Specific Tax Four conditions that must be satisfied after the tax is in place: 3) QD = QS 4) Pb - PS = tax Chapter 9 108

Impact of a Tax Depends on Elasticities of Supply and Demand Burden on Buyer Burden on Seller S D Price Price Q1 Pb PS t Q1 Pb PS t Q0 P0 Quantity Quantity 110

The Impact of a Tax or Subsidy Pass-through fraction ES/(ES - Ed) For example, when demand is perfectly inelastic (Ed = 0), the pass-through fraction is 1, and all the tax is borne by the consumer. Chapter 9 111

The Effects of a Tax or Subsidy A subsidy can be analyzed in much the same way as a tax. It can be treated as a negative tax. The seller’s price exceeds the buyer’s price. Chapter 9 112

upon the elasticities of Subsidy Price D S Q1 PS Pb s Like a tax, the benefit of a subsidy is split between buyers and sellers, depending upon the elasticities of supply and demand. P0 Q0 Quantity Chapter 9 114

Subsidy With a subsidy (s), the selling price Pb is below the subsidized price PS so that: s = PS - Pb Chapter 9 115

Subsidy The benefit of the subsidy depends upon Ed /ES. If the ratio is small, most of the benefit accrues to the consumer. If the ratio is large, the producer benefits most. Chapter 9 115

A Tax on Gasoline Measuring the Impact of a 50 Cent Gasoline Tax Intermediate-run EP of demand = -0.5 QD = 150 - 50P EP of supply = 0.4 QS = 60 + 40P QS = QD at $1 and 100 billion gallons per year (bg/yr) Chapter 9 116

A Tax on Gasoline With a 50 cent tax QD = 150 - 50Pb = 60 + 40PS = QS 150 - 50(PS+ .50) = 60 + 40PS PS = .72 Pb = .5 + PS Pb = $1.22 Chapter 9 117

A Tax on Gasoline With a 50 cent tax Q = 150 -(50)(1.22) = 89 bg/yr Q falls by 11% Chapter 9 118

Impact of a 50 Cent Gasoline Tax D 60 Price ($ per gallon) 1.50 D A Lost Consumer Surplus Lost Producer PS = .72 Pb = 1.22 The annual revenue from the tax is .50(89) or $44.5 billion. The buyer pays 22 cents of the tax, and the producer pays 28 cents. 89 t = 0.50 11 100 P0 = 1.00 .50 Quantity (billion gallons per year) 50 150 Chapter 9 122

Impact of a 50 Cent Gasoline Tax D 60 Price ($ per gallon) 1.50 D A Lost Consumer Surplus Lost Producer PS = .72 Pb = 1.22 89 t = 0.50 11 100 P0 = 1.00 Deadweight loss = $2.75 billion/yr .50 Quantity (billion gallons per year) 50 150 Chapter 9 122

Summary Simple models of supply and demand can be used to analyze a wide variety of government policies. In each case, consumer and producer surplus are used to evaluate the gains and losses to consumers and producers. Chapter 9 123

Summary When government imposes a tax or subsidy, price usually does not rise or fall by the full amount of the tax or subsidy. Government intervention generally leads to a deadweight loss. Chapter 9 124

Summary Government intervention in a competitive market is not always a bad thing. Chapter 9 124

The Analysis of Competitive Markets End of Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets 1