- CHAPTER 13 - Equity Valuation And Personal Taxes.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Stock Ownership Less Than 100%
Advertisements

The Value of Common Stocks. Topics Covered  How Common Stocks are Traded  How To Value Common Stock  Capitalization Rates  Stock Prices and EPS 
DIVIDENDS AND DIVIDEND POLICY Chapter 17. Dividend: cash paid out of earnings Distribution: cash payment from sources other than earnings Cash Dividends.
The Value of Common Stocks Principles of Corporate Finance Seventh Edition Richard A. Brealey Stewart C. Myers Slides by Matthew Will Chapter 4 McGraw.
McGraw-Hill © 2004 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Equity Markets and Stock Valuation Chapter 7.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. 8 Stock Valuation.
Stock Valuation Chapter 9.1,9.2.
1 Capital Budgeting Overview  Capital Budgeting is the set of valuation techniques for real asset investment decisions.  Capital Budgeting Steps estimating.
CHAPTER 09 Cost of Capital
Stock Valuation The price of stocks in the market place is the present value of the cash flows that stockholders have claim to: These cash flows consist.
© 2003 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Stock Valuation Chapter Eight.
Stock Valuation P.V. Viswanath. 2 Key Concepts and Skills  Understand how stock prices depend on future dividends and dividend growth  Be able to compute.
© 2003 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Stock Valuation Chapter Eight.
Stocks & Stock Market Primary Market - Place where the sale of new stock first occurs. Initial Public Offering (IPO) - First offering of stock to the general.
The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., 2000
Value of Bonds and Common Stocks
Lecture 7 The Value of Common Stocks Managerial Finance FINA 6335 Ronald F. Singer.
The Value of Common Stocks Chapter 4. Topics Covered  How Common Stocks are Traded  How To Value Common Stock  Capitalization Rates  Stock Prices.
CHAPTER 9 The Cost of Capital
BUA321 Chapter 9 Class notes Cost of capital. feature=player_detailpage&v=JKJ glPkAJ5o feature=player_detailpage&v=JKJ.
Cost of Capital Chapter 10.
Shares and Taxation Taxation implications of owning shares.
Stock Valuation Chapter 9.1,9.2. Outline Investing in stocks – Capital gains, dividend yield, return The Constant Dividend Growth Model The Dividend and.
5- 1 Outline 5: Stock & Bond Valuation  Bond Characteristics  Bond Prices and Yields  Stocks and the Stock Market  Book Values, Liquidation Values.
The Value of Common Stocks
Chapter 14 Cost of Capital
FIN 819: lecture 2'1 Review of the Valuation of Common Stocks How to apply the PV concept.
1 Calculating the Cost of Capital Three steps to calculate it: 1.Find the required rate of return on each kind of security the firm has issued 2.Find the.
Week 2 Seminar Principles of Corporate Finance Eighth Edition Chapter 2, 3, and 4 Adopted from slides by Matthew Will Copyright © 2006 by The McGraw-Hill.
The value of common stocks
Copyright © 2009 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved. Chapter 10 The Cost of Capital.
Chapter McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Cost of Capital 11.
Stock Valuation. Cash Flows for Stockholders If you buy a share of stock, you can receive cash in two ways –The company pays dividends –You sell your.
CORPORATE FINANCE Week 4 – 17&19 Oct Stock and Company Valuation – Dividend Growth Model, Free Cash Flow Model I. Ertürk Senior Fellow in Banking.
Capital Structure with Taxes
Chapter 7 Valuing Stocks TOPICS COVERED Stocks and the Stock Market Valuing Common Stocks Simplifying the Dividend Discount Model Growth Stocks and Income.
Chapter 4 Principles of Corporate Finance Eighth Edition Value of Bond and Common Stocks Slides by Matthew Will Copyright © 2006 by The McGraw-Hill Companies,
Shares and Taxation Taxation implications of owning shares.
Investment Analysis Lecture: 13 Course Code: MBF702.
Stock Valuation. 2 Valuation The determination of what a stock is worth; the stock's intrinsic value If the price exceeds the valuation, buy the stock.
Principles of Bond and Stock Valuation Estimating value by discounting future cash flows.
Investment Analysis Lecture: 14 Course Code: MBF702.
Chapter 5 Principles PrinciplesofCorporateFinance Ninth Edition The Value of Common Stocks Slides by Matthew Will Copyright © 2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies,
Chapter 5 Principles PrinciplesofCorporateFinance Concise Edition The Value of Common Stocks Slides by Matthew Will Copyright © 2009 by The McGraw-Hill.
F9 Financial Management. 2 Section G: Business Valuations Designed to give you the knowledge and application of: G2. Models for the valuation of shares.
Capital Budgeting Overview
Lecture 3 How to value bonds and common stocks
The Value of Common Stocks
Common Stock Valuation
Liquidity and Efficiency
CHARACTERISTICS OF COMMON STOCKS
Chapter 11 Stockholders’ equity
Stock Valuation.
Stock Valuation.
Chapter 4 The Value of Common Stocks Principles of Corporate Finance
Final Review FIN3701.
CCI Entrepreneurship Curriculum
Chapter 10 Stock Valuation
Dividends and Dividend Policy
Chapter 14 Cost of Capital
- CHAPTER 14 - Financial Leverage (Revisited)
Lecture 4 The Value of Common Stocks
The composition of long-term finance used by the firm
Chapter 15 Financial Statement Analysis Student Version
The Valuation and Characteristics of Stock
Limited company (plc) A plc will normally be financed by two types of long-term capital Equity capital Debt capital.
Valuing Stocks -- Summary of Formula
11 Chapter Cost of Capital.
Weighted Average Cost of Capital (Ch )
Investments: Analysis and Management Common Stock Valuation
Presentation transcript:

- CHAPTER 13 - Equity Valuation And Personal Taxes

Equity valuation and personal taxes We consider the implications of personal taxes on dividends and capital gains, and progress to describe an imputation tax system.

The discounting of dividends model revisited A difficulty with the discounting of dividends model (Eqn 5.6): 𝑃 0 𝑐𝑢𝑚 =$ 𝐷𝐼𝑉 0 + $𝐷𝐼𝑉 1 (1+𝑘) + $𝐷𝐼𝑉 2 1+𝑘 2 + $𝐷𝐼𝑉 3 1+𝑘 3 + . . . + $𝐷𝐼𝑉 𝑁 1+𝑘 𝑁 (5.6) is that it assumes that $1 of dividends equates with $1 of markets value. Consider, for example, a firm that terminates with a closing dividend: 𝑃 0 𝑐𝑢𝑚 =$ 𝐷𝐼𝑉 0

A new discounting of dividends model In effect, we require that Eqn 5.6 should be replaced by 𝑃 0 𝑒𝑥 =$ 𝐷𝐼𝑉 0 𝑥 𝑞+ $𝐷𝐼𝑉 1 𝑥 𝑞 (1+𝑘) + $𝐷𝐼𝑉 2 𝑥 𝑞 1+𝑘 2 + $𝐷𝐼𝑉 3 𝑥 𝑞 1+𝑘 3 + . . . + $𝐷𝐼𝑉 𝑁 𝑥 𝑞 1+𝑘 𝑁 (13.3) where q is the market value of a $1 dividend

The market value of a $1 dividend? Imagine that a share has a market value of $P0 and is about to pay a dividend, $DIV. Suppose that you are an investor about to purchase the share, cum-dividend so as to receive the dividend, $DIV, at a market price of $Pcum. Alternatively, you might choose to purchase the share ex-dividend at what you anticipate will be a lower cost, say, $Pex (since you forego the dividend). What is the rational price, $Pex, at which you are prepared to purchase the share ex-dividend in relation to the current cum-dividend market price, $ Pcum?

The market value of a $1 dividend (cont) You could argue that purchasing the share cum-dividend provides an additional $DIV (1- td) in your pocket plus an additional $(Pcum - Pex)tg of capital gains tax relief when you come to sell the share. In this case, you would determine the ex-dividend share price you are prepared to pay ($Pex) in relation to the current cum-dividend share price ($Pcum) by equating the difference in prices - $(Pcum - Pex) - with the difference in benefits: Pcum - Pex = $DIV (1- td) + $(Pcum - Pex)tg which (with a little manipulation) provides the theoretical change in share price when the firm makes a dividend, $DIV: Pcum - Pex = $𝐷𝐼𝑉 1− 𝑡 𝑑 1− 𝑡 𝑔 (13.2)

The market value of a $1 dividend (cont) Given Pcum - Pex = $𝐷𝐼𝑉 1− 𝑡 𝑑 1− 𝑡 𝑔 (previous slide) (13.2) we therefore deduce, in a world where investors can be represented as subjective to a personal tax on dividends = td, and on capital gains = tg, that the market value of a $1 dividend (which we shall call q), is determined as: q = 1− 𝑡 𝑑 1− 𝑡 𝑔 (13.4)

Dimensional Consistency We note that our new Eqn 13.3: 𝑃 0 𝑐𝑢𝑚 =$ 𝐷𝐼𝑉 0 𝑥 𝑞+ $𝐷𝐼𝑉 1 𝑥 𝑞 (1+𝑘) + $𝐷𝐼𝑉 2 𝑥 𝑞 1+𝑘 2 + $𝐷𝐼𝑉 3 𝑥 𝑞 1+𝑘 3 + . . . + $𝐷𝐼𝑉 𝑁 𝑥 𝑞 1+𝑘 𝑁 accords with the principle of dimensional consistency, in that $DIVi x q represents the market valuation of the dividend, so that we determine a market value ($P0) by discounting the market value of dividends ($DIVi x q) by a discount factor (k) that represents investor’s market capital growth rate.

The cost of equity redefined In Eqn 13.3, we have k as 𝑘= 𝐷𝐼𝑉 1 .𝑞 + 𝑃 1 𝑒𝑥 − 𝑃 0 𝑒𝑥 𝑃 0 𝑒𝑥 (13.5) which identifies k as investors’ required capital growth rate for the firm inclusive of the firm’s cash distributions. Equation 13.5 may be refigured as: k = d.q + g (13.6) where d represents shareholders’ expectation for the firm’s dividend yield - 𝐷𝐼𝑉 1 𝑃 0 𝑒𝑥 − and g represents shareholders’ expectation for the firm’s capital growth rate (net of the firm’s dividend payments) - ie 𝑃 1 𝑒𝑥 − 𝑃 0 𝑒𝑥 𝑃 0 𝑒𝑥 - with q identifying the market value of $1 of the firm’s distributions as dividends.

The components of a stock’s capital appreciation

An example Suppose that you are applying Eqn 5.8: 𝑃 0 𝑒𝑥 =𝑠ℎ𝑎𝑟𝑒 𝑣𝑎𝑙𝑢𝑒 0 𝑒𝑥 = $ 𝐷𝐼𝑉 1 𝑘−𝑔 to the valuation of a share in Company Fats that has maintained a steady growth rate of 2.0% over a number of years. The share has recently paid a dividend and is trading at $20.0. Consistent with the firm’s reliable growth rate in dividends over the years, you anticipate a dividend of $1.60 one year from now. You also believe that the firm can maintain a growth rate of 4.0% going forward. Accordingly, with Eqn 5.8, you determine shareholders’ required return in the above firm (k) as k = $ 𝐷𝐼𝑉 1 𝑃 0 𝑒𝑥 + g = $1.60 $20.0 + 0.04 = 0.08+0.04 = 12.0%.

Accordingly, you estimate the fair price of Domino as An example (cont) Now suppose that you are seeking to value a share in Company Domino, which, you believe, has similar characteristics and hence a similar cost of equity to Fats. This share has an anticipated dividend one year from now = $10.0 and also appears likely to maintain a growth rate of 2.0% going forward. Accordingly, you estimate the fair price of Domino as 𝑃 0 𝑒𝑥 = $ 𝐷𝐼𝑉 1 𝑘−𝑔 = $10.0 0.12−0.02 = $100.

An example (cont) Required Re-evaluate your above calculation is the light of your consideration of personal taxes.

An example (cont) Solution Eqn 5.6 becomes 𝑃 0 𝑒𝑥 =𝑠ℎ𝑎𝑟𝑒 𝑣𝑎𝑙𝑢𝑒 0 𝑒𝑥 = $ 𝐷𝐼𝑉 1 𝑥 𝑞 𝑘−𝑔 Hence we have: k = $ 𝐷𝐼𝑉 1 𝑥𝑞 𝑃 0 𝑒𝑥 + g = $1.60𝑥0.8 $20.0 + 0.04 = 0.064+0.04 = 10.4%. For Domino, we now determine 𝑃 0 𝑒𝑥 = $ 𝐷𝐼𝑉 1 𝑥 𝑞 𝑘−𝑔 = $10.0𝑥0.8 0.104−0.02 = $95.2 (5% less than when we ignore personal tax effects)

Break time

Personal taxes and an imputation tax system An imputation tax system recognizes that when the firm pays a dividend from the firm’s after-corporate tax earnings to shareholders, the firm’s shareholders - as owners of the firm - have already paid corporate tax on the firm’s earnings. Thus, an imputation tax system allows that corporate tax (at rate Tc) paid by the firm may be imputed (attributed) as a pre- payment of the firm’s shareholders personal tax liability on dividends received.

Personal taxes and an imputation tax system (cont) The logic that is applied is that - with a corporate tax rate (Tc) of, say, 30% - when a shareholder receives a 70 cents dividend, the 70 cents represents $1.0 of earnings that the firm earned prior to corporate tax (since $1.0 of earnings before corporate tax equates with $1.0 x 0.7 = 70 cents after corporate tax).

Personal taxes and an imputation tax system (cont) An imputation tax system therefore allows that on receiving a 70 cents dividend, a shareholder with a personal marginal tax liability (tp) on income of, say, 40%, should be allowed to retain 60% - not of the 70 cents received – but of the $1.0 of firm earnings prior to corporate tax that allowed the 70 cents to be paid as a dividend.

Personal taxes and an imputation tax system (cont) In other words, on receiving a dividend $DIV, the above shareholder is allowed to retain 60% of the earnings that funded the dividend payout prior to corporate tax; which is to say, the shareholder is allowed to retain: After tax dividend = $𝐷𝐼𝑉 1− 𝑇 𝑐 1− 𝑡 𝑝 (13.7)

Personal taxes and an imputation tax system (cont) Suppose we identify the shareholder’s effective tax liability on the $DIV received as teff – meaning that by definition of teff , the shareholder gets to keep $DIV (1- teff) . We therefore can write: $𝐷𝐼𝑉 1− 𝑇 𝑐 1− 𝑡 𝑝 =$𝐷𝐼𝑉(1− 𝑡 𝑒𝑓𝑓 ), yielding: 𝑡 𝑒𝑓𝑓 =1− 1− 𝑡 𝑝 1− 𝑇 𝑐 (13.8)

Personal taxes and an imputation tax system (cont) Suppose that the corporate tax rate is 30% in Australia, against which you receive a fully-franked dividend of $1.16. Assume that your personal marginal tax rate on income received is 40%. Calculate the proportion of the $1.16 dividend that you are able to maintain after fulfilling your personal tax obligations. Calculate your effective tax rate on the $1.16 dividend received.

Personal taxes and an imputation tax system (cont) You “get to keep” : $1.16(1−0.4) (1−0.3) = $0.994 (99.4 cents). With Eqn 13.8, your effective tax rate is determined as 𝑡 𝑒𝑓𝑓 =1− 1− 𝑡 𝑝 1− 𝑇 𝑐 = 1 - 0.6 0.7 = 14.3%. ( Check: 𝑡𝑎𝑥 𝑝𝑎𝑖𝑑 𝑑𝑖𝑣𝑖𝑑𝑒𝑛𝑑 𝑟𝑒𝑐𝑒𝑖𝑣𝑒𝑑 = $(1.16 −0.994) $1.16 = 14.3% )

Review We have observed that the discounting of dividends model of Chapter 5 is strictly invalidated if we allow for personal taxes. In addition, we have assessed the theoretical implications of personal taxes under an “imputation” tax system.