Chapter 3 Preferences.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Preferences. Rationality in Economics u Behavioral Postulate: A decisionmaker always chooses its most preferred alternative from its set of available.
Advertisements

Chapter Five Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those.
Choice.
Chapter Four Utility. Preferences - A Reminder u x y: x is preferred strictly to y.  x  y: x and y are equally preferred. u x y: x is preferred at least.
Chapter 3 Preferences Choose the “best” thing one can “afford” Start with consumption bundles (a complete list of the goods that is involved in consumer’s.
Chapter 3. * Prerequisite: A binary relation R on X is said to be Complete if xRy or yRx for any pair of x and y in X; Reflexive if xRx for any x in X;
Tastes/Preferences Indifference Curves.
Combinations (X1, Y1) and (X2, Y2) provide the same level of utility
Intermediate Microeconomics
Chapter Five Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those.
PREFERENCES AND UTILITY
Utility.
Chapter Three Preferences.
Chapter Seven Revealed Preference. Revealed Preference Analysis u Suppose we observe the demands (consumption choices) that a consumer makes for different.
Chapter Five Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those.
Chapter Three Preferences. Rationality in Economics u Behavioral Postulate: A decisionmaker always chooses its most preferred alternative from its set.
Utility.
Schedule of Classes September, 3 September, 10 September, 17 – in-class#1 September, 19 – in-class#2 September, 24 – in-class#3 (open books) September,
Chapter Three Preferences. Rationality in Economics u Behavioral Postulate: A decisionmaker always chooses its most preferred alternative from its set.
Preferences. Preference Relation The consumer strictly prefers bundle X to bundle Y: The consumer is indifferent between X and Y:
1 Chapter 3 PREFERENCES AND UTILITY Copyright ©2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.
1 Intermediate Microeconomics Preferences. 2 Consumer Behavior Budget Set organizes information about possible choices available to a given consumer.
Chapter Three Preferences. Rationality in Economics u Behavioral Postulate: An economic decisionmaker always chooses her most preferred alternative from.
Chapter Three Preferences 偏好. Structure 3.1 Preference relations 3.2 Assumptions about preferences 3.3 Graphical representation of preferences—indifference.
Chapter 5 Choice.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 4 Utility. © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 2 Preferences - A Reminder u x y: x is preferred strictly to y.  x.
Rationality in Economics Behavioral Postulate: A decisionmaker always chooses its most preferred alternative from its set of available alternatives. So.
Course: Microeconomics Text: Varian’s Intermediate Microeconomics 1.
Chapter 3 Preferences.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 3 Preferences.
1 Preferences Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 – Spring 2009.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 4 Utility. © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 2 Preferences - A Reminder u x y: x is preferred strictly to y.  x.
Chapter Three Preferences. u Consumer behavior is best understood in three distinct steps: 1. Consumer Preferences: The first step is to find a practical.
L03 Utility. Big picture u Behavioral Postulate: A decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from the set of affordable alternatives. u Budget.
Budgetary and Other Constraints on Choice
L02 Preferences. Rationality in Economics u Behavioral Postulate: A decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from the set of affordable alternatives.
L03 Utility. Quiz How much do you like microeconomics A: I love it (unconditionally) B: I cannot live without it C: I would die for it D: All of the above.
Recall: Consumer behavior Why are we interested? –New good in the market. What price should be charged? How much more for a premium brand? –Subsidy program:
UTILITY. Chapter 11 What is Utility? A way of representing preferences Utility is not money (but it is a useful analogy) Typical relationship between.
Course: Microeconomics Text: Varian’s Intermediate Microeconomics
PREFERENCES. Rationality in Economics Behavioral Postulate: A decisionmaker always chooses its most preferred alternative from its set of available alternatives.
RATIONAL CONSUMER CHOICE
L02 Preferences.
Preferences and Utility
Chapter 3 Preferences Intermediate Microeconomics:
4 Utility.
RATIONAL CONSUMER CHOICE
L03 Utility.
Choice.
L03 Utility.
3 Preferences.
Theory of Consumer Behavior
Chapter 5 Choice.
Chapter Three Preferences.
Chapter Seven Revealed Preference.
Chapter 7 Revealed Preference.
PREFERENCES.
L02 Preferences.
L03 Utility.
L03 Utility.
L02 Preferences.
Choice.
L03 Utility.
Chapter 3 Preferences Key Concept: characterize preferences by a binary comparison measuring at least as good as. Derive the indifference curves for a.
5 Choice.
L02 Preferences.
L02 Preferences.
L02 Preferences.
Chapter 2 A Theory of Preferences
Presentation transcript:

Chapter 3 Preferences

Rationality in Economics Behavioral Postulate: A decisionmaker always chooses its most preferred alternative from its set of available alternatives. So to model choice we must model decisionmakers’ preferences.

Preference Relations Comparing two different consumption bundles, x and y: strict preference: x is more preferred than is y. weak preference: x is as at least as preferred as is y. indifference: x is exactly as preferred as is y.

Preference Relations Particularly, they are ordinal relations; i.e. they state only the order in which bundles are preferred.

Preference Relations p p denotes strict preference; x y means that bundle x is preferred strictly to bundle y. p p

Preference Relations p p denotes strict preference; x y means bundle x is preferred strictly to bundle y. ~ denotes indifference; x ~ y means x and y are equally preferred. p p

Preference Relations p p f ~ f ~ denotes strict preference so x y means that bundle x is preferred strictly to bundle y. ~ denotes indifference; x ~ y means x and y are equally preferred. denotes weak preference; x y means x is preferred at least as much as is y. p p ~ f ~ f

Preference Relations ~ f ~ f x y and y x imply x ~ y.

Preference Relations ~ f ~ f ~ f ~ f p x y and y x imply x ~ y. x y and (not y x) imply x y. ~ f ~ f p

Assumptions about Preference Relations Completeness: For any two bundles x and y it is always possible to make the statement that either x y or y x. ~ f ~ f

Assumptions about Preference Relations Reflexivity: Any bundle x is always at least as preferred as itself; i.e. x x. ~ f

Assumptions about Preference Relations Transitivity: If x is at least as preferred as y, and y is at least as preferred as z, then x is at least as preferred as z; i.e. x y and y z x z. ~ f ~ f ~ f

Indifference Curves Take a reference bundle x’. The set of all bundles equally preferred to x’ is the indifference curve containing x’; the set of all bundles y ~ x’. Since an indifference “curve” is not always a curve a better name might be an indifference “set”.

Indifference Curves x2 x’ ~ x” ~ x”’ x’ x” x”’ x1

Indifference Curves x2 z x y p p x z y x1

Indifference Curves I1 All bundles in I1 are strictly preferred to all in I2. x2 x z I2 All bundles in I2 are strictly preferred to all in I3. y I3 x1

Indifference Curves x2 x I(x’) I(x) x1 WP(x), the set of bundles weakly preferred to x. x I(x’) I(x) x1

Indifference Curves x2 x I(x) x1 WP(x), the set of bundles weakly preferred to x. x WP(x) includes I(x). I(x) x1

Indifference Curves x2 x I(x) x1 SP(x), the set of bundles strictly preferred to x, does not include I(x). x I(x) x1

Indifference Curves Cannot Intersect

Slopes of Indifference Curves When more of a commodity is always preferred, the commodity is a good. If every commodity is a good then indifference curves are negatively sloped.

Slopes of Indifference Curves Good 2 Two goods a negatively sloped indifference curve. Better Worse Good 1

Slopes of Indifference Curves If less of a commodity is always preferred then the commodity is a bad.

Extreme Cases of Indifference Curves; Perfect Substitutes If a consumer always regards units of commodities 1 and 2 as equivalent, then the commodities are perfect substitutes and only the total amount of the two commodities in bundles determines their preference rank-order.

Extreme Cases of Indifference Curves; Perfect Substitutes Slopes are constant at - 1. 15 I2 Bundles in I2 all have a total of 15 units and are strictly preferred to all bundles in I1, which have a total of only 8 units in them. 8 I1 x1 8 15

Extreme Cases of Indifference Curves; Perfect Complements If a consumer always consumes commodities 1 and 2 in fixed proportion (e.g. one-to-one), then the commodities are perfect complements and only the number of pairs of units of the two commodities determines the preference rank-order of bundles.

Extreme Cases of Indifference Curves; Perfect Complements Each of (5,5), (5,9) and (9,5) contains 5 pairs so each is equally preferred. 9 5 I1 x1 5 9

Extreme Cases of Indifference Curves; Perfect Complements Since each of (5,5), (5,9) and (9,5) contains 5 pairs, each is less preferred than the bundle (9,9) which contains 9 pairs. 9 I2 5 I1 x1 5 9

Indifference Curves for Discrete Commodities A commodity is infinitely divisible if it can be acquired in any quantity; e.g. water or cheese. A commodity is discrete if it comes in unit lumps of 1, 2, 3, … and so on; e.g. aircraft, ships and refrigerators.

Indifference Curves for Discrete Commodities Suppose commodity 2 is an infinitely divisible good (gasoline) while commodity 1 is a discrete good (aircraft). What do indifference “curves” look like?

Indifference Curves With a Discrete Good Gas-oline Indifference “curves” are collections of discrete points. Aircraft 1 2 3 4

Well-Behaved Preferences A preference relation is “well-behaved” if it is monotonic and convex. Monotonicity: More of any commodity is always preferred.

Well-Behaved Preferences Convexity: Mixtures of bundles are (at least weakly) preferred to the bundles themselves. E.g., the 50-50 mixture of the bundles x and y is z = (0.5)x + (0.5)y. z is at least as preferred as x or y.

Well-Behaved Preferences -- Convexity. x+y is preferred to both x and y. x2+y2 z = 2 2 y y2 x1 x1+y1 y1 2

Well-Behaved Preferences -- Convexity. z =(tx1+(1-t)y1, tx2+(1-t)y2) is preferred to x and y for all 0 < t < 1. y y2 x1 y1

Non-Convex Preferences Better The mixture z is less preferred than x or y. z y2 x1 y1

More Non-Convex Preferences Better The mixture z is less preferred than x or y. z y2 x1 y1

Slopes of Indifference Curves The slope of an indifference curve is its marginal rate-of-substitution (MRS). How can a MRS be calculated?

Marginal Rate of Substitution x2 MRS at x’ is: - the slope of the indifference curve at x’ x’ x1

Marginal Rate of Substitution x2 MRS at x’ is - lim {Dx2/Dx1} Dx1 0 = - dx2/dx1 at x’ Dx2 x’ Dx1 x1

Marginal Rate of Substitution dx2 = -MRS ´ dx1 so, at x’, -MRS is the rate at which the consumer is only just willing to exchange commodity 2 for a small amount of commodity 1. x2 x’ dx2 dx1 x1

MRS & Ind. Curve Properties Good 2 Two goods a negatively sloped indifference curve Better MRS > 0. Worse Good 1