Can Markets Set Caps for Cap-and-trade Pollution Permits? Ted Bergstrom Economics Department University of California Santa Barbara.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
15 CHAPTER Externalities.
Advertisements

PART 10 Market Failures Markets may fail to generate efficient results due to Monopoly Externalities Public Goods Open Access Markets may also have informational.
Chapter 11 Environmental Regulation of the Energy Industry.
A P.O. Is a C.E. © 1998, 2007 by Peter Berck. What Is It Good? Sum of surplus and profits allows for policies that make income less evenly distributed.
1 Chapter 14 Practice Quiz Environmental Economics.
Equity, Efficiency and Need
Incentive-Based Strategies: Transferable Discharge Permits Chapter 13.
Trading and Efficiency © 1998, 2006 Peter Berck. Topics Marginal Cost of abatement and Bid for Permits Efficient Allocation of Emissions among firms Cap.
 Homework #1 Due Thursday  Group Quiz Next Thursday  Writing Assignment Due Oct. 27th.
10 Externalities.
1 Chapter 3 Externalities and Public Policy. 2 Externalities Externalities are costs or benefits of market transactions not reflected in prices. Negative.
Intermediate Microeconomic Theory
1 Topic 3.c: Transferable emission permits We will start analyzing the last policy we will look at for pollution control. –Tradable/transferable emission.
 Homework #1 Due Thursday  Group Quiz Next Thursday  Writing Assignment Due Oct. 28th.
 Homework #1 Due Thursday  Group Quiz Next Thursday  Writing Assignment Due Oct. 28th.
15 Externalities Notes and teaching tips: 4, 24, 28, and 40.
© 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Economics R. Glenn Hubbard, Anthony Patrick O’Brien, 2e. Fernando & Yvonn Quijano Prepared by: Chapter 5 Externalities,
Chapter 21 The Environment Copyright © 2010 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
Externalities © Allen C. Goodman 2009 Ideal Market Processes are desirable if … We accept the value judgment that “personal wants of individuals should.
“Supply, Demand, and Market Equilibrium”
Externalities and the Environment. What is an Externality? When a person/firm does something that affects the interests of another person or firm without.
Elasticity of Demand and Supply
Chapter 20 Externalities and Public Goods Copyright © 2014 McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. No reproduction or distribution without the prior.
Sample Questions ECON 2420 Exam 1.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2012 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Chapter 22 Natural Resources, the Environment, and Climate Change.
C. Bordoy UWC Maastricht Market Failure Evaluation of policies to correct externalities.
1 of 22 General Equilibrium and the Efficiency of Perfect Competition General Equilibrium Analysis Allocative Efficiency and Competitive Equilibrium The.
Lecture Notes: Econ 203 Introductory Microeconomics Lecture/Chapter 10: Externalities M. Cary Leahey Manhattan College Fall 2012.
Harcourt, Inc. items and derived items copyright © 2001 by Harcourt, Inc. Environmental Economics.
How can we limit climate change?
Econ 201 Chpt. 10 Coase Theorem: Establishing Property Rights & Tradable Permits.
Unit II: The Nature and Function of Product Markets
General Equilibrium and the Efficiency of Perfect Competition
Chapter 2 Externalities and the Environment McGraw-Hill/Irwin
Market Failure Solutions A review of various approaches to address imperfections of the free market system.
Permits and the U.S. Acid Rain Program (ARP). Acid Rain Caused primarily by SO2 and Nox, which is generated largely by coal fired plants Harmful to trees,
Review for Exam 1 Chapters 1 Through 5. Production Possibilities Frontiers and Opportunity Costs Learning Objective 2.1 Production possibilities frontier.
Public goods and externalities: two more “market failures” another market failure (discussed in the previous lecture) is due to “monopoly power” these.
Externalities.
Modeling Market Failure Chapter 3 © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western.
Research on ‘Emissions Trade’ By Sarah Jang Research on ‘Emissions Trade’ By Sarah Jang.
Dr. Laura Dawson Ullrich March 25, Q per year $ MB MD MPC MSC = MPC + MD Q1Q1 Q* Actual output Socially efficient output b a c.
Chapter 14 Economic Efficiency and the Competitive Ideal ECONOMICS: Principles and Applications, 4e HALL & LIEBERMAN, © 2008 Thomson South-Western.
Copyright © 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 17 The Economics of Environmental Protection.
PPT accompaniment for the Consortium's Supply, Demand, and Market Equilibrium.
Sometimes externality problems can’t be solved by private bargaining (transaction costs are too big). Public policy toward externalities. “Command-and-control”
CHAPTER 18 EXTENSIONS TO SUPPLY AND DEMAND By Lauren O’Brien, Peter Cervantes, Erik Borders.
MICROECONOMICS Chapter 5 Efficiency and Equity
Market Failure Chapter 14 Externalities. Economic Freedom Economic freedom refers to the degree to which private individuals are able to carry out voluntary.
Unit II: The Nature and Function of Product Markets.
A P.O. Is a C.E. © 1998 by Peter Berck. What Is It Good? §Sum of surplus and profits allows for policies that make income less evenly distributed. §A.
MICROECONOMICS: Theory & Applications By Edgar K. Browning & Mark A. Zupan John Wiley & Sons, Inc. 11 th Edition, Copyright 2012 PowerPoint prepared by.
Business in a Modern World Fabian Girod Business in a Modern World 1 Markets, Firms, and the Role of Governments Legal systems; externalities and public.
Externalities Mr. Barnett UHS AP Econ. © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except.
Macroeconomics ECON 2302 May 2009 Marilyn Spencer, Ph.D. Professor of Economics Chapter 5.
Other methods of government intervention. Tradable pollution permits  Tradable pollution permits are rights to sell and buy actual or potential pollution.
Econ 201 Chpt. 10 Coase Theorem: Establishing Property Rights & Tradable Permits.
Policy Tools: Correcting Market Failures. What are the most serious problems we face? Climate change Agricultural production Peak oil Water supply Biodiversity.
Chapter 3 – Market Failure
Efficiency and Equity in a Competitive Market
C h a p t e r 3 EXTERNALITIES AND GOVERNMENT POLICY
10 Externalities.
The Failure of Cap and Trade in GHG Emissions Controls
Main Topics for Free Responses Since 1995
10 Externalities.
10 Externalities.
Chapter 2 Externalities and the Environment McGraw-Hill/Irwin
10 Externalities.
Trading and Efficiency
Presentation transcript:

Can Markets Set Caps for Cap-and-trade Pollution Permits? Ted Bergstrom Economics Department University of California Santa Barbara

Alternate Title: Arrow, Coase, Missing Markets, and the Easter Bunny

Economists have lots of good ideas that politicians and public dont like as well as we do. Gasoline Tax Congestion Tolls Legalize and tax recreational drugs Legalize trade in body organs Subsidize surstrőmming?

Tradable pollution permits: an economists idea that got popular Endorsed by Clinton, Edwards, Obama, and McCain By major energy companies Some Environmental Groups – Environmental Defense Fund, Union of Concerned Scientists – But not Sierra Club

A Coasian Solution to Externalities? A fond hope of many economists is that externalities can be internalized by establishing property rights and market institutions. Achieved with a minimum of government regulation. Reduce politicians chances for corruption and bribery. Is this Easter Bunny economics?

What is cap-and-trade? Government requires a permit for every unit of pollution produced. Issues a fixed number of tradable permits. Permits typically issued to original polluters in proportion to historic pollution. – Wouldnt have to be this way. Could be auctioned. Number of permits decreases over time.

Los Angeles Air Quality Typical example: Southern Californias RECLAIM market started in – Tradeable permits for SOx and NOx issued to large polluters in L.A. in proportion to emissions they produce at full capacity. – Number of permits issued reduced by 8% per year Large brokerage firms handle trades – Coasian Transaction costs? Commissions: percent L.A. air quality has improved drastically.

Other Cap-and-trade markets Acid Rain SOx markets in Eastern US States Water pollution in Wisconsin and Colorado Fisheries in Australia and New Zealand Tradable permits to own cars in Singapore. – Number increases by 3% per year. – New permits auctioned in Walrasian auction

Alternatives to Cap-and-Trade Command and control measures Pigovian Pollution tax Why do energy companies like cap-and- trade? – Preferable to C and C or pollution tax if they get the permits. – Especially if abatement technologies are cheaper for them than for others.

Advantage of Cap-and-Trade Decentralizes firms decisions about whether to install abatement devices, change technologies, cut back output, move away. Marginal benefits from polluting are about the same* across all firms and equal to marginal costs of abatement. Conditional on aggregate level of pollution, if market is competitive, outcome is Pareto efficient.

Further advantage Endowing current polluters, reduces opposition, makes change nearly Pareto improving – Except for grouchy people at Sierra Club Even grouches may concede that they need to buy off polluters to get reform.

What is missing Cap-and-trade policies do a good job of allocating chosen level of cap, but cap is currently chosen by political bodies. Can the caps also be determined by markets?

Arrows suggestion Arrow (1969) stated: By a suitable and not unnatural reinterpretation of the commodity space, externalities can be regarded as ordinary commodities and all of the formal theory of competitive equilibrium is valid, including its optimality

Arrows formalism Treat pollution of each victim as a separate commodity. These are joint products of pollutant produced by a polluter. Competitive equilibrium would exist in this imaginary economy and would be the same as a Lindahl equilibrium, which would be Pareto optimal.

Does this mean that decentralized markets can optimize externalities ?

Not so fast, says Arrow The existence of Lindahl equilibrium prices for pollution does mean that they can be implemented in a working market. Two problems. – 1) Free-riders cannot be excluded from benefits of air quality purchased by others. – 2) Personalized markets are thin markets. Competitive outcome is unlikely.

Do Arrows 2 problems doom a full market solution for pollution control methods? Rays of hope from mechanism design. – Weakly dominant Groves Clarke Mechanism – Nash implementation Groves-Ledyard Mark Walker and others Not like markets, but maybe some kind of market will work.

Is there a way around these problems?

Multiple polluters, single victim Assume there are many firms, each produces a single pollutant as a bi-product and could reduce the ratio of pollutant to output at some cost. There is only one pollution victim. Government monitors pollution and requires a permit for each unit of pollutant emitted. Government issues enough permits for total pollution produced before permits required.

Permits given to Polluters Government issues permits to original polluters equal to their previous emissions. Pollution victim can buy permits and retire them. Outcome will be efficient and Pareto superior to status quo ante. Damage to victim of marginal unit of pollution equals marginal benefit of polluting and marginal cost of abatement for each polluter.

Permits given to victim We may think that the victim had a right to a clean environment and should not have to pay. Coasian argument : No worries. Just endow the victim with the permits. Outcome will be the same except for income distribution.

Not so fast, Mr. Rabbit Victim will now be a monopoly seller of permits. Marginal cost of selling a permit is victims disutility of pollution. Firms demand for permits will be downward sloping. Marginal revenue will exceed price. Victim will sell too few permits for efficiency. We could use a Pigovian tax, but how high should the tax be set?

Many Polluters, Many Victims Assume many polluters as before, but now let there be many pollution victims. Suppose that pollution permits are required and permits issued to current polluters allowing pre-permit pollution levels. This establishes property rights to air quality. Victims can buy and retire permits. Markets give us efficiency, right?

Not so fast, Mr. Rabbit Nash equilibrium in this market will be the voluntary provision of public goods outcome. The equilibrium price in this market will be equal to the marginal cost of pollution to any individual victim who buys tickets. Each retired premit reduces pollution for all victims, yet purchasers consider only their own gains. Efficiency requires price of permit equals sum of marginal costs to victims. Equilibrium has far lower price, equal to maximum of marginal costs to victims.

Endowing the victims Can we cure the problem by endowing the victims rather than the polluters? Suppose the total supply of permits was divided equally among victims. Market would be competitive now: many victims Victims would be willing to supply at their marginal damage. Equilibrium price would be marginal damage to a single person. Again far below efficient price. And total revenue received by victims far less than total damage caused by pollution.

Personalized permits Suppose that the government endows each pollution victim a number of pollution permits equal to the total amount of pollution produced before permits were introduced. For each unit of pollution that a firm produces, it must have one personalized permit from each victim.

Unanimous consent? What goes wrong when many victims are endowed with tradable permits? Each victim can sell permission to pollute not only himself but everyone in the community. Lets try market devices that require unanimous (or near unanimous consent) of victims. (Wicksell suggested that near unanimity might be required for tax-funded projects.)

Too many commodities? Think of a global market with a small number of nations acting on behalf of their citizens. Polluters need a permit from each country for each unit of pollution they produce.

Complementary monopoly problem Each victim is the monopoly supplier of his own permits. Permits are perfect complements. This is the complementary monopoly model of Cournot. Output is even smaller than with a single monopoly. – Total markup as percentage of sum of prices is N/|E|, where E is elasticity of demand and N the number of victims.

Fixing Arrows Problem 2 We could have personalized permits without monopoly by spreading initial endowments of each victims permits among many participants – either victims or polluting firms, depending on distributional goals. There would be many demanders for these permitsseveral firms and one victim.

Lindahl equilibrium Endowment of X personalized permits for each person is distributed. In equilibrium, each victim buys the same quantity Q of his own permits and firms buy a total of X-Q of each kind of permit. Each persons personalized price is his marginal rate of substitution between pollution and private goods. Cost to a firm of producing a unit of pollution is sum of prices of personalized permits.

Can we implement Lindahl with competitive permit market? The Lindahl equilibrium would be a competitive equilibrium if each victim experienced X-Qi units of pollution when he retires Qi permits. But in the actual market we have proposed, firms can only produce j X-max{Q j } units of pollution.

Lindahl equilibrium is not supported by a competitive equilibrium in pollution tickets

But is there some other kind of equilibrium and is it any good? What if we make the amount of pollution that a producer is allowed some c.e.s function of the numbers of each type of ticket that he holds?

Hope springs eternal

Had enough?