What I want you to learn:

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
The Solow Growth Model (Part One)
Advertisements

The Solow Growth Model (Part Three)
Review of Exam 1.
mankiw's macroeconomics modules
The Solow Model and Beyond
1 Economic Growth Professor Chris Adam Australian Graduate School of Management University of Sydney and University of New South Wales.
The Solow Model When 1st introduced, it was treated as more than a good attempt to have a model that allowed the K/Y=θ to vary as thus avoid the linear.
ECO 402 Fall 2013 Prof. Erdinç Economic Growth The Solow Model.
Chapter 7 learning objectives
Macroeconomics fifth edition N. Gregory Mankiw PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich CHAPTER SEVEN Economic Growth I macro © 2002 Worth Publishers, all.
Review of the previous lecture The real interest rate adjusts to equate the demand for and supply of goods and services loanable funds A decrease in national.
Neoclassical Growth Theory
In this chapter, you will learn:
Chapter 8 Learning objectives
M ACROECONOMICS C H A P T E R © 2008 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved SIXTH EDITION PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich N. G REGORY M ANKIW Economic.
Economic models …are simplied versions of a more complex reality irrelevant details are stripped away Used to show the relationships between economic variables.
Economic Growth: The Solow Model
The importance of economic growth
M ACROECONOMICS C H A P T E R Unemployment 6. slide 1 CHAPTER 6 Unemployment In this chapter, you will learn… …about the natural rate of unemployment:
Chapter 6: Economic Growth Estimate economic growth and implications of sustained growth for standard of living. Trends in economic growth in U.S. and.
1 Economic Growth and Rising Living Standards. Real GDP per Person, (in 2000 US $) 2.
In this chapter, you will learn…
M ACROECONOMICS C H A P T E R © 2007 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved SIXTH EDITION PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich N. G REGORY M ANKIW Economic.
Macroeconomics fifth edition N. Gregory Mankiw PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich macro © 2002 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved Topic 5: Economic.
In this chapter, you will learn…
MANKIW'S MACROECONOMICS MODULES
Economic Growth: Malthus and Solow
Macroeconomics fifth edition N. Gregory Mankiw PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich macro © 2002 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved Topic 5: Economic.
MACROECONOMICS © 2010 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved S E V E N T H E D I T I O N PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich N. Gregory Mankiw C H A P.
Macroeconomics fifth edition N. Gregory Mankiw PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich macro © 2002 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved CHAPTER EIGHT Economic.
Macroeconomics & The Global Economy Ace Institute of Management Chapter 7 and 8: Economic Growth I Instructor Sandeep Basnyat
Chapter 7 learning objectives
MACROECONOMICS © 2013 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich N. Gregory Mankiw Economic Growth II: Technology, Empirics,
IN THIS CHAPTER, YOU WILL LEARN:
Economic Growth I Economics 331 J. F. O’Connor. "A world where some live in comfort and plenty, while half of the human race lives on less than $2 a day,
Copyright © 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 6 Economic Growth: Malthus and Solow.
IN THIS CHAPTER, YOU WILL LEARN:
Copyright © 2006 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. 4-1 The Theory of Economic Growth: The Solow Growth Model Reading: DeLong/Olney:
Economic Growth II: Technology, Empirics, and Policy.
M ACROECONOMICS C H A P T E R © 2007 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved SIXTH EDITION PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich N. G REGORY M ANKIW Economic.
Economic Growth I CHAPTER 7.
In this section, you will learn…
Economic Growth I Chapter Seven.
Growth Facts Solow Growth Model Optimal Growth Endogenous Growth
M ACROECONOMICS C H A P T E R © 2007 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved SIXTH EDITION PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich N. G REGORY M ANKIW Economic.
MACROECONOMICS © 2014 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved N. Gregory Mankiw PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich Fall 2013 update Economic Growth I:
Ch7: Economic Growth I: Capital Accumulation and Population Growth
Of 261 Chapter 26 Long-Run Economic Growth. of 262 Copyright © 2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc. Learning Objectives 3. List the main elements of Neoclassical.
1 Long-Run Economic Growth and Rising Living Standards Economic Growth.
Chapter 4 Growth and Policy Item Etc. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Macroeconomics, 10e © 2008 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., All Rights Reserved.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western. In this section, look for the answers to these questions: Why does productivity matter for living standards? What determines.
Copyright © 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 6 Economic Growth: Solow Model.
CHAPTER 7 Economic Growth I slide 0 Econ 101: Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory Larry Hu Lecture 7: Introduction to Economic Growth.
Chapter 3 Growth and Accumulation Item Etc. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Macroeconomics, 10e © 2008 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., All Rights Reserved.
Slide 0 CHAPTER 7 Economic Growth I Macroeconomics Sixth Edition Chapter 7: Economic Growth I: Capital Accumulation and Population Growth Econ 4020/Chatterjee.
Macroeconomics fifth edition N. Gregory Mankiw PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich macro © 2002 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved CHAPTER EIGHT Economic.
Review of the previous lecture 1.The Solow growth model shows that, in the long run, a country’s standard of living depends positively on its saving rate.
IN THIS CHAPTER, YOU WILL LEARN:
National Income & Business Cycles 0 Ohio Wesleyan University Goran Skosples 7. Long-Run Growth.
Macroeconomics fifth edition N. Gregory Mankiw PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich CHAPTER SEVEN Economic Growth I macro © 2002 Worth Publishers, all.
Growth and Policy Chapter #4. Introduction Chapter 3 explained how GDP and GDP growth are determined by the savings rate, rate of population growth, and.
MACROECONOMICS © 2011 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved S E V E N T H E D I T I O N PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich N. Gregory Mankiw C H A P.
Copyright © 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 6 Economic Growth: Solow Model.
MACROECONOMICS © 2013 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich N. Gregory Mankiw Economic Growth I: Capital Accumulation.
IN THIS CHAPTER, YOU WILL LEARN:
Economic Growth II Topic 5: (Chapter 8)
Ohio Wesleyan University Goran Skosples 7. Long-Run Growth
Economic Growth I.
Saving, Capital Accumulation, and Output
Econ 101: Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory Larry Hu
Presentation transcript:

Economic Growth I: Capital Accumulation and Population Growth

What I want you to learn: the closed economy Solow model how a country’s standard of living depends on its saving and population growth rates how to use the “Golden Rule” to find the optimal saving rate and capital stock 1

Why growth matters Data on infant mortality rates: 20% in the poorest 1/5 of all countries 0.4% in the richest 1/5 In Pakistan, 85% of people live on less than $2/day. One-fourth of the poorest countries have had famines during the past 3 decades. Poverty is associated with oppression of women and minorities. Economic growth raises living standards and reduces poverty….

Income and poverty in the world selected countries, 2000

links to prepared graphs @ Gapminder.org notes: circle size is proportional to population size, color of circle indicates continent Income per capita and Life expectancy Infant mortality Malaria deaths per 100,000 Adult literacy Cell phone users per 100,000

Why growth matters Anything that effects the long-run rate of economic growth – even by a tiny amount – will have huge effects on living standards in the long run. percentage increase in standard of living after… annual growth rate of income per capita …25 years …50 years …100 years 2.0% 64.0% 169.2% 624.5% 2.5% 85.4% 243.7% 1,081.4%

Why growth matters If the annual growth rate of U.S. real GDP per capita had been just one-tenth of one percent higher during the 1990s, the U.S. would have generated an additional $496 billion of income during that decade.

The lessons of growth theory …can make a positive difference in the lives of hundreds of millions of people. These lessons help us understand why poor countries are poor design policies that can help them grow learn how our own growth rate is affected by shocks and our government’s policies

The Solow model due to Robert Solow, won Nobel Prize for contributions to the study of economic growth a major paradigm: widely used in policy making benchmark against which most recent growth theories are compared looks at the determinants of economic growth and the standard of living in the long run

How Solow model is different from Chapter 3’s model K is no longer fixed: investment causes it to grow, depreciation causes it to shrink L is no longer fixed: population growth causes it to grow the consumption function is simpler no G or T (only to simplify presentation; we can still do fiscal policy experiments) cosmetic differences

The production function In aggregate terms: Y = F (K, L) Define: y = Y/L = output per worker k = K/L = capital per worker Assume constant returns to scale: zY = F (zK, zL ) for any z > 0 Pick z = 1/L. Then Y/L = F (K/L, 1) y = F (k, 1) y = f(k) where f(k) = F(k, 1)

The production function Output per worker, y Capital per worker, k f(k) 1 MPK = f(k +1) – f(k) Note: this production function exhibits diminishing MPK.

The national income identity Y = C + I (remember, no G ) In “per worker” terms: y = c + i where c = C/L and i = I /L

The consumption function s = the saving rate, the fraction of income that is saved (s is an exogenous parameter) Note: s is the only lowercase variable that is not equal to its uppercase version divided by L Consumption function: c = (1–s)y (per worker)

Saving and investment saving (per worker) = y – c = y – (1–s)y = sy National income identity is y = c + i Rearrange to get: i = y – c = sy (investment = saving, like in chap. 3!) Using the results above, i = sy = sf(k)

Output, consumption, and investment Output per worker, y Capital per worker, k f(k) y1 k1 c1 sf(k) i1

Depreciation  = the rate of depreciation = the fraction of the capital stock that wears out each period Depreciation per worker, k Capital per worker, k k  1

k = s f(k) – k Capital accumulation The basic idea: Investment increases the capital stock, depreciation reduces it. Change in capital stock = investment – depreciation k = i – k Since i = sf(k) , this becomes: k = s f(k) – k

The equation of motion for k k = s f(k) – k The Solow model’s central equation Determines behavior of capital over time… …which, in turn, determines behavior of all of the other endogenous variables because they all depend on k. E.g., income per person: y = f(k) consumption per person: c = (1–s) f(k)

k = s f(k) – k The steady state If investment is just enough to cover depreciation [sf(k) = k ], then capital per worker will remain constant: k = 0. This occurs at one value of k, denoted k*, called the steady state capital stock.

Investment and depreciation The steady state Investment and depreciation Capital per worker, k k sf(k) k*

Moving toward the steady state k = sf(k)  k Investment and depreciation Capital per worker, k k sf(k) k* investment k1 k depreciation

Moving toward the steady state k = sf(k)  k Investment and depreciation Capital per worker, k k sf(k) k* k1 k k2

Moving toward the steady state k = sf(k)  k Investment and depreciation Capital per worker, k k sf(k) k* investment k depreciation k2

Moving toward the steady state k = sf(k)  k Investment and depreciation Capital per worker, k k sf(k) k* k2 k

Moving toward the steady state k = sf(k)  k Investment and depreciation Capital per worker, k k sf(k) k* k k2 k3

Moving toward the steady state k = sf(k)  k Investment and depreciation Capital per worker, k k Summary: As long as k < k*, investment will exceed depreciation, and k will continue to grow toward k*. sf(k) k* k3

A numerical example Production function (aggregate): To derive the per-worker production function, divide through by L: Then substitute y = Y/L and k = K/L to get

A numerical example, cont. Assume: s = 0.3  = 0.1 initial value of k = 4.0 As each assumption appears on the screen, explain it’s interpretation. I.e., “The economy saves three-tenths of income,” “every year, 10% of the capital stock wears out,” and “suppose the economy starts out with four units of capital for every worker.”

Approaching the steady state: A numerical example Year k y c i δk Δk 1 4.000 2.000 1.400 0.600 0.400 0.200 2 4.200 2.049 1.435 0.615 0.420 0.195 3 4.395 2.096 1.467 0.629 0.440 0.189 4 4.584 2.141 1.499 0.642 0.458 0.184 … 10 5.602 2.367 1.657 0.710 0.560 0.150 25 7.351 2.706 1.894 0.812 0.732 0.080 100 8.962 2.994 2.096 0.898 0.896 0.002 ∞ 9.000 3.000 2.100 0.900 0.900 0.000 Before revealing the numbers in the first row, ask your students to determine them and write them in their notes. Give them a moment, then reveal the first row and make sure everyone understands where each number comes from. Then, ask them to determine the numbers for the second row and write them in their notes. After the second round of this, it’s probably fine to just show them the rest of the table.

NOW YOU TRY: Solve for the Steady State Continue to assume s = 0.3,  = 0.1, and y = k 1/2 Use the equation of motion k = s f(k)  k to solve for the steady-state values of k, y, and c.

ANSWERS: Solve for the Steady State

An increase in the saving rate An increase in the saving rate raises investment… …causing k to grow toward a new steady state: Investment and depreciation k δk s2 f(k) s1 f(k)

Prediction: Higher s  higher k*. And since y = f(k) , higher k*  higher y* . Thus, the Solow model predicts that countries with higher rates of saving and investment will have higher levels of capital and income per worker in the long run.

International evidence on investment rates and income per person Income per person in 2003 (log scale) Investment as percentage of output (average 1960-2003)

The Golden Rule: Introduction Different values of s lead to different steady states. How do we know which is the “best” steady state? The “best” steady state has the highest possible consumption per person: c* = (1–s) f(k*). An increase in s leads to higher k* and y*, which raises c* reduces consumption’s share of income (1–s), which lowers c*. So, how do we find the s and k* that maximize c*?

The Golden Rule capital stock the Golden Rule level of capital, the steady state value of k that maximizes consumption. To find it, first express c* in terms of k*: c* = y*  i* = f (k*)  i* = f (k*)  k* In the steady state: i* = k* because k = 0.

The Golden Rule capital stock steady state output and depreciation steady-state capital per worker, k*  k* Then, graph f(k*) and k*, look for the point where the gap between them is biggest. f(k*)

The Golden Rule capital stock c* = f(k*)  k* is biggest where the slope of the production function equals the slope of the depreciation line:  k* f(k*) MPK =  steady-state capital per worker, k*

The transition to the Golden Rule steady state The economy does NOT have a tendency to move toward the Golden Rule steady state. Achieving the Golden Rule requires that policymakers adjust s. This adjustment leads to a new steady state with higher consumption. But what happens to consumption during the transition to the Golden Rule? Remember: policymakers can affect the national saving rate: - changing G or T affects national saving - holding T constant overall, but changing the structure of the tax system to provide more incentives for private saving (e.g., a revenue-neutral shift from the income tax to a consumption tax)

Starting with too much capital then increasing c* requires a fall in s. In the transition to the Golden Rule, consumption is higher at all points in time. time y c i t0 is the time period in which the saving rate is reduced. It would be helpful if you explained the behavior of each variable before t0, at t0 , and in the transition period (after t0 ). Before t0: in a steady state, where k, y, c, and i are all constant. At t0: The change in the saving rate doesn’t immediately change k, so y doesn’t change immediately. But the fall in s causes a fall in investment [because saving equals investment] and a rise in consumption [because c = (1-s)y, s has fallen but y has not yet changed.]. Note that c = -i, because y = c + i and y has not changed. After t0: In the previous steady state, saving and investment were just enough to cover depreciation. Then saving and investment were reduced, so depreciation is greater than investment, which causes k to fall toward a new, lower steady state value. As k falls and settles on its new, lower steady state value, so will y, c, and i (because each of them is a function of k). Even though c is falling, it doesn’t fall all the way back to its initial value. Policymakers would be happy to make this change, as it produces higher consumption at all points in time (relative to what consumption would have been if the saving rate had not been reduced. t0

Starting with too little capital then increasing c* requires an increase in s. Future generations enjoy higher consumption, but the current one experiences an initial drop in consumption. y c Before t0: in a steady state, where k, y, c, and i are all constant. At t0: The increase in s doesn’t immediately change k, so y doesn’t change immediately. But the increase in s causes investment to rise [because higher saving means higher investment] and consumption to fall [because we are saving more of our income, and consuming less of it]. After t0: Now, saving and investment exceed depreciation, so k starts rising toward a new, higher steady state value. The behavior of k causes the same behavior in y, c, and i (qualitatively the same, that is). Ultimately, consumption ends up at a higher steady state level. But initially consumption falls. Therefore, if policymakers value the current generation’s well-being more than that of future generations, they might be reluctant to adjust the saving rate to achieve the Golden Rule. Notice, though, that if they did increase s, an infinite number of future generations would benefit, which makes the sacrifice of the current generation seem more acceptable. i t0 time

Population growth Assume the population and labor force grow at rate n (exogenous): EX: Suppose L = 1,000 in year 1 and the population is growing at 2% per year (n = 0.02). Then L = n L = 0.02  1,000 = 20, so L = 1,020 in year 2.

Break-even investment ( + n)k = break-even investment, the amount of investment necessary to keep k constant. Break-even investment includes:  k to replace capital as it wears out n k to equip new workers with capital (Otherwise, k would fall as the existing capital stock is spread more thinly over a larger population of workers.)

The equation of motion for k With population growth, the equation of motion for k is: k = s f(k)  ( + n) k actual investment break-even investment

The Solow model diagram k = s f(k)  ( +n)k Investment, break-even investment Capital per worker, k ( + n ) k sf(k) k*

The impact of population growth Investment, break-even investment ( +n2) k ( +n1) k An increase in n causes an increase in break-even investment, sf(k) k2* leading to a lower steady-state level of k. k1* Capital per worker, k

Prediction: Higher n  lower k*. And since y = f(k) , lower k*  lower y*. Thus, the Solow model predicts that countries with higher population growth rates will have lower levels of capital and income per worker in the long run.

International evidence on population growth and income per person Income per person in 2003 (log scale) Population growth (percent per year, average 1960-2003)

The Golden Rule with population growth To find the Golden Rule capital stock, express c* in terms of k*: c* = y*  i* = f (k* )  ( + n) k* c* is maximized when MPK =  + n or equivalently, MPK   = n In the Golden Rule steady state, the marginal product of capital net of depreciation equals the population growth rate.

Alternative perspectives on population growth The Malthusian Model (1798) Predicts population growth will outstrip the Earth’s ability to produce food, leading to the impoverishment of humanity. Since Malthus, world population has increased sixfold, yet living standards are higher than ever. Malthus neglected the effects of technological progress. Thomas Malthus

Alternative perspectives on population growth The Kremerian Model (1993) Posits that population growth contributes to economic growth. More people = more geniuses, scientists & engineers, so faster technological progress. Evidence, from very long historical periods: As world pop. growth rate increased, so did rate of growth in living standards Historically, regions with larger populations have enjoyed faster growth. Michael Kremer Michael Kremer, “Population Growth and Technological Change: One Million B.C. to 1990,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 108 (August 1993): 681-716.

Summary positively on its saving rate 1. The Solow growth model shows that, in the long run, a country’s standard of living depends: positively on its saving rate negatively on its population growth rate 2. An increase in the saving rate leads to: higher output in the long run faster growth temporarily but not faster steady state growth 53

Summary 3. If the economy has more capital than the Golden Rule level, then reducing saving will increase consumption at all points in time, making all generations better off. If the economy has less capital than the Golden Rule level, then increasing saving will increase consumption for future generations, but reduce consumption for the present generation. 54

Technological progress in the Solow model In the simple Solow model, the production technology is held constant. income per capita is constant in the steady state. Neither point is true in the real world: 1908-2008: U.S. real GDP per person grew by a factor of 7.8, or 2.05% per year. examples of technological progress abound 55

Examples of technological progress From 1950 to 2000, U.S. farm sector productivity nearly tripled. The real price of computer power has fallen an average of 30% per year over the past three decades. Percentage of U.S. households with ≥ 1 computers: 8% in 1984, 62% in 2003 1981: 213 computers connected to the Internet 2000: 60 million computers connected to the Internet 2001: iPod capacity = 5gb, 1000 songs. Not capable of playing episodes of True Blood. 2009: iPod capacity = 120gb, 30,000 songs. Can play episodes of True Blood. 56

Technological progress in the Solow model A new variable: E = labor efficiency Assume: Technological progress is labor-augmenting: it increases labor efficiency at the exogenous rate g: 57

Technological progress in the Solow model We now write the production function as: where L  E = the number of effective workers. Increases in labor efficiency have the same effect on output as increases in the labor force. 58

Technological progress in the Solow model Notation: y = Y/LE = output per effective worker k = K/LE = capital per effective worker Production function per effective worker: y = f(k) Saving and investment per effective worker: s y = s f(k) 59

Technological progress in the Solow model ( + n + g)k = break-even investment: the amount of investment necessary to keep k constant. Consists of:  k to replace depreciating capital n k to provide capital for new workers g k to provide capital for the new “effective” workers created by technological progress The only thing that’s new here, compared to Chapter 7, is that gk is part of break-even investment. Remember: k = K/LE, capital per effective worker. Tech progress increases the number of effective workers at rate g, which would cause capital per effective worker to fall at rate g (other things equal). Investment equal to gk would prevent this. 60

Technological progress in the Solow model k = s f(k)  ( +n +g)k Investment, break-even investment Capital per worker, k ( +n +g ) k sf(k) k* The equation that appears above the graph is the equation of motion modified to allow for technological progress. There are minor differences between this and the Solow model graph from Chapter 7: Here, k and y are in “per effective worker” units rather than “per worker” units. The break-even investment line is a little bit steeper: at any given value of k, more investment is needed to keep k from falling - in particular, gk is needed. Otherwise, technological progress will cause k = K/LE to fall at rate g (because E in the denominator is growing at rate g). With this graph, we can do the same policy experiments as in Chapter 7. We can examine the effects of a change in the savings or population growth rates, and the analysis would be much the same. The main difference is that in the steady state, income per worker/capita is growing at rate g instead of being constant. 61

Steady-state growth rates in the Solow model with tech. progress Symbol Variable Capital per effective worker k = K/(LE ) Output per effective worker y = Y/(LE ) Output per worker Table 8-1, p.225. Explanations: k is constant (has zero growth rate) by definition of the steady state y is constant because y = f(k) and k is constant To see why Y/L grows at rate g, note that the definition of y implies (Y/L) = yE. The growth rate of (Y/L) equals the growth rate of y plus that of E. In the steady state, y is constant while E grows at rate g. Y grows at rate g + n. To see this, note that Y = yEL = (yE)L. The growth rate of Y equals the growth rate of (yE) plus that of L. We just saw that, in the steady state, the growth rate of (yE) equals g. And we assume that L grows at rate n. (Y/ L) = yE g Total output Y = yEL n + g 62

The Golden Rule with technological progress To find the Golden Rule capital stock, express c* in terms of k*: c* = y*  i* = f (k* )  ( + n + g) k* c* is maximized when MPK =  + n + g or equivalently, MPK   = n + g In the Golden Rule steady state, the marginal product of capital net of depreciation equals the pop. growth rate plus the rate of tech progress. Remember: investment in the steady state, i*, equals break-even investment. 63

Growth empirics: Balanced growth Solow model’s steady state exhibits balanced growth - many variables grow at the same rate. Solow model predicts Y/L and K/L grow at the same rate (g), so K/Y should be constant. This is true in the real world. Solow model predicts real wage grows at same rate as Y/L, while real rental price is constant. Also true in the real world. 64

Growth empirics: Convergence Solow model predicts that, other things equal, “poor” countries (with lower Y/L and K/L) should grow faster than “rich” ones. If true, then the income gap between rich & poor countries would shrink over time, causing living standards to “converge.” In real world, many poor countries do NOT grow faster than rich ones. Does this mean the Solow model fails? 65

Growth empirics: Convergence Solow model predicts that, other things equal, “poor” countries (with lower Y/L and K/L) should grow faster than “rich” ones. No, because “other things” aren’t equal. In samples of countries with similar savings & pop. growth rates, income gaps shrink about 2% per year. In larger samples, after controlling for differences in saving, pop. growth, and human capital, incomes converge by about 2% per year. 66

Growth empirics: Convergence What the Solow model really predicts is conditional convergence - countries converge to their own steady states, which are determined by saving, population growth, and education. This prediction comes true in the real world. 67

Growth empirics: Factor accumulation vs. production efficiency Differences in income per capita among countries can be due to differences in: 1. capital – physical or human – per worker 2. the efficiency of production (the height of the production function) Studies: Both factors are important. The two factors are correlated: countries with higher physical or human capital per worker also tend to have higher production efficiency. 68

Growth empirics: Factor accumulation vs. production efficiency Possible explanations for the correlation between capital per worker and production efficiency: Production efficiency encourages capital accumulation. Capital accumulation has externalities that raise efficiency. A third, unknown variable causes capital accumulation and efficiency to be higher in some countries than others. 69

Growth empirics: Production efficiency and free trade Since Adam Smith, economists have argued that free trade can increase production efficiency and living standards. Research by Sachs & Warner: Average annual growth rates, 1970-89 closed open Interpreting the numbers in this table: Sachs and Warner classify countries as either “open” or “closed.” Among the developed nations classified as “open,” the average annual growth rate was 2.3%. Among developed nations classified as “closed,” the growth rate was only 0.7% per year. The average growth rate for “open” developing nations was 4.5%. The average growth rate for “closed” developing countries was only 0.7%. See note 4 on p.229 for references. 0.7% 2.3% developed nations 0.7% 4.5% developing nations 70

Growth empirics: Production efficiency and free trade To determine causation, Frankel and Romer exploit geographic differences among countries: Some nations trade less because they are farther from other nations, or landlocked. Such geographical differences are correlated with trade but not with other determinants of income. Hence, they can be used to isolate the impact of trade on income. Findings: increasing trade/GDP by 2% causes GDP per capita to rise 1%, other things equal. See note 4 on p.229 for references. 71

Policy issues Are we saving enough? Too much? What policies might change the saving rate? How should we allocate our investment between privately owned physical capital, public infrastructure, and “human capital”? How do a country’s institutions affect production efficiency and capital accumulation? What policies might encourage faster technological progress? 72

Policy issues: Evaluating the rate of saving Use the Golden Rule to determine whether the U.S. saving rate and capital stock are too high, too low, or about right. If (MPK   ) > (n + g ), U.S. is below the Golden Rule steady state and should increase s. If (MPK   ) < (n + g ), U.S. economy is above the Golden Rule steady state and should reduce s. This section (this and the next couple of slides) presents a very clever and fairly simple analysis of the U.S. economy. When asked, students often have reasonable ideas of how to estimate MPK (e.g., look at stock market returns), n and g, but very few offer suggestions on how to estimate the depreciation rate: there are lots of different kinds of capital out there. Here, Mankiw presents a simple and elegant way to estimate the aggregate depreciation rate (which appears a couple of slides below). First, though, you should make sure your students know why the inequalities in the last two lines tell us whether our current steady-state is above or below the Golden Rule steady state. To see this, remember that the steady-state value of capital is inversely related to the steady state value of MPK. If we’re above the Golden Rule capital stock, then we have “too much” capital, so MPK will be smaller than in the Golden Rule steady state. If we’re below the GR capital stock, then MPK is higher than in the Golden Rule. 73

Policy issues: Evaluating the rate of saving To estimate (MPK   ), use three facts about the U.S. economy: 1. k = 2.5 y The capital stock is about 2.5 times one year’s GDP. 2.  k = 0.1 y About 10% of GDP is used to replace depreciating capital. 3. MPK  k = 0.3 y Capital income is about 30% of GDP. 74

Policy issues: Evaluating the rate of saving 1. k = 2.5 y 2.  k = 0.1 y 3. MPK  k = 0.3 y To determine  , divide 2 by 1: The actual U.S. economy has tens of thousands of different types of capital goods, all with different depreciation rates. Estimating the aggregate depreciation rate therefore might seem impossible. But on this slide, we see Mankiw’s simple, clever, and elegant method of estimating the aggregate depreciation rate. Pretty neat! 75

Policy issues: Evaluating the rate of saving 1. k = 2.5 y 2.  k = 0.1 y 3. MPK  k = 0.3 y To determine MPK, divide 3 by 1: Similarly, the method of estimating the aggregate MPK shown on this slide is far simpler and more elegant than somehow measuring and aggregating the returns on all different kinds of capital. Hence, MPK   = 0.12  0.04 = 0.08 76

Policy issues: Evaluating the rate of saving From the last slide: MPK   = 0.08 U.S. real GDP grows an average of 3% per year, so n + g = 0.03 Thus, MPK   = 0.08 > 0.03 = n + g Conclusion: When the second bullet point displays on the screen, it might be helpful to remind students that, in the Solow model’s steady state, total output grows at rate n + g. Thus, we can estimate n + g for the U.S. simply by using the long-run average growth rate of real GDP. The U.S. is below the Golden Rule steady state: Increasing the U.S. saving rate would increase consumption per capita in the long run. 77

Policy issues: How to increase the saving rate Reduce the government budget deficit (or increase the budget surplus). Increase incentives for private saving: reduce capital gains tax, corporate income tax, estate tax as they discourage saving. replace federal income tax with a consumption tax. expand tax incentives for IRAs (individual retirement accounts) and other retirement savings accounts. 78

Policy issues: Allocating the economy’s investment In the Solow model, there’s one type of capital. In the real world, there are many types, which we can divide into three categories: private capital stock public infrastructure human capital: the knowledge and skills that workers acquire through education How should we allocate investment among these types? 79

Policy issues: Allocating the economy’s investment Two viewpoints: 1. Equalize tax treatment of all types of capital in all industries, then let the market allocate investment to the type with the highest marginal product. 2. Industrial policy: Govt should actively encourage investment in capital of certain types or in certain industries, because they may have positive externalities that private investors don’t consider. 80

Possible problems with industrial policy The govt may not have the ability to “pick winners” (choose industries with the highest return to capital or biggest externalities). Politics (e.g., campaign contributions) rather than economics may influence which industries get preferential treatment. 81

Policy issues: Establishing the right institutions Creating the right institutions is important for ensuring that resources are allocated to their best use. Examples: Legal institutions, to protect property rights. Capital markets, to help financial capital flow to the best investment projects. A corruption-free government, to promote competition, enforce contracts, etc. 82

Policy issues: Encouraging tech. progress Patent laws: encourage innovation by granting temporary monopolies to inventors of new products. Tax incentives for R&D Grants to fund basic research at universities Industrial policy: encourages specific industries that are key for rapid tech. progress (subject to the preceding concerns). 83

CASE STUDY: The productivity slowdown U.S. U.K. Japan Italy Germany France Canada Growth in output per person (percent per year) 1948-72 1972-95 2.2 2.4 8.2 4.9 5.7 4.3 2.9 1.5 1.8 2.6 2.3 2.0 1.6 84

Possible explanations for the productivity slowdown Measurement problems: Productivity increases not fully measured. But: Why would measurement problems be worse after 1972 than before? Oil prices: Oil shocks occurred about when productivity slowdown began. But: Then why didn’t productivity speed up when oil prices fell in the mid-1980s? 85

Possible explanations for the productivity slowdown Worker quality: 1970s - large influx of new entrants into labor force (baby boomers, women). New workers tend to be less productive than experienced workers. The depletion of ideas: Perhaps the slow growth of 1972-1995 is normal, and the rapid growth during 1948-1972 is the anomaly. 86

Which of these suspects is the culprit? All of them are plausible, but it’s difficult to prove that any one of them is guilty. 87

CASE STUDY: I.T. and the “New Economy” U.S. U.K. Japan Italy Germany France Canada Growth in output per person (percent per year) 1948-72 1972-95 1995-2007 2.2 2.4 8.2 4.9 5.7 4.3 2.9 1.5 1.8 2.6 2.3 2.0 1.6 2.0 2.6 1.2 1.5 1.7 2.2 88

CASE STUDY: I.T. and the “New Economy” Apparently, the computer revolution did not affect aggregate productivity until the mid-1990s. Two reasons: 1. Computer industry’s share of GDP much bigger in late 1990s than earlier. 2. Takes time for firms to determine how to utilize new technology most effectively. The big, open question: How long will I.T. remain an engine of growth? 89

Endogenous growth theory Solow model: sustained growth in living standards is due to tech progress. the rate of tech progress is exogenous. Endogenous growth theory: a set of models in which the growth rate of productivity and living standards is endogenous. In the Solow model, the long-run economic growth rate equals the rate of technological progress, which is exogenous in the model. Hence, the Solow model is basically saying “all I can tell you is that growth in living standards depends on technological progress. I have no idea what drives technological progress.” Endogenous growth theory tries to explain the behavior of the rates of technological progress and/or productivity growth, rather than merely taking these rates as given. 90

A basic model Production function: Y = A K where A is the amount of output for each unit of capital (A is exogenous & constant) Key difference between this model & Solow: MPK is constant here, diminishes in Solow Investment: s Y Depreciation:  K Equation of motion for total capital: K = s Y   K 91

A basic model K = s Y   K Divide through by K and use Y = A K to get: If s A > , then income will grow forever, and investment is the “engine of growth.” Here, the permanent growth rate depends on s. In Solow model, it does not. Y and K grow at the same rate because A is constant. Discussion: The return to capital is the incentive to invest. If capital exhibits diminishing returns, then the incentive to invest decreases as the economy grows. Hence, investment cannot be a source of sustained growth. However, in this model, MPK does not fall as K rises, so the incentive to invest never declines, people will always find it worthwhile to save and invest over and above depreciation, so investment becomes an engine of growth. The $64,000 question: Does capital exhibit diminishing or constant marginal returns? The answer is critical, for it determines whether investment explains sustained (i.e. steady-state) growth in productivity and living standards. See the next slide for discussion. 92

Does capital have diminishing returns or not? Depends on definition of “capital.” If “capital” is narrowly defined (only plant & equipment), then yes. Advocates of endogenous growth theory argue that knowledge is a type of capital. If so, then constant returns to capital is more plausible, and this model may be a good description of economic growth. 93

A two-sector model Two sectors: manufacturing firms produce goods. research universities produce knowledge that increases labor efficiency in manufacturing. u = fraction of labor in research (u is exogenous) Mfg prod func: Y = F [K, (1-u )E L] Res prod func: E = g (u )E Cap accumulation: K = s Y   K 94

A two-sector model In the steady state, mfg output per worker and the standard of living grow at rate E/E = g (u ). Key variables: s: affects the level of income, but not its growth rate (same as in Solow model) u: affects level and growth rate of income In this model, the steady state growth rate of the standard of living equals the growth rate of labor efficiency, just like in the Solow model with tech progress, covered at the beginning of this chapter. The difference here is that the rate of tech progress, g, is not exogenous: it depends on how much labor the economy has allocated to research. 95

Facts about R&D Patents create a stream of monopoly profits. 1. Much research is done by firms seeking profits. 2. Firms profit from research: Patents create a stream of monopoly profits. Extra profit from being first on the market with a new product. 3. Innovation produces externalities that reduce the cost of subsequent innovation. Much of the new endogenous growth theory attempts to incorporate these facts into models to better understand technological progress. 96

Is the private sector doing enough R&D? The existence of positive externalities in the creation of knowledge suggests that the private sector is not doing enough R&D. But, there is much duplication of R&D effort among competing firms. Estimates: Social return to R&D ≥ 40% per year. Thus, many believe govt should encourage R&D. 97

Economic growth as “creative destruction” Schumpeter (1942) coined term “creative destruction” to describe displacements resulting from technological progress: the introduction of a new product is good for consumers, but often bad for incumbent producers, who may be forced out of the market. Examples: Luddites (1811-12) destroyed machines that displaced skilled knitting workers in England. Walmart displaces many “mom and pop” stores. 98

Chapter Summary 1. Key results from Solow model with tech progress steady state growth rate of income per person depends solely on the exogenous rate of tech progress the U.S. has much less capital than the Golden Rule steady state 2. Ways to increase the saving rate increase public saving (reduce budget deficit) tax incentives for private saving 99

Chapter Summary 3. Productivity slowdown & “new economy” Early 1970s: productivity growth fell in the U.S. and other countries. Mid 1990s: productivity growth increased, probably because of advances in I.T. 4. Empirical studies Solow model explains balanced growth, conditional convergence Cross-country variation in living standards is due to differences in cap. accumulation and in production efficiency 100

Chapter Summary 5. Endogenous growth theory: Models that examine the determinants of the rate of tech. progress, which Solow takes as given. explain decisions that determine the creation of knowledge through R&D. 101