1 Arbitrage risk and the book- to-market anomaly Ali, Hwang and Trombley JFE (2003)

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Common Risk Factors in the Returns on Stocks and Bonds Eugene F. Fama Kenneth R. French Journal of Financial Economics 1993 Presenter: 周立軒.
Advertisements

The Efficient Market Hypothesis
Value Premium in International REITs ERES Conference 2014 Ytzen van der Werf and Fred Huibers 27 June 2014
1/19 Motivation Framework Data Regressions Portfolio Sorts Conclusion Option Returns and Individual Stock Volatility Jie Cao, Chinese University of Hong.
Konan Chan Fengfei Li National Chengchi University University of Hong Kong Tse-Chun Lin Ji-Chai Lin University of Hong Kong Louisiana State University.
Brett Bates Greg Chedwick Chris Ferre Matt Karam.
Pricing Risk Chapter 10.
STOCK RETURNS AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE Michael DeStefano.
Empirical Tests of the Capital Asset Pricing Model (Chapter 9)
Capital Investments and Stock Returns Sheridan Titman K. C. John Wei Feixue Xie (Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 39, 2004, pp )
LECTURE 9 : EMPRICIAL EVIDENCE : CAPM AND APT
Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved. Chapter 10 Capital Markets and the Pricing of Risk.
1 Investor Protection and the Information Content of Annual Earnings Announcements: International Evidence Mark L. DeFond Mingyi Hung Robert Trezevant.
The Inefficient Market What Pays Off and Why Part 2: Why Prentice Hall 1999 Visit our web-site at HaugenSystems.com.
Small is good? Small cap investing Aswath Damodaran.
THREE FACTOR MODEL: FAMA AND FRENCH (1992) Oren Hovemann Yutong Jiang Erhard Rathsack Jon Tyler.
GROUP 5. Outline  Weekly Group Update  Update on Table 6 (2007 paper)  Update on Table 2 (2007 paper)  Plans for the 2008 paper.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin © 2008 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., All Rights Reserved. Capital Asset Pricing and Arbitrage Pricing Theory CHAPTER 7.
R&D-Intensity, Mispricing, and Stock Returns in Taiwan Stock Market.
CHAPTER 13 Investments Empirical Evidence on Security Returns Slides by Richard D. Johnson Copyright © 2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights.
Size Effect Matthew Boyce Huibin Hu Rajesh Raghunathan Lina Yang.
Determinants of Credit Default Swap Spread: Evidence from the Japanese Credit Derivative Market.
Chapter 10 Capital Markets and the Pricing of Risk.
Chapter 10 Capital Markets and the Pricing of Risk
Jie Zhang, HKPU Forecasted Earnings per Share and the Cross Section of Expected Returns Ling Cen K.C. John Wei Hong Kong University of Science and Technology.
Liquidity and Market Efficiency Tarun Chordia (Emory) Richard Roll (UCLA) A. Subrahmanyam (UCLA)
Investments, 8 th edition Bodie, Kane and Marcus Slides by Susan Hine McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2009 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights.
Chapter 9 CAPITAL ASSET PRICING AND ARBITRAGE PRICING THEORY The Risk Reward Relationship.
Investor Sentiment and Price Discovery: Evidence from the Pricing Dynamics between the Futures and Spot Markets SWJTU, Chengdu, 2015 Robin K. Chou National.
Explaining the Value Premium around the World: Risk or Mispricing? Discussant: Yanzhi Wang Department of Finance National Taiwan University 1.
Empirical Evidence of Risk Shifting Behavior in Large and Small Distressed Firms Chuang-Chang Chang Yu-Jen Hsiao Yu-Chih Lin Wei-Cheng Chen.
Portfolio risk and return
International portfolio diversification benefits: Cross-country evidence from a local perspective Authors of the Paper: Joost Driessen Luc Laeven Presented.
International portfolio diversification benefits: Cross-country evidence from a local perspective By J. Driessen and L. Laeven Presented by Michal Kolář,
Anomalies and NEWS Joey engelberg (UCSD) R
Does Academic Research Destroy Stock Return Predictability. R
Momentum and Reversal.
Hasib Ahmed Phuvadon Wuthisatian Atsuyuki Naka
Chapter 10 Capital Markets and the Pricing of Risk
The Value Premium and the CAPM
Market-Risk Measurement
Are Financial Markets Efficient ?
Equilibrium Asset Pricing
Pricing Risk.
Capital Asset Pricing and Arbitrage Pricing Theory
Capital Asset Pricing and Arbitrage Pricing Theory
What Factors Drive Global Stock Returns?
The CAPM is a simple linear model expressed in terms of expected returns and expected risk.
When does the market matter?
Forecast Revision and Information Uncertainty in Australia Stocks
Investor Sentiment.
Author: Konstantinos Drakos Journal: Economica
Momentum, contrarian, and the January seasonality
Portfolio Risk Management : A Primer
Momentum Effect (JT 1993).
Leverage, Financial Distress and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns
MICHAEL NEEL, University of Houston
Journal of Economics and Finance(2017) 41:311–329
Capital Asset Pricing and Arbitrage Pricing Theory
The relation between equity incentives and misreporting: The role of risk-taking incentives 吴圆圆
Behavioral Finance Economics 437.
Weifeng Hung, Feng Chia Universty, Taiwan Chaoshin Chiao,
Over-investment in corporate R&D, risk, and stock returns
From: Accounting Review, 2012, 87(2): Cited Quantity:514
Audra L. Boone, Erik Lie, Yixin Liu
Figure 7.1 Efficient Frontier and Capital Market Line
Even-Tov O Journal of Accounting & Economics, 2017, 64(1).
Options Trading Activity and Firm Valuation
Measuring Exposure to Exchange Rate Fluctuations
Global Market Inefficiencies
Presentation transcript:

1 Arbitrage risk and the book- to-market anomaly Ali, Hwang and Trombley JFE (2003)

2 I. Introduction Empirical evidence: predictable returns over three to five years for portfolios long in high B/M stocks and short in low B/M stocks. There are two competing explanations. 1. The return to B/M based portfolio strategies represents compensation for risk (Fama and French(1992, 1993)). 2. The return to B/M based portfolio strategies results from systematic mispricing of extreme B/M securities.

3 I. Introduction (con.)  Studies show that market participants underestimate (overestimate) future earnings for high (low) B/M stocks. (La Porta et al., 1997).  Shleifer and Vishny (1997) argue that arbitrage is costly. The risk due to the volatility of arbitrage returns (arbitrage risk) deters arbitrage activity. This study empirically examines the prediction of SV(1997) and provides additional evidence to discriminate between the risk and mispricing

4 I. Introduction (con.) explanations for the B/M effect. 1. If the B/M effect is due to mispricing, it should be greater with higher expected volatility. This study uses historical volatility of the market model residuals as a proxy for idiosyncratic risk. 2. Besides, this study also finds that the B/M effect is greater for stocks with higher transaction costs and stocks with less ownership by sophisticated investors.

5 I. Introduction (con.) Related literature 1. Lakonishok et al., (1994) predict that returns to B/M strategies are smaller for stocks of larger companies (arbitrage costs and investor sophistication affect the existence of mispricing and firm size proxies for these factors). However, La Porta et al., (1997) report that the B/M effect is not much different across small and large firms. 本文的貢獻 : 以更直接的變數來 測度套利成本與投資者的複雜度, 以檢驗 B/M 效果 的價格錯估假說.

6 I. Introduction (con.) 2. Prior empirical studies attempting to explain the existence of systematic mispricing on the basis of arbitrage costs focus mainly on transaction costs, and not much attention is given to arbitrage risk. 本文的貢獻 : 強調套利風險的影響, 並且 examine whether arbitrage risk contributes incrementally to the existence of the B/M effect.

7 II. Data and Variables Returns to B/M based portfolio strategies 1. Samples: the sample consists of all firms on NYSE and AMEX from the period 1976 to B/M is calculated as book value in year t-1 divided by market value of equity at the end of June of year t. 2. Form quintile portfolios with the lowest B/M observations (Q1) and the highest B/M observations (Q5) for each year. Buy-and-hold returns are measured over one-, two-, and three-year holding periods beginning in July of year t.

8 II. Data and Variables (con.) 3. Then compute difference in returns of the extreme B/M portfolios (Q5-Q1) for each sample year and use the time-series of return differences to calculate the mean value and the test statistics. 4. Table 1: B/M based portfolio strategies produce positive returns.  Raw returns (Ret12, Ret24, Ret36)  Size-adjusted returns (SRet12, SRet24, SRet36): raw returns minus the corresponding NYSE/AMEX CRSP size-decile index returns ( 調整規模大小的影響 ).

9 II. Data and Variables (con.) Measures of arbitrage risk, transaction costs and investor sophistication 1. Expected arbitrage risk is Ivolatility: by regressing daily returns on a value-weighted market index over a maximum of 250 days ending on June 30 of year t and then computing the variance of the residuals. 2. Direct transaction costs: (1) Bid-Ask: (bid-ask)/ 0.5*(bid+ask) ( 由 July of year t-1 to June of year t, 共 12 個月之每月最後一個交易日 的最後一小時報價來平均 )(available from 1994 to 1997).

10 II. Data and Variables (con.) (2) Price: the closing price per share in June of year t. 3. Indirect transaction costs Volume: the annual volume of trade from July 1 of year t-1 to June 30 of year t (in million of dollars). 4. Short-selling costs Inst%: the percentage of common stocks owned by institutions at the end of year t-1 (available beginning in 1987)

11 II. Data and Variables (con.) 5. Comprehensive measure of transaction costs Zerofreq: the frequency of zero daily returns over the period July 1 of year t-1 to June 30 of year t. 6. Investor sophistication (1) Analysts: the number of analysts’ estimates included in the database in May of year t (beginning in 1976). (2) Inst#: the numbers of institutional owners at the end of year t-1 (beginning in 1987).

12 II. Data and Variables (con.) For each year, all the observations are ranked ( 每 一年根據前述套利風險等指標, 將樣本股票分 成十組, 第一組 G1 代表套利風險與成本最高者, 依序遞減 ). 1. All of the variables exhibit substantial variation between G1 and G10 groups (p.363). 2. Table 2: Spearman correlations among the measure of arbitrage risk, transaction costs, investor sophistication and firm size.

13 II. Data and Variables (con.)  The correlations of ME with other measures are significant different from zero. Also each correlation is also significant less than one. It is not sufficient to examine only the effect of firm size.  The correlations among measures of arbitrage risk, transaction costs, and investor sophistication are significantly less than 1, but they are also not close to zero.

14 III. Empirical results Portfolio tests 1.Independent of B/M rankings, firms are ranked each year in descending order of Ivolatility (G1- G10). This results in 50 portfolios in each year. Q5-Q1 SRet36 are then computed for each of the group (G1~G10).  Table 3 first column: the mean of Q5-Q1 SRet36 for each of the ten groups. The mean of Q5-Q1 Ret36 of group G1 is significantly greater than that of group G10.

15 III. Empirical results (con.)  To examine the relation across all the decile groups, a correlation between group ranks and Q5-Q1 SRet36 of the groups is computed (negative).  Figure 1: annual estimates of Q5-Q1 Ret36 for Ivolatility groups G1 and G10.  Figure 2: cumulated returns for the Q5-Q1 portfolios of groups G1 and G10 at monthly intervals.  These results support the market-mispricing explanation and indicate that arbitrage risk is one of the reasons why arbitrageurs do not trade away the

16 III. Empirical results (con.) systematic B/M-related mispricing. 2. The above analysis is repeated for each of the other measures of arbitrage costs and investor sophistication.  For all the measures, the correlation between Q5- Q1 SRet36 and the group rank for G1 to G10 is negative, consistent with mispricing explanation. Besides, lots of the G1-G10 results are positive and significant. B/M effect increases with arbitrage costs and decreases with investor

17 III. Empirical results (con.) sophistication, consistent with the mispricing explanation. Incremental role of arbitrage risk This study intends to determine the incremental role of arbitrage risk in the existence of the B/M effect (see p.369 regression eq(1)). 1. The coefficients on the interaction terms capture how the B/M effect varies cross-sectionally with the arbitrage cost/investor sophistication measures.

18 III. Empirical results (con.)  A significant negative coefficient on B/M * Ivolatility -1 would suggest that after controlling for other arbitrage cost and investor sophistication measures, Ivolatility explains cross- sectional variation in the B/M effect. 2. Table 4 reports the regression estimates of eq1. and two reduced versions of the model.  Column 1: the presence of B/M effect (consistent with table 1).

19 III. Empirical results (con.)  Column 2: B/M effect increases with the increase in return volatility (-0.138, t=-2.797,consistent with the results in table 3).  Column 3: the results of complete eq1. The coefficient on B/M * Ivolatility -1 remains negative and significant. Among the other interaction terms in eq1, none has a negative and significant coefficient. A likely explanation is that these measures are highly correlated with each other and that more than one measure can capture similar underlying effects.

20 IV. Conclusion The finding is consistent with the Shleifer and Vishny (1997) thesis that risk associated with the volatility of arbitrage returns deters arbitrage activity and is an important reason for the existence of the B/M-related mispricing. The authors also recognize the limitation of their tests in discriminating between the mispricing and risk explanation for the B/M effect. If B/M captures financial distress, then the B/M effect may be stronger for firms with high volatility stocks because the financial distress factor may be more sensitive for such firms.