Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Chapter 12 Capital Structure: Theory and Taxes

Similar presentations


Presentation on theme: "Chapter 12 Capital Structure: Theory and Taxes"— Presentation transcript:

1 Chapter 12 Capital Structure: Theory and Taxes
Professor XXXXX Course Name / # © 2007 Thomson South-Western

2 The fundamental principle of financial leverage:
Substituting debt for equity increases expected returns to shareholders—measured by earnings per share or ROE—and the risk (dispersion) of those returns.

3 Financial Leverage When firms borrow money, we say that they use financial leverage. a firm with debt on its balance sheet is a levered firm a firm that finances its operations entirely with equity is an unlevered firm. In Britain, they refer to debt as gearing. These terms imply that debt magnifies a firm’s financial performance in some way. That effect can be either positive or negative, depending on the returns a firm earns on the money it borrows. Recapitalization

4 Example: Using Debt to Increase Expected Earnings per Share

5 Evidence on Capital Structure
1) More profitable firms tend to use less leverage. 2) High-growth firms borrow less than mature firms do. 3) Firms’ product market strategies and asset bases influence capital structure choice. 4) Stock market generally views leverage-increasing events positively. 5) Tax deductibility of interest gives firms an incentive to use debt.

6 Worldwide Capital Structure Patterns
Firms in the same industry often have similar capital structures regardless of their home country. Capital structures vary across countries. Leverage ratios vary inversely with financial distress costs. Corporate and personal taxes influence capital structures, but taxes alone cannot explain differences in leverage across firms, industries, or countries.

7 Worldwide Capital Structure Patterns
Markets interpret leverage-increasing events as “good news” and leverage-decreasing events as “bad news.” Corporations strive to maintain target capital structures. Research suggests that corporations like to operate within target leverage zones and will issue new equity (debt) when debt ratios get too high (low). There is some evidence that, within industries, leverage varies inversely with profitability.

8 Theoretical Models Of Capital Structure
The agency cost/tax shield trade-off model The pecking order theory The signaling model The market-timing model Modigliani and Miller’s (M&M) capital structure model

9 The Agency Cost/Tax-shield Trade-off Model
The trade-off model: predicts that managers choose the capital structure that strikes a balance between debt’s tax advantages and its agency costs.

10 The Pecking-order Model
Strongest challenger to the trade-off model Consists of two assumptions: Managers are better informed about their own firms’ prospects than are outside investors (an asymmetric information assumption) Managers act in the best interests of existing shareholders

11 The Signaling Model The signaling model assumes that managers know more about a firm’s prospects than investors do and that in the absence of any compelling evidence to the contrary, investors assign an “average” valuation to each firm. If managers feel that investors undervalue the firm, the only way to convince them of the firm’s true value is to send a signal that a less-valuable firm cannot mimic. One such signal is to issue debt Investors respond to the signal by bidding up the share prices of debt-issuing firms.

12 The Market-timing Model
Firms time the market by issuing equity when share values are high and issuing debt when share prices are low. As a consequence, a firm’s capital structure simply reflects the cumulative effects of its managers’ past market-timing activities.

13 The Modigliani & Miller Propositions
Modigliani and Miller (M&M) argument: capital structure decisions cannot affect firm value Managers who operate in imperfect markets can see more clearly how market imperfections might lead them to choose one capital structure over another. M&M’s argument rests on the principle of no arbitrage

14 The M&M Capital Structure Model
First model to show that capital structure decision may be irrelevant Assumes perfect markets, no taxes or transactions costs Key insight Firm value is determined by: Cash flows generated Underlying business risk Capital structure merely determines how cash flows and risks are allocated between bondholders and stockholders.

15 Assumptions Of The M&M Capital Structure Model
Capital markets are frictionless – neither firms nor investors pay taxes or transactions costs. Investors can borrow and lend at the same rate that corporations can. Firms are identical in every respect except for capital structure.

16 M&M Proposition I In perfect markets, a firm’s total market value equals the value of its assets and is independent of the firm’s capital structure. The value of the assets equals the present value of the cash flows generated by the assets.

17 M&M Proposition I Because the proposition leads to the conclusion that the firm’s capital structure does not matter, it is popularly known as the “irrelevance proposition.” The firm’s market value equals the present value of the cash flows it generates regardless of the capital structure it chooses.

18 Use arbitrage arguments to prove proposition I
M&M Proposition I Use arbitrage arguments to prove proposition I Proposition I: Market value of a firm is driven by two factors: cash flow and risk (determines the discount rate). Firm U has no debt. Firm L has both debt and equity. Required return r for firms of this risk class is 10%. Firms U and L belong to same risk class and have same expected EBIT $2,000,000 per year in perpetuity. Under proposition I, market value of firms U and L should be identical.

19 M&M Proposition I Market value of assets should be $20,000,000
Firm U Firm L Earnings before interest (no taxes) $2,000,000 Required return on assets 10% Market value of assets Debt $0 $10,000,000 Interest rate on debt 6% Interest expense $600,000 Shares outstanding 1,000,000 500,000 Price per share $20 Market value of equity $20,000,000 Market value of firm U = 1,000,000 x $20 = $20,000,000 Market value of firm L = 500,000 x $20 + $10,000,000 = $20,000,000

20 M&M Proposition I What is the return the shareholders of the two firms expect on their shares? Firm U has no debt Required return on equity equals required return on assets of 10% Required return on equity = 10% Firm L pays $600,000 interest. EBIT is $2,000,000 Shareholders receive a cash dividend of $1,400,000, or $2.80/share. Share price = $20. Required return on equity = $2.80/$20 = 14%

21 What if the shares of the levered firm are selling at premium?
M&M Proposition I What if the shares of the levered firm are selling at premium? Assume the stock price of firm L is $25. Firm L Stock price $20 Total firm value $20,000,000 Debt value $10,000,000 Shares outstanding 500,000 Dividend per share $2.80 Required return on equity 0.14 $25 $22,500,000 Total firm value increases to $22,500,000. The price of $25 per share implies a return of $2.80/$20 = 0.112 Firm L stockholders can use “homemade leverage” to generate arbitrage profit.

22 Assume investor owns 5,000 shares of firm L
M&M Proposition I Assume investor owns 5,000 shares of firm L The investor owns 1% of firm L. He earns $2.80 per share in dividends. The shares will generate $14,000 each year. The investor could earn an arbitrage profit from the following: Sell 5,000 of firm L at $25 per share Proceeds of $125,000 Borrow an amount equal to 1% of firm L debt $100,000 at 6% interest Buy 1% of firm U equity 10,000 shares at $20 per share

23 The net return on the new portfolio
M&M Proposition I Using homemade leverage, investor has built a portfolio of $200,000 of firm U's stock and $100,000 in personal debt. Investor has $25,000 remaining. Trades Proceeds from stock sale $125,000 Proceeds from borrowing $100,000 Total proceeds $225,000 Cost of firm U shares -$200,000 Net proceeds $25,000 The net return on the new portfolio $2 dividend per share of firm U, $20,000 for 10,000 shares $6,000 interest expense on borrowed money $14,000 cash inflow next year on the new portfolio The same return expected on the original 1% stake in firm L's shares! The cost of building this portfolio is just $200,000 , $25,000 less than the cost of 5,000 firm L shares.

24 Proposition II And The WACC
Though debt is less costly for firms to issue than equity, issuing debt causes the required return on the remaining equity to rise. Based on the core finance principle that investors expect compensation for risk, shareholders of levered firms demand higher returns than do shareholders in all-equity companies.

25 Proposition II And The WACC
Proposition II says that the expected return on a levered firm’s equity, rl, rises with the debt-to-equity ratio: Proposition II rearranged is the WACC:

26 M&M Proposition II Illustrated—The Cost of Equity, Cost of Debt, and WACC for a Firm in a World without Taxes

27 The M&M Model With Corporate Taxes
Firms can treat interest payments to lenders as a tax-deductible business expense. Dividend payments to shareholders receive no similar tax advantage. Intuitively, this should lead to a tax advantage for debt, meaning that managers can increase firm value by issuing debt.

28 Determining The Present Value Of Debt Tax Shields
Assume the firm always renews its debt when it matures – the interest deduction becomes a perpetuity equal to the tax rate times the interest paid.

29 The Impact of Taxes on Proposition I

30 The Impact of Taxes on Proposition I

31 The M&M Model With Corporate And Personal Taxes
Miller argued that debt’s tax advantage over equity at the corporate level might be partially or fully offset by a tax disadvantage at the individual level

32 Bond Market Equilibrium With Corporate And Personal Taxes
Wouldn’t taxable investors also demand a higher interest rate to compensate them for taxes due? The answer is yes, but …. Miller explains that interest rates do not rise immediately for two reasons: (1) Some investors, such as endowments and pension funds, do not have to pay taxes on interest income. (2) Investors who do not enjoy this tax-exempt status can buy municipal bonds, which pay interest that is tax free.

33 Bond Market Equilibrium in the Miller (1977) Model

34 Other Tax-based Models Of Capital Structure
The Nondebt tax shields (NDTS) hypothesis states that companies with large amounts of depreciation, investment tax credits, R&D expenditures, and other nondebt tax shields should employ less debt financing than otherwise equivalent companies with fewer such shields. Later research found that leverage seemed to be directly, not inversely, related to the availability of NDTS. The secured debt hypothesis implies that firms rich in tangible assets are able to use higher levels of (secured) debt.

35 How Taxes Should Affect Capital Structure
The higher the corporate income tax rate, Tc, the higher will be the equilibrium leverage level economy-wide. An increase in Tc should cause debt ratios to increase for most firms. The higher the personal tax rate on equity-related investment income (dividends and capital gains), Tps, the higher will be the equilibrium leverage level. An increase in Tps should cause debt ratios to increase. The higher the personal tax rate on interest income, Tpd, the lower will be the equilibrium leverage level. An increase in Tpd should cause debt ratios to fall.


Download ppt "Chapter 12 Capital Structure: Theory and Taxes"

Similar presentations


Ads by Google