Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Economics 216: The Macroeconomics of Development Lawrence J. Lau, Ph. D., D. Soc. Sc. (hon.) Kwoh-Ting Li Professor of Economic Development Department.

Similar presentations


Presentation on theme: "Economics 216: The Macroeconomics of Development Lawrence J. Lau, Ph. D., D. Soc. Sc. (hon.) Kwoh-Ting Li Professor of Economic Development Department."— Presentation transcript:

1 Economics 216: The Macroeconomics of Development Lawrence J. Lau, Ph. D., D. Soc. Sc. (hon.) Kwoh-Ting Li Professor of Economic Development Department of Economics Stanford University Stanford, CA 94305-6072, U.S.A. Spring 2000-2001 Email: ljlau@stanford.edu; WebPages: http://www.stanford.edu/~ljlau

2 Lecture 6 Models of Economic Development: One-Sector Models Lawrence J. Lau, Ph. D., D. Soc. Sc. (hon.) Kwoh-Ting Li Professor of Economic Development Department of Economics Stanford University Stanford, CA 94305-6072, U.S.A. Spring 2000-2001 Email: ljlau@stanford.edu; WebPages: http://www.stanford.edu/~ljlau

3 Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University3 One-Sector Closed Economy Models u Optimizing Models of Growth u Specification of an objective function u Consumption versus savings u Choice of technique u Allocation of investment u Descriptive Models of Growth

4 Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University4 Assumptions u Consumers u Representative consumer with time preference u Infinite lifetime u Existing level of output per capita exceeds the subsistence level of consumption per capita (otherwise no capacity for savings) u Production u One-sector aggregate production function as a function of capital stock and labor u Investment u Distribution u Exogenously determined rate of growth of population u CAPITAL ACCUMULATION IS THE LINK BETWEEN THE PRESENT AND THE FUTURE

5 Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University5 The Harrod-Domar Model u Production function with fixed coefficients (no substitution possibilities) u Y = min { a K K, a L L}

6 Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University6 One-Sector Model with Neoclassical Production Function u Production function with smooth substitution possibilities u Cobb-Douglas production function u Constant-Elasticity-of-Substitution (C.E.S.) production function u Special case of elasticity of substitution greater than unity

7 Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University7 The Neoclassical Model of Growth (Solow) u Production Function u One-sector aggregate production function as a function of capital stock and labor Y = F(K, L) u Consumers u Representative consumer with time preference u Infinite lifetime u Existing level of output per capita exceeds the subsistence level of consumption per capita u No income-leisure choice u Consumption and savings behavior C = (1-s) Y; S = sY; where s is the savings rate, assumed to be constant

8 Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University8 The Neoclassical Model of Growth (Solow) u Producers u Competitive maximization of profits u Investment behavior I = S u Equilibrium in output markets C + I = Y u Equilibrium in factor markets u Full employment of capital and labor u Population growth L = L 0 e nt u Capital accumulation u The link between present and future

9 Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University9 The Neoclassical Model of Growth (Solow) Capital Accumulation

10 Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University10 The Assumption of Constant Returns to Scale u Let y  Y/L; k  K/L. Under constant returns to scale, F( K, L) = F(K, L) u Let =1/L, then, F(K/L, L/L) = F(K, L)/L, or u y = Y/L = F(k, 1)  f(k), the “intensive” form of the production function, expressing output per unit labor as a function of capital per unit labor

11 Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University11 Differential Equation of k

12 Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University12 Differential Equation of k: The Equation of Motion

13 Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University13 Differential Equation of k

14 Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University14 Existence of Steady-State Growth

15 Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University15 Existence of Steady-State Growth

16 Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University16 The Inada (1964) Conditions u The marginal productivity of capital approaches infinity as capital approaches zero, holding labor constant u The marginal productivity of capital approaches zero as capital approaches infinity, holding labor constant u The Inada conditions are sufficient, but not necessary, for the existence of a steady state u It is possible to replace the second Inada condition by the following (at the cost of possible non-existence of a steady-state) u The marginal productivity of capital approaches a constant as capital approaches infinity, holding labor constant

17 Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University17 The Role of Strict Monotonicity and Strict Concavity of the Production Function u Strict monotonicity of F(K, L) implies strict monotonicity of f(k) u Strict concavity of F(K, L) implies strict concavity of f(k) u Twice continuous differentiability of F(K, L) implies twice continuous differentiability of f(k) u Essentially of K and L implies that f(0) = 0 u The Inada conditions imply that f’(k) approaches infinity as k approaches zero and f’(k) approaches zero as k approaches infinity u f’(k) is therefore a continuously differentiable, positive and strictly decreasing function of k, taking values within the range infinity and zero--for sufficiently large k, f(k) approaches a constant

18 Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University18 The Role of Strict Monotonicity and Strict Concavity of the Production Function u The function sf(k)-(  + n)k considered as a function of k is monotonically increasing for small positive values of k because of the Inada condition u The function sf(k)-(  + n)k considered as a function of k is monotonically decreasing for sufficiently large positive values of k again because of the Inada condition u The function is strictly concave in k so that its slope is always declining u For sufficiently small values of k, the function is positive; for sufficiently large values of k, the function is dominated by -(  + n)k and is hence negative u Given strict concavity, which implies continuity, the function must be equal to zero for some k*, and only for that k*--there is a unique value of k = k* for which sf(k)-(  + n)k = 0

19 Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University19 Comparative Statics of the Steady State u Comparative statics with respect to s u The effect on the steady-state rate of growth--none u The effect on the steady-state level of k--positive u Hence the effect on the steady-state level of y—positive u Comparative statics with respect to n u The effect on the steady-state rate of growth—positive u The effect on the steady-state level of k—negative u Hence the effect on the steady-state level of y--negative u Comparative statics with respect to  u The effect on the steady-state rate of growth--none u The effect on the steady-state level of k--negative u Hence the effect on the steady-state level of y—negative

20 Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University20 The Case of Purely Labor-Augmenting (Harrod-Neutral) Technical Progress u Production Function u One-sector aggregate production function as a function of capital stock and labor Y = F(K, Le  t ), where  is the exogenously given rate of purely labor-augmenting technical progress u Consumers u C = (1-s) Y; S = sY; where s is the savings rate, assumed to be constant

21 Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University21 The Neoclassical Model of Growth (Solow) u Producers I = S u Equilibrium in output markets C + I = Y u Equilibrium in factor markets u Full employment of capital and labor u Population growth L = L 0 e nt u Capital accumulation

22 Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University22 The Neoclassical Model of Growth (Solow) Capital Accumulation

23 Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University23 The Assumption of Constant Returns to Scale u Let y  Y/Le  t ; k  K/Le  t, respectively output per unit “augmented labor” and capital per unit “augmented labor”. Under constant returns to scale, u F(K/Le  t, Le  t /Le  t ) = F(K, Le  t )/Le  t, or u y = Y/Le  t = F(k, 1)  f(k), the “intensive” form of the production function, expressing output per unit “augmented labor” as a function of capital per unit “augmented labor”

24 Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University24 Differential Equation of k

25 Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University25 Differential Equation of k

26 Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University26 Existence of Steady-State Growth

27 Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University27 Steady State in the Case of Purely Labor- Augmenting Technical Progress u Since K/Le  t =K/L 0 e (n+  )t is equal to a constant in steady state, K must also be growing at the same rate of (n+  ) as “augmented labor”. By constant returns to scale, the rate of growth of real output is also (n+  ), independent of the value of s u The rate of growth of real output per unit “augmented labor” is therefore 0, but the rate of growth of real output per unit (actual, unaugmented) labor is  u The capital/“augmented” labor ratio is constant, but the actual capital/labor ratio grows at the rate 

28 Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University28 The Case of a Non-Constant Savings Rate u Let s  g(y) with g’(y)  0 u g’(y) approaches zero for y  some y* u Consider the function sf(k)-(  +n)k = g(f(k))f(k)-(  +n)k = f*(k)-(  +n)k u For sufficiently large k (and therefore y), g’(y) = 0, the behavior of f*(k)-(  +n)k is therefore similar to that of sf(k)-(  +n)k with s a constant u For sufficiently small k (and therefore y), if g’(y) approaches a constant as y approaches zero, then the behavior of f*(k)-(  +n)k is again similar to that of sf(k)-(  +n)k with s a constant u f*(k)-(  +n)k is therefore positive for small k and negative for large k and therefore must be equal to 0 for some k*

29 Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University29 Existence of Steady-State Growth

30 Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University30 The Case of a Non-Constant Savings Rate u Let s  g(r/p, y), where r/p is the rate of return on capital u g(.) is assumed to be continuously differentiable and weakly monotonically increasing with respect to r/p and y u r/p = f’(k) under the assumption of competitive profit maximization u Consider the function sf(k)-(  +n)k = g(f’(k), f(k))f(k)-(  +n)k = f*(k)-(  +n)k; its behavior determines whether a steady state exists u If for some k 1, f*(k 1 ) -(  +n)k 1  0, that is, the savings in the economy exceed the depreciation and the dilution (due to the growth of the labor force) of capital; and for some k 2, f*(k 2 ) -(  +n)k 2  0, then a steady state exists and is stable. u Condition II is generally satisfied because g(.) is bounded by, say, 0.5 from above and 0 from below, and f(k) is strictly concave, f*(k)- (  +n)k is therefore eventually negative for large k

31 Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University31 Alternative Sets of Sufficient Conditions u Conditions on f*(k) u There exists k 1 and k 2, k 1  k 2,such that f*(k 1 ) -(  +n)k 1  0; f*(k 2 ) -(  +n)k 2  0 u Conditions on f*’(k) u lim f*’(k) as k approaches zero is strictly greater than (  + n) u lim f*’(k) as k approaches plus infinity is strictly less than (  + n)

32 Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University32 The Independence of the Steady-State Rate of Growth from the Savings Rate u R. M. Solow (1956) u The importance of Inada’s second condition--the marginal product of capital approaches zero as the quantity of capital (relative to labor) approaches infinity u If the marginal product of capital has a lower bound, then the steady-state rate of growth may depend on the savings rate (Rebelo (1991))

33 Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University33 Two-Gap Models u How to overcome short and medium-term constraints on economic development and growth? u How to jump-start a stagnant economy? u Two-gap models are not intended for long-run or steady-state analysis u Open economy versus closed economy u Constraints on savings u Net imports can augment domestic savings and enable higher domestic investment in an economy with low real GNP and/or low savings u Constraints on imports: u Foreign exchange revenue (exports, foreign investment, loans, foreign aid)

34 Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University34 A Simple Two-Gap Model u Production Function u One-sector aggregate production function as a function of capital stock and labor Y = F(K, L) u Consumers u Consumption and savings behavior (C+S=Y) C = (1-s) Y; S = sY; where s is the savings rate, not necessarily constant, more generally, one can write S = G(Y), where G(.) is a non-decreasing function of Y u Producers u Investment behavior (X and M are perfect substitutes in this one-good model) I = S + M -X

35 Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University35 A Simple Two-Gap Model u Equilibrium in output markets C + I + X - M= Y u Equilibrium in factor markets u Full employment of capital and labor u Population growth L = L 0 e nt u Capital accumulation u The link between present and future

36 Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University36 A Simple Two-Gap Model: Capital Accumulation

37 Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University37 A Simple Two-Gap Model: The Savings and Foreign Exchange Gaps u The savings gap--nonnegativity of net investment (or net investment per unit labor) I -  K = G(Y) + M -X -  K  0 (nK) u The net investment required to increase K and Y sufficiently so that domestic savings can become a sustaining source of domestic investment and capital accumulation u The foreign-exchange gap M  X + FC, where FC = Foreign aid, foreign investment and foreign loans u Increasing FC allows M to increase, other things being equal, thereby relieving both constraints u Increasing X also helps, provided M is also increased at the same time (that is why even export-oriented developing countries run trade deficits in their early phases of development)

38 Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University38 Extensions of the Two-Gap Model u Imports can affect an economy more directly and more significantly--exports and imports are not really perfect substitutes: u Output may depend on both domestic capital stock and imported inputs (capital or intermediate goods) u Fixed investment may depend on imported capital and intermediate inputs

39 Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University39 Alternative Specifications of Two-Gap Models u Production Function u One-sector aggregate production function as a function of capital stock, labor, and the quantity of imports (of intermediate inputs) Y = F(K, L, M) u A heterogeneous capital stock model--the aggregate production function as a function of domestic and imported capital stocks and labor Y = F(K D, K M, L) u Drawback: two capital accumulation equations will be needed u Investment function u (Fixed) investment is constrained by both the availability of financial savings and actual physical imports (of capital equipment)

40 Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University40 Implications on Export Orientation u These alternative specifications incorporate the recognition that it is not only net imports, but also gross imports, that matter. In other words, exports and imports are not perfect substitutes u In order to increase gross imports, exports must be increased (in order to increase net imports, exports can be decreased) u Moreover, the ability to export makes an economy much more attractive to foreign investors and lenders because it facilitates potential repatriation

41 Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University41 Refinements of One-Sector Models u Heterogeneous capital goods u Human capital u Wage-productivity relations u Endogenous population growth u Overlapping generations u Endogenous technical progress u Non-purely labor-augmenting technical progress and the existence of a steady state u Two- and multi-sector models


Download ppt "Economics 216: The Macroeconomics of Development Lawrence J. Lau, Ph. D., D. Soc. Sc. (hon.) Kwoh-Ting Li Professor of Economic Development Department."

Similar presentations


Ads by Google