Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Why composite should be non compensatory Giuseppe Munda Universitat Autonoma de Barcelona Dept.of Economics and Economic History.

Similar presentations


Presentation on theme: "Why composite should be non compensatory Giuseppe Munda Universitat Autonoma de Barcelona Dept.of Economics and Economic History."— Presentation transcript:

1 Why composite should be non compensatory Giuseppe Munda Universitat Autonoma de Barcelona Dept.of Economics and Economic History

2 2

3 3 Step 1. Developing a theoretical framework Step 2. Selecting indicators Step 3. Multivariate analysis Step 4. Imputation of missing data Step 5. Normalisation of data Step 6. Weighting and aggregation Step 7. Robustness and sensitivity Step 8. Association with other variables Step 9. Back to the details (indicators) Step 10. Presentation and dissemination Index construction- Steps [OECD-JRC Handbook]

4 4 Based on:

5 5 Structure of the presentation Linear Aggregation Rule Social Choice and Aggregation Rules Non-Compensatory Aggregation Rules Conclusions

6 6 Linear Aggregation Rule

7 7 Linear aggregation rules and preference independence The variables X1, X2,..., Xn are mutually preferentially independent if every subset Y of these variables is preferentially independent of its complementary set of evaluators. The following theorem holds: given the variables X1, X2,..., Xn, an additive aggregation function exists if and only if these variables are mutually preferentially independent.

8 8 Preferential independence implies that the trade-off ratio between two variables is independent of the values of the n-2 other variables, i.e. Preferential independence is a very strong condition from both the operational and epistemological points of view.

9 9 The meaning of weights in linear aggregation rules Greater weight should be given to components which are considered to be more significant in the context of the particular composite indicator. (OECD, 2003, p. 10). Weights as symmetrical importance, that is "… if we have two non-equal numbers to construct a vector in R2, then it is preferable to place the greatest number in the position corresponding to the most important criterion." (Podinovskii, 1994, p. 241).

10 10

11 11 The aggregation of several criteria implies taking a position on the fundamental issue of compensability. Compensability refers to the existence of trade- offs, i.e. the possibility of offsetting a disadvantage on some criteria by an advantage on another criterion. E.g. in the construction of a composite indicator of environmental sustainability a compensatory logic (using equal weighting) would imply that one is willing to accept, lets say, 10% more CO2 emissions in exchange of a 3% increase in GDP.

12 12 The implication is the existence of a theoretical inconsistency in the way weights are actually used and their real theoretical meaning. For the weights to be interpreted as importance coefficients (the greatest weight is placed on the most important dimension) non-compensatory aggregation procedures must be used to construct composite indicators.

13 Linear Aggregation is a correect rule iff Mutual preferential independence applies Compensability is desirable Weights are derived as trade-offs

14 14 Social Choice and Aggregation Rules

15 15 The Plurality Rule

16 16 Example (rearranged from Moulin, 1988, p. 228; 21 criteria and 4 alternatives ) Objective: find best country A first possibility: apply the plurality rule the country which is more often ranked in the first position is the winning one. Country a is the best. BUT Country a is also the one with the strongest opposition since 13 indicators put it into the last position! # of indicators3576 1st position aabc 2nd position bcdb 3rd position cbcd 4th position ddaa This paradox was the starting step of Bordas and Condorcets research at the end of the 18th century, but the plurality rule corresponds to the most common electoral system in the 21st century!!!

17 17 Borda approach RankabcdPoints 1st nd rd th Frequency matrix (21 criteria 4 alternatives) Jean-Charles, chevalier de Borda

18 18 Borda approach Borda solution: b c a d Now: country b is the best, not a (as in the case of the plurality rule) RankabcdPoints 1st nd rd th Frequency matrix (21 criteria 4 alternatives) Borda score: The plurality rule paradox has been solved.

19 19 Condorcet approach Outranking matrix (21 criteria 4 alternatives) Jean-Antoine-Nicolas de Caritat, Marquis de Condorcet

20 20 Condorcet approach For each pair of countries a concordance index is computed by counting how many individual indicators are in favour of each country (e.g. b better than a 13 times). constant sum property in the outranking matrix (13+8=21) Outranking matrix (21 criteria 4 alternatives)

21 21 Condorcet approach Pairs with concordance index > 50% of the indicators are selected. Majority threshold = 11 (i.e. a number of individual indicators bigger than the 50% of the indicators considered) Pairs with a concordance index 11: bPa= 13, bPd=21(=always), cPa=13, cPb=11, cPd=14, dPa=13. Condorcet solution: c b d a Yet, the derivation of a Condorcet ranking may sometimes be a long and complex computation process. Outranking matrix (21 criteria 4 alternatives)

22 22 Which approach should one prefer? Both Borda and Condorcet approaches solve the plurality rule paradox. However, the solutions offered are different. Borda solution: b c a d Condorcet solution: c b d a In the framework of composite indicators, can we choose between Borda and Condorcet on some theoretical and/or practical grounds?

23 23 An Original Condorcets Numerical Example

24 24 Number of indicators st abbcc 2nd bcaab 3rd cacba RankabcPoints 1st nd rd Example with 60 indicators [Condorcet, 1785] Frequency matrix Outranking matrix concordance threshold =31 aPb, bPc and cPa (cycle)??? Borda approach Condorcet approach

25 25 From this example we might conclude that the Borda rule (or any scoring rule) is more effective since a country is always selected while the Condorcet one sometimes leads to an irreducible indecisiveness. However Borda rules have other drawbacks, too

26 26 Both social choice literature and multi-criteria decision theory agree that whenever the majority rule can be operationalized, it should be applied. However, the majority rule often produces undesirable intransitivities, thus more limited ambitions are compulsory. The next highest ambition for an aggregation algorithm is to be Condorcet (Arrow and Raynaud, 1986, p. 77).

27 27 Non-Compensatory Aggregation Rules

28 28 Condorcet approach Basic problem: presence of cycles, i.e. aPb, bPc and cPa The probability of obtaining a cycle increases with both N (indicators) and M (countries) [Fishburn (1973, p. 95)]

29 29 Condorcet approach Condorcet himself was aware of this problem (he built examples to explain it) and he was even close to find a consistent rule able to rank any number of alternatives when cycles are present… … but Maximilien de Robespierre

30 30 Condorcet approach Basic problem: presence of cycles, i.e. aPb, bPc and cPa Furter attempts made by Kemeny (1959) and by Young and Levenglick (1978) … led to: Condorcet-Kemeny-Young-Levenglick (C-K-Y-L) ranking procedure

31 31 C-K-Y-L ranking procedure Main methodological foundation: maximum likelihood concept. The maximum likelihood principle selects as a final ranking the one with the maximum pair-wise support. What does this mean and how does it work?

32 Indic.GDPUnemp. Rate Solid wastes Income dispar. Crime rate Country A25, B45, C20, weights AB = =0.666 BA = =0.333 AC = =0.333 CA = =0.666 BC = =0.333 CB = =0.666 C-K-Y-L ranking procedure

33 Indic.GDPUnemp. Rate Solid wastes Income dispar. Crime rate Country A25, B45, C20, weights ABCABC A B C C-K-Y-L ranking procedure AB = =0.666 BA = =0.333 AC = =0.333 CA = =0.666 BC = =0.333 CB = =0.666

34 Indic.GDPUnemp. Rate Solid wastes Income dispar. Crime rate Country A25, B45, C20, weights ABCABC A B C ABC = = BCA = = CAB = = 2 ACB = = BAC = = 1 CBA = = C-K-Y-L ranking procedure

35 35 The Computational problem The only drawback of this aggregation method is the difficulty in computing it when the number of candidates grows. With only 10 countries 10! = 3,628,800 permutations (instead of 3!=6 of the example) To solve this problem of course there is a need to use numerical algorithms C-K-Y-L ranking procedure

36 36 Conclusions

37 Compensabiliity is a fundamental concept in choosing an aggregation rule

38 38

39 39

40 40

41 Using Borda too The KEI example …

42 42 The frequency matrix (Borda type approach) of a countrys rank in each of the seven dimensions and the overall KEI ~2,000 scenarios was calculated across the ~2,000 scenarios.

43 43

44 44 REFERENCES Borda J.C. de (1784) – Mémoire sur les élections au scrutin, in Histoire de l Académie Royale des Sciences, Paris. Brand, D.A., Saisana, M., Rynn, L.A., Pennoni, F., Lowenfels, A.B. (2007) Comparative Analysis of Alcohol Control Policies in 30 Countries, PLoS Medicine, 0759 April 2007, Volume 4, Issue 4, e151, p , Condorcet, Marquis de (1785) – Essai sur lapplication de lanalyse à la probabilité des décisions rendues à la probabilité des voix, De l Imprimerie Royale, Paris. Fishburn P.C. (1973) – The theory of social choice, Princeton University Press, Princeton. Fishburn P.C. (1984) – Discrete mathematics in voting and group choice, SIAM Journal of Algebraic and Discrete Methods, 5, pp

45 45 Munda G. (1995), Multicriteria evaluation in a fuzzy environment, Physica-Verlag, Contributions to Economics Series, Heidelberg. Munda G. (2004) – Social multi-criteria evaluation (SMCE): methodological foundations and operational consequences, European Journal of Operational Research, vol. 158/3, pp Munda G. (2005a) – Multi-Criteria Decision Analysis and Sustainable Development, in J. Figueira, S. Greco and M. Ehrgott (eds.) –Multiple-criteria decision analysis. State of the art surveys, Springer International Series in Operations Research and Management Science, New York, pp Munda G. (2005b) – Measuring sustainability: a multi-criterion framework, Environment, Development and Sustainability Vol 7, No. 1, pp Munda G. and Nardo M. (2005) - Constructing Consistent Composite Indicators: the Issue of Weights, EUR EN, Joint Research Centre, Ispra. Munda G. and Nardo M. (2007) - Non-compensatory/Non-Linear composite indicators for ranking countries: a defensible setting, Forthcoming in Applied Economics. Munda G. (2008) - Social multi-criteria evaluation for a sustainable economy, Springer-Verlag, Heidelberg, New York.


Download ppt "Why composite should be non compensatory Giuseppe Munda Universitat Autonoma de Barcelona Dept.of Economics and Economic History."

Similar presentations


Ads by Google