Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Lecture Notes. Cost Minimization Before looked at maximizing Profits (π) = TR – TC or π =pf(L,K) – wL – rK But now also look at cost minimization That.

Similar presentations


Presentation on theme: "Lecture Notes. Cost Minimization Before looked at maximizing Profits (π) = TR – TC or π =pf(L,K) – wL – rK But now also look at cost minimization That."— Presentation transcript:

1 Lecture Notes

2 Cost Minimization Before looked at maximizing Profits (π) = TR – TC or π =pf(L,K) – wL – rK But now also look at cost minimization That is choose L and K to minimize costs = wL + rK subject to Y = f(L, K). From this problem derive a cost function C = C(w, r, Y). Minimum cost of producing output Y given input prices w and r. How do we get these minimum costs?

3 Recall the definition of an IsoQuant Shows the relationship between two inputs, L and K, holding output (Y) constant. What would an isoquant look like? If use more L => what would happen to K to keep Y constant? Thus, isoquants are downward sloping and convex (why?) L K Y=Y*

4 Isoquants show a given output, Y*, that the firm wants to produce. How to minimize costs of producing this output? Isocost curve = shows combinations of L and K keeping cost constant. Recall C = total costs = wL + rK or K = C/r – w/rL This is an isocost line. Intercept = C/r Slope = -w/r What does the line look like for C=100 r=10 and w=20?

5 K L Intercept = C/r = 10 Intercept = C/w = 5 Slope = -w/r = -20/10 = -2 Everywhere on isocost curve total cost = 100 Isocost curve is given by K = C/r – w/rL As Costs Increase Move to a higher Isocost

6 Problem is to choose L and K to produce a given output, Y* (on fixed isoquant), so that costs are minimized (on lowest isocost possible.) Where is the point of minimum cost on C 1 ? Tangency point between isocost and isoquant. L K Y=Y* C1C1 C2C2 L* K*

7 Tangency between isocost and isoquant occurs where slopes are equal or Slope of isoquant = technical rate of substitution = - MP L /MP K. Slope of isocost = -w/r Therefore cost minimization requires that: - MP L /MP K = -w/r or - MP L /w = MP K /r Does this look familiar at all? These are the conditions required for long-run profit maximization. Therefore, cost minimization and profit maximization occur simultaneously.

8 Let L* and K* define optimal (cost minimizing) L and K L* = f(Y*, w, r) K* = f(Y*, w, r) These are the conditional or derived factor demand curves. Derived from what? How are profit maximization and cost minimization different? If maximizing profit => must also be minimizing costs. If minimizing costs are you necessarily maximizing profit? No. Why not?

9 Revealed Cost Minimization Similar idea to revealed profit maximization Observe choices in two time periods, t and s, where firm choose L and K to minimize costs => must be true that: (1) w t L t + r t K t ≤ w t L s + r t K s - why? (2) w s L s + r s K s ≤ w s L t + r s K t - why? WACM = Weak Axiom of Cost Minimization To be minimizing costs the costs from actual choices must be ≤ the costs from other possible choices at that time. Follow the same steps to transform (1) and (2) to get: ΔwΔL + ΔrΔK ≤ 0 – implications? If Δr = 0 and Δw > 0 => ΔL ≤ 0 or derived D for labor must be downward sloping. Same is true of the derived D for Kapital.

10 Returns to Scale and Cost Functions Define Average Costs = AC = (C(w, r, Y*))/Y* or: AC = C(Y*)/Y* - (assuming w and r are constant). AC and returns to scale Constant Returns to Scale AC is constant as Y increases Increasing Returns to Scale AC is decreasing as Y increases Decreasing Returns to Scale AC is increasing as Y increases Why? What does the AC and C look like with the three types of returns to scale?

11 Y $ AC → returns ↑ returns ↓ returns C1C1 C2C2 C3C3 Y $ ↑ returns → returns ↓ returns

12 Short-Run Costs L may vary but K is fixed. C = C S (Y, K) with K fixed. Or choose L to min C=wL +rK, again with K fixed. Simpler problem (also assumes w and r are fixed). Short run factor demand functions are given by: Short-run Costs are given by: note that long-run costs = What does this mean?

13 Cost Curves First, examine the Short-Run Cost Curves C SR (y) = C v (y) + F or TC = TVC +TFC So that AC SR (y) = C SR (y) / y = C V (y)/y + F/y Or AC SR (y) = AVC(y) + AFC(y)

14 What do the curves look like? costs are increasing at an increasing rate. Why? C V (y) C(y) F C y

15 Because of the fixed factor k (i.e. as L ↑ more and more => M PL must decline ) Law of diminishing MP What do cost curves like this imply about AC’s? AFC $ y Why? AVC $ y Why? A B

16 C $ y Since AC=AFC+ AVC A & B imply C A is easy; B follows from assumption about MPL in the SR.

17 Now suppose MPL ↑ at first as L increases due to specialization and decreases as L increases past some point => now what does the cost curve look like? $ y AC AVC Why?

18 Marginal Costs MC(y) = Δ C SR (y)/ Δy = Δ C v (y)/ Δ y + Δ F / Δy Total or variable cost curve or rate of change of costs Also note that MC=AVC for 1 st unit of output MC(∆y) = ( C v (Δ y) + F – C v (0) –F) / Δy = C v (Δ y) / Δy = AVC(Δy) Since variable costs = 0 when y=0

19 Recall… (1) AVC may initially fall as y increases (not necessary) but must eventually rise due to fixed factors. (2) AC initially falls due to decreacng AFC but eventually rises de to increased AVC. (3)MC= AVC for 1 st unit produced (4) MC= AVC at min AVC why? (5) MC=AC at min AC why?

20 MC AVC AC MC Y* Area under MC up to Y*= total variable costs of producing y* why?

21 Example C(y) = y 3 + 4 C v (y)= y 3 C f (y)= 4 AVC = y 2 AC=y 2 + 4/y MC=3y 2 MC AVC AC TC TVC

22 Long-Run Costs (1) No fixed factors: K can vary (2)Can think of costs associated with different plant sizes For any given LR output, y, there will be some optimal K or plant size (3)Once K is chosen in the LR, K becomes fixed in the SR Long Run AC is the envelope of SR AC curves Recall: LR Costs or C(y*) C(y*) =C SR (y*, K*(y*)) Why? If not at optimal K in short-run => C(y) < C SR (y, K(y)) – why?

23 Now, what if not at optimal K in SR? i.e. y changes in the SR => C(y*) < C SR (y*, K*(y*) Why? …K is not chosen optimally Relationship between SR and LR AC must be… y* y1 Y 2 y SRAC* SRAC1 SRAC2 LRAC

24 This follows since C(y*) <C SR (y*, K*(y*)) =>ACs (y, K*) > AC(y) since AC (y) = C(y)/y And ACs (y, K*) = Cs(y, K*)/(y) LRAC is the lower envelope of all SRAC curves (only true for continuous plant sizes) NOTE: if only discrete levels of plant sixe => say only three: SRAC1 SRAC2 SRAC3

25 Long-Run Marginal Cost Discrete Plant Sizes LRAC = SRAC until move to new one. LRMC = SRMC until move to new one. =>LRMC =SRMCas long as LRAC=SRAC for 1,2,3, etc… SRAC 1 SRAC2 SRAC3 y

26 Continuous Plant Sizes Same idea is true for LRMC here but continuous $ LRAC LRMC SRAC 1 SRMC 1 y y*


Download ppt "Lecture Notes. Cost Minimization Before looked at maximizing Profits (π) = TR – TC or π =pf(L,K) – wL – rK But now also look at cost minimization That."

Similar presentations


Ads by Google