Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Copenhagen 2012 Comments by Marcus Miller University of Warwick 1 The European Sovereign Debt Crisis: Background and Perspectives What is the Risk of European.

Similar presentations


Presentation on theme: "Copenhagen 2012 Comments by Marcus Miller University of Warwick 1 The European Sovereign Debt Crisis: Background and Perspectives What is the Risk of European."— Presentation transcript:

1 Copenhagen 2012 Comments by Marcus Miller University of Warwick 1 The European Sovereign Debt Crisis: Background and Perspectives What is the Risk of European Sovereign Debt Defaults? Fiscal Space, CDS Spreads and Market Pricing of Risk by J. Aizenman, M. Hutchison and Y. Jinjarak

2 What kind of market, friends, is this? Fundamentally driven; or fancy free? 2

3 AHJ analyse the sovereign debt component of the (largely OTC) CDS market This amounts to $2.5 trillion in 2010, which exceeds the total of US government-issued international debt ($2.2 tr) and US GDP ($1.5 tr)! Regression analysis is used to relate sovereign spreads to fundamentals for 50 countries, over the period 2005-2011 for 3, 5 and 10 year CDS’ with the focus on the SWEAP* group in particular. The fundamentals include two measures of ‘fiscal space’: debt to tax base and deficit to tax base. *South-West Eurozone Periphery 3

4 All-too- brief summary of findings After a fascinatingh and well-documented empirical analysis, the authors conclude that: 1.‘fiscal space is validated as an important determinant of market-based sovereign risk’, i.e. the fiscal fundamentals are statistically significant, but 2.there are large prediction errors in pricing SWEAP risk, with under prediction before the crisis and over prediction during the crisis. Two explanations of these prediction errors are suggested: Market failure (‘excessive pessimism and overreaction’) Expected future fundamentals. 4

5 3 Comments A. FF are treated as exogenous, but -if the deficit includes debt servicing costs- are likely to be endogenous. Is there not a risk of bias? B. Is there not a possibility of Type II error? The Maintained hypothesis is ‘spreads reflect current fiscal fundamentals (FF)’: what of Alternative hypothesis that ‘there are multiple equilibria’, Calvo (1988)? C. Need to add strategic aspects? 1)Games between financial intermediaries. 2)Interaction between markets and government. 5

6 Caveats Definition of Fiscal Fundamentals (debt and deficits) not too clear from paper, in particular Fiscal deficit: is this primary deficit, or does it include costs of debt service? (Note that text treats both fiscal fundamentals as ‘risk increasing’ (p.13); but in regressions it’s the fiscal surplus that is used, hence negative sign.) No explicit account is taken of government action and reaction at national or supranational level. (If one is considering sovereign default, should variables not be included to reflect political economy considerations?). 6

7 7 Error vector SS FF Actual spread αFF SS= ∝FF+ ε If ε positively correlated with fundamentals, OLS estimate of ∝ will be biased upwards. Is there a bias because actual market spreads affect fiscal fundamentals?

8 No default Partial default Full default R E1E1 E0E0 x* g x g+bR b Rb Rb g+αbR b Safe rate Risky rate Endogenous Fiscal Fundamentals: Calvo’s self- fulfilling crisis for solvent sovereign (E 0 -> E 1 ) 8 Government expenditure including cost of debt service at the safe rate R ‘Optimal’ level of tax chosen by govt Market Rate, including sovereign spread Government expenditure including legal costs of default

9 Government Reaction Θ 1 1 1 R Rb Rb 1 1/(1-α) Default : actual and expected Market expectation Partial default Θ1Θ1 Full No ΘeΘe Market and government: Expected and actual default - Calvo revisited 9 [Θ = rate of default]

10 Spreads FF β Good ME Bad - insolvent Maintained hypothesis (Aizenman et al.) Alternative hypothesis - multiple equilibria (Calvo) Maintained and Alternative Hypothesis 10 SS= ∝FF+ ε

11 Under the alternative hypothesis, there is of course the problem of ‘equilibrium selection’. Question: when will the market switch from the safe rate to one which reflects the partial default that it causes? One idea is ‘sun spots’, i.e. exogenous randomness. Another is that the switching reflects mixed strategies in a market game. 11

12 Payoffs : (Buyer, Seller) Probabilities in parentheses (Nash Equilibrium p=2/3, q=1/3 i.e. expected payoff is 1/3 for both players for either action) CDS seller (underwriter) Willing to pay up (q ) Will not pay (1-q) CDS buyer Only insures with ‘interest ‘ (p ) Market works 1, 1 ‘Market failure ’ 0,0 Goes ‘naked’ (1-p) Explosive increase in market 3, -1 Market implosion -1,1 A CDS ‘market game’ with mixed strategy equilibrium 12

13 13 Market works 2/9 ‘Market failure’ 4/9 Explosive increase in market 1/9 Market implosion 2/9 Frequency distribution of outcomes

14 Conclusion The authors are effectively testing the efficiency of the CDS market in measuring risk of sovereign default. The results for 2008-2010 imply that sovereign default risk was over-priced by a factor of 2.5 to 5 times (fundamentals greatly under-predict the actual spreads charged in the market). The authors suggest that market price risk ‘follows waves of contagion’. Are they not verifying Calvo’s model of multiple equilibria? 14

15 Numerical Example of Calvo Model For the case of a country like Italy where the ratio of government debt to GDP is about 100%, we choose the parameters such that the critical value of market rates, above which the government will choose to default, is 7%, and the time consistent equilibrium with default is 20%. This implies α is about ¼ - i.e. You save ¾ by default! Parameters: b=1, g=0.38, R=1.03, α=0.235, c=0.684 For a country like Germany, where the ratio of government debt to GDP is close to the Maastricht criteria of 60%, we assume that the interest rate is 3% (with no default). If so, it turns out that the government will not choose to default until market rates reach 10%; and the time consistent equilibrium with default turns out to be over 30%. 15 Appendix

16 16 b (debt/GDP) 2.31.2 0.38 0.45 0.42 Tax as fraction of GDP 1 0.03 0.07 g g+rb “Italy” “Greece” 1.6 Debt Write Down Current Situation: A schematic outline. Italy on the edge of default. Greece over the edge?

17 What about a country like Greece where debt is 160% of GDP? If the tax take was as for Italy, namely 45% of GDP, then the sustainable level of debt turns out to be much higher, if only interest rates stayed at German levels, but Greece collects a lot less tax than other European countries. If the tax take goes down from 45% to 42% of GDP, it turns out that debt is unsustainable, even at German rates and a write down of about 30% to reduce debt to 120% GDP is needed for sustainability. (See diagram above) 17


Download ppt "Copenhagen 2012 Comments by Marcus Miller University of Warwick 1 The European Sovereign Debt Crisis: Background and Perspectives What is the Risk of European."

Similar presentations


Ads by Google