Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Finding equilibria in large sequential games of imperfect information Andrew Gilpin and Tuomas Sandholm Carnegie Mellon University Computer Science Department.

Similar presentations


Presentation on theme: "Finding equilibria in large sequential games of imperfect information Andrew Gilpin and Tuomas Sandholm Carnegie Mellon University Computer Science Department."— Presentation transcript:

1 Finding equilibria in large sequential games of imperfect information Andrew Gilpin and Tuomas Sandholm Carnegie Mellon University Computer Science Department

2 Motivation: Poker Poker is a wildly popular card game –This year’s World Series of Poker prize pool surpassed $103 million, including $56 million for the World Championship event –ESPN is broadcasting parts of the tournament Poker presents several challenges for AI –Imperfect information –Risk assessment and management –Deception (bluffing, slow-playing) –Counter-deception (calling a bluff)

3 Rhode Island Hold’em poker: The Deal

4 Rhode Island Hold’em poker: Round 1

5 Rhode Island Hold’em poker: Round 2

6 Rhode Island Hold’em poker: Round 3

7 Rhode Island Hold’em poker: Showdown

8 Sneak preview of results: Solving Rhode Island Hold’em poker Rhode Island Hold’em poker invented as a testbed for AI research [Shi & Littman 2001] Game tree has more than 3.1 billion nodes Previously, the best techniques did not scale to games this large Using our algorithm we have computed optimal strategies for this game This is the largest poker game solved to date by over four orders of magnitude

9 Outline of this talk Game-theoretic foundations: Equilibrium Model: Ordered games Abstraction mechanism: Information filters Strategic equivalence: Game isomorphisms Algorithm: GameShrink Solving Rhode Island Hold’em

10 Game Theory In multi-agent systems, an agent’s outcome depends on the actions of the other agents Consequently, an agent’s optimal action depends on the actions of the other agents Game theory provides guidance as to how an agent should act A game-theoretic equilibrium specifies a strategy for each agent such that no agent wishes to deviate –Such an equilibrium always exists [Nash 1950]

11 A simple example 0, 0-1, 11, -1 0, 0-1, 1 1, -10, 0 Rock Paper Scissors Paper 1/3

12 Complexity of computing equilibria Finding a Nash equilibrium is “A most fundamental computational problem whose complexity is wide open [and] together with factoring … the most important concrete open question on the boundary of P today” [Papadimitriou 2001] –Even for games with only two players There are algorithms (requiring exponential-time in the worst-case) for computing Nash equilibria Good news: Two-person zero-sum matrix games can be solved in poly-time using linear programming

13 What about sequential games? Sequential games involve turn-taking, moves of chance, and imperfect information Every sequential game can be converted into a simultaneous-move game –Basic idea: Make one strategy in the simultaneous- move game for every possible action in every possible situation in the sequential game –This approach leads to an exponential blowup in the number of strategies

14 Sequence form representation The sequence form is an alternative representation that is more compact [Koller, Megiddo, von Stengel, Romanovskii] Using the sequence form, two-player zero-sum games with perfect recall can be solved in time polynomial in the size of the game tree –But, Texas Hold’em has 10 18 nodes

15 Our approach Instead of developing an equilibrium-finding algorithm per se, we instead introduce an automated abstraction technique that results in a smaller, equivalent game We prove that a Nash equilibrium in the smaller game corresponds to a Nash equilibrium in the original game Our technique applies to n-player sequential games with observed actions and ordered signals

16 Illustration of our approach Nash equilibrium Original game Abstracted game Abstraction Compute Nash

17 Game with ordered signals (a.k.a. ordered game) 1.Players I = {1,…,n} 2.Stage games G = G 1,…,G r 3.Player label L 4.Game-ending nodes ω 5.Signal alphabet Θ 6.Signal quantities κ = κ 1,…,κ r and γ = γ 1,…,γ r 7.Signal probability distribution p 8.Partial ordering ≥ of subsets of Θ 9.Utility function u (increasing in private signals) I = {1,2} Θ = {2♠,…,A♦} κ = (0,1,1) γ = (1,0,0) UniformHand rank

18 Information filters Observation: We can make games smaller by filtering the information a player receives Instead of observing a specific signal exactly, a player instead observes a filtered set of signals –E.g. receiving the signal {A♠,A♣,A♥,A♦} instead of A♠ Combining an ordered game and a valid information filter yields a filtered ordered game Prop. A filtered ordered game is a finite sequential game with perfect recall –Corollary If the filtered ordered game is two-person zero- sum, we can solve it in poly-time using linear programming

19 Filtered signal trees Every filtered ordered game has a corresponding filtered signal tree –Each edge corresponds to the revelation of some signal –Each path corresponds to the revelation of a set of signals Our algorithms operate directly on the filtered signal tree –We never load the full game representation into memory

20 Filtered signal tree: Example

21 Ordered game isomorphic relation The ordered game isomorphic relation captures the notion of strategic symmetry between nodes We define the relationship recursively: –Two leaves are ordered game isomorphic if the payoffs to all players are the same at each leaf, for all action histories –Two internal nodes are ordered game isomorphic if they are siblings and there is a bijection between their children such that only ordered game isomorphic nodes are matched We can compute this relationship efficiently using dynamic programming and perfect matching computations in a bipartite graph

22 Ordered game isomorphic abstraction transformation This operation transforms an existing information filter into a new filter that merges two ordered game isomorphic nodes The new filter yields a smaller, abstracted game Thm If a strategy profile is a Nash equilibrium in the smaller, abstracted game, then it is a Nash equilibrium in the original game

23 Applying the ordered game isomorphic abstraction transformation

24

25

26 GameShrink: Efficiently computing ordered game isomorphic abstraction transformations Recall: we have a dynamic program for determining if two nodes of the filtered signal tree are ordered game isomorphic Algorithm: Starting from the top of the filtered signal tree, perform the transformation where applicable Approximation algorithm: instead of requiring perfect matching, instead require a matching with a penalty below some threshold

27 GameShrink: Efficiently computing ordered game isomorphic abstraction transformations The Union-Find data structure provides an efficient representation of the information filter –Linear memory and almost linear time Can eliminate certain perfect matching computations by using easy-to-check necessary conditions –Compact histogram databases for storing win/loss frequencies to speed up the checks

28 Solving Rhode Island Hold’em poker GameShrink computes all ordered game isomorphic abstraction transformations in under one second Without abstraction, the linear program has 91,224,226 rows and columns After applying GameShrink, the linear program has only 1,237,238 rows and columns By solving the resulting linear program, we are able to compute optimal min-max strategies for this game –CPLEX Barrier method takes 7 days, 17 hours and 25 GB RAM to solve This is the largest poker game solved to date by over four orders of magnitude

29 Comparison to previous research Rule-based –Limited success in even small poker games Simulation/Learning –Do not take multi-agent aspect into account Game-theoretic –Manual abstraction “Approximating Game-Theoretic Optimal Strategies for Full-scale Poker”, Billings, Burch, Davidson, Holte, Schaeffer, Schauenberg, Szafron, IJCAI-03. Distinguished Paper Award. –Automated abstraction

30 Directions for future work Computing strategies for larger games –Requires approximation of solutions Tournament poker More than two players Other types of abstraction

31 Summary Introduced an automatic method for performing abstractions in a broad class of games Introduced information filters as a technique for working with games with imperfect information Developed an equilibrium-preserving abstraction transformation, along with an efficient algorithm Described a simple extension that yields an approximation algorithm for tackling even larger games Solved the largest poker game to date –Playable on-line at http://www.cs.cmu.edu/~gilpin/gsi.html http://www.cs.cmu.edu/~gilpin/gsi.html Thank you very much for your interest


Download ppt "Finding equilibria in large sequential games of imperfect information Andrew Gilpin and Tuomas Sandholm Carnegie Mellon University Computer Science Department."

Similar presentations


Ads by Google