Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Product Variety and Quality

Similar presentations


Presentation on theme: "Product Variety and Quality"— Presentation transcript:

1 Product Variety and Quality

2 Introduction Most firms sell more than one product
Products are differentiated in different ways horizontally goods of similar quality targeted at consumers of different types how is variety determined? is there too much variety vertically consumers agree on quality differ on willingness to pay for quality how is quality of goods being offered determined?

3 Modeling horizontal differentiation
Address models Consumers have preferences over the characteristics of products Monopolistic competition model Consumers have preferences over goods and a taste for variety

4 Horizontal product differentiation
Suppose that consumers differ in their tastes firm has to decide how best to serve different types of consumer offer products with different characteristics but similar qualities This is horizontal product differentiation firm designs products that appeal to different types of consumer products are of (roughly) similar quality Questions: how many products? of what type? how do we model this problem?

5 A spatial approach to product variety
The spatial model (Hotelling) is useful to consider pricing design variety Has a much richer application as a model of product differentiation “location” can be thought of in space (geography) time (departure times of planes, buses, trains) product characteristics (design and variety) consumers prefer products that are “close” to their preferred types in space, or time or characteristics

6 A Spatial approach to product variety 2
Assume N consumers living equally spaced along Main Street – 1 mile long. Monopolist must decide how best to supply these consumers Consumers buy exactly one unit provided that price plus transport costs is less than V. Consumers incur there-and-back transport costs of t per mile The monopolist operates one shop reasonable to expect that this is located at the center of Main Street

7 Suppose that the monopolist
sets a price of p1 The spatial model Price Price p1 + tx p1 + t.x V V All consumers within distance x1 to the left and right of the shop will by the product t t What determines x1? p1 z = 0 x1 x1 z = 1 1/2 Shop 1 p1 + tx1 = V, so x1 = (V – p1)/t

8 The spatial model 2 Suppose the firm reduces the price to p2? Price
p1 + t.x p1 + t.x V V Then all consumers within distance x2 of the shop will buy from the firm p1 p2 z = 0 x2 x1 x1 x2 z = 1 1/2 Shop 1

9 The spatial model 3 Suppose that all consumers are to be served at price p. The highest price is that charged to the consumers at the ends of the market Their transport costs are t/2 : since they travel ½ mile to the shop So they pay p + t/2 which must be no greater than V. So p = V – t/2. Suppose that marginal costs are c per unit. Suppose also that a shop has set-up costs of F. Then profit is p(N, 1) = N(V – t/2 – c) – F.

10 Monopoly pricing in the spatial model
What if there are two shops? The monopolist will coordinate prices at the two shops With identical costs and symmetric locations, these prices will be equal: p1 = p2 = p Where should they be located? What is the optimal price p*?

11 Location with two shops
Delivered price to consumers at the market center equals their reservation price Suppose that the entire market is to be served Price Price If there are two shops they will be located symmetrically a distance d from the end-points of the market V p(d) The maximum price the firm can charge is determined by the consumers at the center of the market p(d) What determines p(d)? Now raise the price at each shop Start with a low price at each shop d 1/2 1 - d z = 0 z = 1 Shop 1 Shop 2 Suppose that d < 1/4 The shops should be moved inwards

12 Location with two shops 2
Delivered price to consumers at the end-points equals their reservation price The maximum price the firm can charge is now determined by the consumers at the end-points of the market Price Price V p(d) p(d) Now what determines p(d)? Now raise the price at each shop Start with a low price at each shop d 1/2 1 - d z = 0 z = 1 Shop 1 Shop 2 Now suppose that d > 1/4 The shops should be moved outwards

13 Location with two shops 3
It follows that shop 1 should be located at 1/4 and shop 2 at 3/4 Price at each shop is then p* = V - t/4 Price Price V V - t/4 V - t/4 Profit at each shop is given by the shaded area c c z = 0 1/4 1/2 3/4 z = 1 Shop 1 Shop 2 Profit is now p(N, 2) = N(V - t/4 - c) – 2F

14 Profit is now p(N, 3) = N(V - t/6 - c) – 3F
By the same argument they should be located at 1/6, 1/2 and 5/6 What if there are three shops? Three shops Price Price V Price at each shop is now V - t/6 V - t/6 V - t/6 z = 0 1/6 1/2 5/6 z = 1 Shop 1 Shop 2 Shop 3 Profit is now p(N, 3) = N(V - t/6 - c) – 3F

15 Optimal number of shops
A consistent pattern is emerging. Assume that there are n shops. They will be symmetrically located distance 1/n apart. How many shops should there be? We have already considered n = 2 and n = 3. When n = 2 we have p(N, 2) = V - t/4 When n = 3 we have p(N, 3) = V - t/6 It follows that p(N, n) = V - t/2n Aggregate profit is then p(N, n) = N(V - t/2n - c) – nF

16 Optimal number of shops 2
Profit from n shops is p(N, n) = (V - t/2n - c)N - nF and the profit from having n + 1 shops is: p*(N, n+1) = (V - t/2(n + 1)-c)N - (n + 1)F Adding the (n +1)th shop is profitable if p(N,n+1) - p(N,n) > 0 This requires tN/2n - tN/2(n + 1) > F which requires that n(n + 1) < tN/2F.

17 An example Suppose that F = $50,000 , N = 5 million and t = $1
Then tN/2F = 50 For an additional shop to be profitable we need n(n + 1) < 50. This is true for n < 6 There should be no more than seven shops in this case: if n = 6 then adding one more shop is profitable. But if n = 7 then adding another shop is unprofitable.

18 Some intuition What does the condition on n tell us?
Simply, we should expect to find greater product variety when: there are many consumers. set-up costs of increasing product variety are low. consumers have strong preferences over product characteristics and differ in these consumers are unwilling to buy a product if it is not “very close” to their most preferred product

19 Empirical Application: Price Discrimination and Imperfect Competition
Although we have presented price discrimination and product design (versioning) issues in the context of a monopoly, these same tactics also play a role in more competitive settings of imperfect competition Imagine a two-store setting again Assume N customers distributed evenly between the two stores, each with maximum willingness to pay of V . No transport cost—Half of the consumers always buys at nearest store. Other half always buys at cheapest store.

20 Price Discrimination and Imperfect Competition 2
If both stores operated by a monopolist, set price = V. Cannot set it higher of there will be no customers. Setting it lower though gains nothing. What if stores operated by separate firms? Imagine P1 = P2 = V. Store 1 serves N/4 price-sensitive customers and N/4 price-insensitive ones. The same is true for Store 2. If Store 1 cuts its price  below V. It loses N/2 from all current customers It gains N(V - )/4 by stealing all price-sensitive customers from Store 2

21 Price Discrimination and Imperfect Competition 3
MORAL 1: Both firms have a real incentive to cut price. This ultimately proves self-defeating In equilibrium, both still serve N/2 customers but now do so at a price closer to cost. This is especially frustrating in light of the “brand-loyal” or price-insensitive customers Cutting their price does not increase their likelihood of shopping at a particular place. It just loses revenue. MORAL 2: Unlike the monopolist who sets the same price to everyone, these firms have an incentive to discriminate and so continue to charge a high price to loyal consumers while pricing low to others.

22 Price Discrimination and Imperfect Competition 4
The intuition then is that price discrimination may be associated with imperfect competition and become more prominent as markets get more competitive (but still less than perfectly competitive). This idea is tested by Stavins (2001) with airline prices. Restrictions such as a required Saturday night stay-over or an advanced purchase serve as screening mechanism for price-sensitive customers. Hence, restrictions lead to lower ticket price. Stavins (2001) idea is that price reduction associated with flight restrictions will be small in markets that are not very competitive.

23 Price Discrimination and Imperfect Competition 5
Stavins (2001) looks at nearly 6,000 tickets covering 12 different city-pair routes in September, 1995. She finds strong support for the dual hypothesis that: a) passengers flying on a ticket with restrictions pay less; b) price reduction shrinks as concentration rises In highly competitive (low HHI) markets, a Saturday night restriction leads to a $253 price reduction but only a $165 reduction in less competitive ones. In highly competitive (low HHI) markets, an Advance Purchase restriction leads to a $111 price reduction but only a $41 reduction in less competitive ones.

24 Product Quality

25 Monopoly and product quality
Firms can, and do, produce goods of different qualities Quality then is an important strategic variable The choice of product quality determined by its ability to generate profit; attitude of consumers to q uality Consider a monopolist producing a single good what quality should it have? determined by consumer attitudes to quality prefer high to low quality willing to pay more for high quality but this requires that the consumer recognizes quality also some are willing to pay more than others for quality

26 Choosing quality Quality – vertical attributes of a product (ALL consumers agree that a product X is of higher quality than another product Y) Firms choose both quantity and quality Profit maximization MR of an increment of quality is equal to its MC Key problem: asymmetric information

27 Asymmetric information
Lemons problem How would you describe an equilibrium? Why is this a problem? Adverse selection Moral hazard One side of a transaction has an incentive to change the terms of the exchange, unobserved by the other side

28 Asymmetric information: types of goods
Search goods: consumers have sufficient everyday knowledge or can accurately predict quality of a product BEFORE purchase Experience goods: quality can be determined by consumers only AFTER purchase

29 Search goods Why manufacturers and service companies do not provide a moderate quality at a moderate price (why price/quality ratio rare works in real life)? Aim: increase profit by capturing consumer surplus (we assume imperfect competition here) Mechanism: quality discrimination (Highest quality level is chosen solely on grounds of independent profit maximization, but a firm needs preventing switching high-end consumers to low-end products) versioning / damaged goods widening the range of quality offered

30 Experience goods: strategies
Reputation Aim: repeat sales (customer loyalty) Reputation is transferrable across consumers (“word of mouth” as a promotion tool) and across markets (exploiting established reputation in new markets) Commitment warranty (how to use for quality discrimination?) reputation (why restaurants in tourist areas are so bad?) Investment as a form of commitment: what is a signal of quality in this case?

31 Modeling commitment “Pure reputation model” (Shapiro, 1983)
Only new products are of unknown quality in the first period Consumers learn true quality after purchase and inform other potential buyers Decision: investment in reputation in the first period vs. earning a rent from selling high-quality products in all subsequent periods Assume that companies don’t “milk” their reputation “Advertising models” (Nelson, 1970, 1978) Decision: price / advertising expenses combination to prevent entry of low-quality producers Why “burning money” / noninformative advertising exists? (Warning: explanation for new experience goods only)

32 Price and advertising as signals of quality
Higher price – Higher Quality Theory: Yes More advertising – High Quality Theory: it depends (on the cost of information)

33 Empirical testing Caves and Greene (1996)
Source of information: Consumer Reports (ranking products by objective characteristics – use as measures of quality) Method: correlation analysis Findings: rank correlation coefficient for price-quality 0.38 for list prices, 0.27 for transaction prices Is it a strong or weak correlation?

34 Why weak? Price-quality correlation is higher for product categories that include more brands (greater scope for vertical differentiation) Lower for “convenience goods” (heavy advertising and frequent repeat purchase) Weakest for product that can use image advertising to build customer loyalty (horizontal differentiation)

35 Testing Nelson model Conclusion: quality signaling is not a particularly important determinant of advertising in consumer goods (median values of the rank correlations are close to zero) In some product categories correlation in very strong positive, in some – strong negative) Advertising outlays tend to increase with quality for innovative goods (providing information) Advertising is less correlated with quality of convenience goods (horizontal differentiation)

36 Case: health care markets

37 Commodity Bundling and Tie-In Sales

38 Introduction Firms often bundle the goods that they offer
Microsoft bundles Windows and Explorer Office bundles Word, Excel, PowerPoint, Access Bundled package is usually offered at a discount Bundling may increase market power GE merger with Honeywell Tie-in sales ties the sale of one product to the purchase of another Tying may be contractual or technological IBM computer card machines and computer cards Kodak tie service to sales of large-scale photocopiers Tie computer printers and printer cartridges Why? To make money!

39 Willingness to pay for Casablanca Willingness to pay for Godzilla
Bundling: an example How much can be charged for Godzilla? How much can be charged for Casablanca? Two television stations offered two old Hollywood films Casablanca and Son of Godzilla Arbitrage is possible between the stations Willingness to pay is: If the films are sold separately total revenue is $19,000 $7,000 Willingness to pay for Casablanca Willingness to pay for Godzilla $2,500 Station A $8,000 $2,500 Station B $7,000 $3,000

40 Bundling: an example 2 How much can be charged for the package?
Bundling is profitable because it exploits aggregate willingness pay Bundling: an example 2 Now suppose that the two films are bundled and sold as a package If the films are sold as a package total revenue is $20,000 Willingness to pay for Casablanca Willingness to pay for Godzilla Total Willingness to pay Station A $8,000 $2,500 $10,500 Station B $7,000 $3,000 $10,000 $10,000

41 Bundling Extend this example to allow for mixed bundling: offering products in a bundle and separately

42 Mixed bundling What should a firm actually do?
There is no simple answer mixed bundling is generally better than pure bundling but bundling is not always the best strategy Each case needs to be worked out on its merits

43 An Example Four consumers; two products; MC1 = $100, MC2 = $150 A $50
Reservation Price for Good 1 Reservation Price for Good 2 Sum of Reservation Prices Consumer A $50 $450 $500 B $250 $275 $525 $300 $220 $520 C D $450 $50 $500

44 The example 2 Consider simple monopoly pricing Good 1 should be sold
Good 1: Marginal Cost $100 Consider simple monopoly pricing Price Quantity Total revenue Profit $450 1 $450 $350 $300 2 $400 Good 1 should be sold at $250 and good 2 at $450. Total profit is $450 + $300 = $750 $600 $250 $250 3 $750 $450 $50 4 $200 -$200 Good 2: Marginal Cost $150 Price Quantity Total revenue Profit $450 $450 1 $450 $300 $275 2 $550 $200 $220 3 $660 $210 $50 4 $200 -$400

45 The example 3 Now consider pure bundling The highest bundle
Reservation Price for Good 1 Reservation Price for Good 2 Sum of Reservation Prices Consumer The highest bundle price that can be considered is $500 All four consumers will buy the bundle and profit is 4x$ x($150 + $100) = $1,000 A $50 $450 $500 B $250 $275 $525 $300 $220 $520 C D $450 $50 $500

46 The example 4 Now consider mixed bundling All four consumers buy
Take the monopoly prices p1 = $250; p2 = $450 and a bundle price pB = $500 All four consumers buy something and profit is $250x2 + $150x2 = $800 Reservation Price for Good 1 Reservation Price for Good 2 Sum of Reservation Prices Consumer Can the seller improve on this? A $50 $450 $500 $500 B $250 $275 $500 $525 $300 $250 $220 $520 C D $250 $450 $50 $500

47 The example 5 This is actually the best that the firm can do
Try instead the prices p1 = $450; p2 = $450 and a bundle price pB = $520 All four consumers buy and profit is $300 + $270x2 + $350 = $1,190 Reservation Price for Good 1 Reservation Price for Good 2 Sum of Reservation Prices Consumer A $50 $450 $450 $500 B $250 $275 $520 $525 $300 $220 $520 $520 C D $450 $450 $50 $500

48 Bundling again Bundling does not always work
Mixed bundling is always more profitable than pure bundling Mixed bundling is always better than no bundling But pure bundling is not necessarily better than no bundling Requires that there are reasonably large differences in consumer valuations of the goods Bundling is a form of price discrimination May limit competition

49 Tie-in sales What about tie-in sales?
“like” bundling but proportions vary allows the monopolist to make supernormal profits on the tied good different users charged different effective prices depending upon usage facilitates price discrimination by making buyers reveal their demands

50 Tie-in sales 2 Suppose that a firm offers a specialized product – a camera – that uses highly specialized film cartridges Then it has effectively tied the sales of film cartridges to the purchase of the camera this is actually what has happened with computer printers and ink cartridges How should it price the camera and film? suppose also that there are two types of consumer, high-demand and low-demand, with one-thousand of each type high demand P = 16 – Qh; low demand P = 12 - Ql the company does not know which type is which

51 Tie-in sales 3 Film is produced competitively at $2 per picture
so film is priced at $2 per picture Suppose that the company leases its cameras if priced so that all consumers lease then we can ignore production costs of the camera these are fixed at 2000c Now consider the lease terms

52 Tie-in sales: an example 2
So the firm can set a lease charge of $50 to each type of consumer: it cannot discriminate Recall that the film sells at $2 per picture High-Demand Consumers Low-Demand Consumers Profit is $50 from each low-demand and high-demand consumer. Total profit is $100,000 High-demand consumers take 14 pictures Demand: P = 16 - Q Demand: P = 12 - Q $ $ Consumer surplus for high-demand consumers is $98 Consumer surplus for low-demand consumers is $50 $16 $12 Low-demand consumers take 10 pictures $98 $50 $2 $2 14 16 10 12 Quantity Quantity

53 Tie-in sales example 3 This is okay but there may be room for improvement Redesign the camera to tie the camera and the film technological change that makes the camera work only with the firm’s film cartridge Suppose that the firm can produce film at a cost of $2 per picture Implement a tying strategy that makes it impossible to use the camera without this film

54 Tie-in sales: an example 2
Tying increases the firm’s profit $16 16 $12 12 High-Demand Consumers Low-Demand Demand: P = 16 - Q Demand: P = 12 - Q $ Quantity $2 Aggregate profit is now $48,000 + $56,000 = $104,000 Lease the camera at $32. Profit is $32 plus $16 in film profits = $48 Profit is $32 plus $24 in film profits = $56 Each high-demand consumer will lease the camera at $32 Consumer surplus for low-demand consumers is $32 Low-demand consumers take 8 pictures High-demand consumers take 12 pictures $32 $32 $4 $4 $24 $16 12 8

55 Tie-in sales example 3 Why does tying increase profits?
high-demand consumers are offered a quantity discount under both the original and the tied lease arrangement but tying solves the identification and arbitrage problems film exploits its monopoly in film supply high-demand consumers are revealed by their film purchases quantity discount is then used to increase profit arbitrage is not an issue: both types of consumers pay the same lease and the same unit price for film

56 Tie-in sales example 4 Can the firm do even better?
Redesign the camera so that the film cartridge is integral offer two types of integrated camera/film package: high capacity and low capacity what capacities? This is similar to second-degree price discrimination design two cameras with socially efficient capacities: 10 picture and 14 picture lease these as integrated packages

57 Tie-in sales: an example 2
Aggregate profit is now $50,000 + $58,000 = $108,000 $16 16 $12 12 High-Demand Consumers Low-Demand Demand: P = 16 - Q Demand: P = 12 - Q $ Quantity $2 High-demand consumers get $40 consumer surplus by leasing the 10-picure camera Low-demand consumers will pay up to $70 to lease the 10-picure camera So high-demand consumers can be charged $86 to lease the 14-picture camera 10 12 $40 $70 $70 $16 10 14

58 Network externalities
Product complementarities can generate network effects Windows and software applications substantial economies of scale strong network effects leads to an applications barrier to entry new operating system will sell only if applications are written for it but… So product complementarities can lead to monopoly power being extended

59 Anti-trust and bundling
The Microsoft case is central accusation that used power in operating system (OS) to gain control of browser market by bundling browser into the OS need\ to show monopoly power in OS OS and browser are separate products with no need to be bundled abuse of power to maintain or extend monopoly position Microsoft argued that technology required integration further argued that it was not “acting badly” consumers would benefit from lower price because of the complementarity between OS and browser

60 Microsoft and Netscape
Complementarity products so merge? what if Netscape refuses? then Microsoft can develop its own browser MC ≈ 0 so competition in the browser market drives price close to zero but then get the outcome of merger firm through competition So Microsoft is not “acting badly” But JAVA allows applications to be run on Internet browsers Netscape then constitutes a threat need to reduce their market share

61 And now… This view gained more force & support in Europe
bundling of Media Player into Windows Competition Directorate found against Microsoft Microsoft Appealed Microsoft finally lost its appeal in September, 2007 Result: Microsoft ordered to stop bundling and forced to pay fine of €497 (finally settled in October, 2007) Some economists upset by this decision arguing that as price discrimination, bundling often expands the market, AND also that bundling/tying can reflect competition and not just market power

62 Competitive Bundling/Tying
Bundling and tying are very commonly observed phenomena Perhaps too commonly observed to be just the outcome of monopoly power Is there a way to understand competitive bundling? Yes! Salinger and Evans (2005) and Evans (2006) It may well be the case that the structure of demand and the nature of scope and scale economies force competitive firms to bundle tie their goods

63 Competitive Bundling/Tying 2
Consider the table on the next slide and assume consumer willingness to pay is $20 for most preferred option Competitive firm can’t offer pain reliever & decongestant separately, To do so incurs total fixed cost of $600 Marginal cost of $4 Breakeven price = $6 50 by pain relief alone and pay $6 per unit 50 by decongestant alone and pay $6 per unit 100 buy both and pay $12 per combined unit Total Revenue = $1800; Total cost = $600 + $4x150 + $4x150 = $1800 Rival could sell bundled product for $10 and steal all 100 customers interested in joint goods who now pay $12

64 Competitive Bundling/Tying 3
$8.50 is lowest feasible price and is achieve by only offering the bundled product Product Pain Relief Decongestant Bundle Demand 50 100 Costs Fixed Cost $300 Marginal Cost $4 $7 Feasible Prices Separate Goods $6 ----- Pure Bundling ---- $8.50 Mixed Bundling $10 Bundle + Good 1 $9 Bundle + Good 2 Moral: competitive pressure may be the underlying reason for much bundling

65 Antitrust and tying arrangements
Tying arrangements have been the subject of extensive litigation Current policy tie-in violates antitrust laws if there exists distinct products: tying product & tied one firm tying the products has sufficient market power in the tying market to force purchase of the tied good tying arrangement forecloses or has the potential to foreclose a substantial volume of trade As time passes, approach is more and more of a rule-of-reason standard with increasing recognition that whether price discrimination or competitive pressure is the reason, bundling/tying is often welfare-improving


Download ppt "Product Variety and Quality"

Similar presentations


Ads by Google