Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Forward Premium Puzzle: Futures Contracts Evidence and Speculation Strategies Academy of Economic Studies Bucharest Doctoral School of Finance and Banking.

Similar presentations


Presentation on theme: "Forward Premium Puzzle: Futures Contracts Evidence and Speculation Strategies Academy of Economic Studies Bucharest Doctoral School of Finance and Banking."— Presentation transcript:

1 Forward Premium Puzzle: Futures Contracts Evidence and Speculation Strategies Academy of Economic Studies Bucharest Doctoral School of Finance and Banking DOFIN Supervisor: Professor Dr. Moisa Altar MSc Student: ALINA PICIOREA Bucharest, July 2007

2 Contents PART I New evidence from futures contracts (instead of the forward contracts), in support of the forward premium puzzle, and therefore filling the gap at the (multi-) day maturity level Inside and outside regressions PART II Two currency speculation strategies – Carry trade: widely used by practitioners. Sell currencies that are at a forward premium. Buy currencies that are at a forward discount. – BGT Strategy: Use a particular regression to forecast payoff to selling currencies forward: Backus, Gregory, and Telmer (1993) Properties of the speculation payoffs Does risk explain the high Sharpe Ratios? PART I New evidence from futures contracts (instead of the forward contracts), in support of the forward premium puzzle, and therefore filling the gap at the (multi-) day maturity level Inside and outside regressions PART II Two currency speculation strategies – Carry trade: widely used by practitioners. Sell currencies that are at a forward premium. Buy currencies that are at a forward discount. – BGT Strategy: Use a particular regression to forecast payoff to selling currencies forward: Backus, Gregory, and Telmer (1993) Properties of the speculation payoffs Does risk explain the high Sharpe Ratios?

3 Uncovered interest rate parity (UIP) assumes that the expected change in the exchange rate compensates for the interest rate differential or, given that covered interest rate parity holds, equals the forward premium. UIP is a key feature of linearized open-economy models; it reflects the market’s expectations of exchange rate changes and it represents the starting point for any analysis which depends on future exchange rate values. Problem: UIP is overwhelmingly rejected by the data. – `Forward premium-depreciation anomaly‘ is a particularly egregious deviation from UIP – Currencies that are at a forward premium tend to depreciate. Traditional Reponses to this Problem Ignore rejection of UIP and hope that UIP isn’t central to the predictions of the model. Add an UIP `risk premium shock’. Uncovered interest rate parity (UIP) assumes that the expected change in the exchange rate compensates for the interest rate differential or, given that covered interest rate parity holds, equals the forward premium. UIP is a key feature of linearized open-economy models; it reflects the market’s expectations of exchange rate changes and it represents the starting point for any analysis which depends on future exchange rate values. Problem: UIP is overwhelmingly rejected by the data. – `Forward premium-depreciation anomaly‘ is a particularly egregious deviation from UIP – Currencies that are at a forward premium tend to depreciate. Traditional Reponses to this Problem Ignore rejection of UIP and hope that UIP isn’t central to the predictions of the model. Add an UIP `risk premium shock’. Motivation

4 Forward Rate Unbiasedness Hypothesis stipulates that under the joint hypothesis of risk neutrality and rational expectations, the current forward rate is an unbiased predictor of the future spot rate Early investigations of forward rate unbiasedness (e.g. Frenkel, 1976, 1981; and Levich, 1978) relied on: under the null hypothesis α =0 and β=1 The puzzle arises because β<>1. Fama (1984) suggests that the expected change in the exchange rate is often inversely related to the forward premium Following Meese and Singleton’s (1982) evidence that foreign exchange rates are nonstationary, it has been common (e.g. Longworth, 1981; Hodrick, 1987; McCallum, 1994) to test the unbiasedness by estimating: Liu and Maddala (1992) and Barnhart, McNown and Wallace (1999), claims that the conventional Fama regression is invalidated, due to problems of endogeneity, which may result from the appearance of an unobserved risk premium. Forward Rate Unbiasedness Hypothesis stipulates that under the joint hypothesis of risk neutrality and rational expectations, the current forward rate is an unbiased predictor of the future spot rate Early investigations of forward rate unbiasedness (e.g. Frenkel, 1976, 1981; and Levich, 1978) relied on: under the null hypothesis α =0 and β=1 The puzzle arises because β<>1. Fama (1984) suggests that the expected change in the exchange rate is often inversely related to the forward premium Following Meese and Singleton’s (1982) evidence that foreign exchange rates are nonstationary, it has been common (e.g. Longworth, 1981; Hodrick, 1987; McCallum, 1994) to test the unbiasedness by estimating: Liu and Maddala (1992) and Barnhart, McNown and Wallace (1999), claims that the conventional Fama regression is invalidated, due to problems of endogeneity, which may result from the appearance of an unobserved risk premium. Literature Review

5 Conventionally the expectations hypothesis is tested by using forward exchange rates. But, the forward rates come only in maturities of one, two, three, six and twelve months. Thus, one is restricted to using monthly horizons and multiples thereof. Futures contracts have a fixed maturity date, which is e.g. the third Wednesday of a month. Accordingly, the maturity length is determined by the date when the futures contract is traded and the maturity spectrum can be measured in daily units. Thus, futures data embody a much finer set of information. m – time to maturity and run from one day up to three months, that is between 1 and 65 working days. A necessary condition for the comparability of estimation results based on forward contract and futures contracts is that there is no significant difference between forward and futures prices. The general finding (e.g. Cornell and Reinganum, 1981; Polakoff and Grier, 1991; Chang and Chang, 1990 and Hull, 2006) is that the factors that might cause forward and futures prices to differ (e.g. differences in default risk or liquidity premium), can be ignored and that the two prices are the same. Conventionally the expectations hypothesis is tested by using forward exchange rates. But, the forward rates come only in maturities of one, two, three, six and twelve months. Thus, one is restricted to using monthly horizons and multiples thereof. Futures contracts have a fixed maturity date, which is e.g. the third Wednesday of a month. Accordingly, the maturity length is determined by the date when the futures contract is traded and the maturity spectrum can be measured in daily units. Thus, futures data embody a much finer set of information. m – time to maturity and run from one day up to three months, that is between 1 and 65 working days. A necessary condition for the comparability of estimation results based on forward contract and futures contracts is that there is no significant difference between forward and futures prices. The general finding (e.g. Cornell and Reinganum, 1981; Polakoff and Grier, 1991; Chang and Chang, 1990 and Hull, 2006) is that the factors that might cause forward and futures prices to differ (e.g. differences in default risk or liquidity premium), can be ignored and that the two prices are the same. Futures Contracts Evidence

6 s t denote the log of the spot exchange rate at time t f t t−m be the log of the futures exchange rate at time t−m with delivery for time t and maturity m. Following the expectations hypothesis, a futures rate is regarded as an efficient predictor of the spot exchange rate at the maturity date of the futures contract, t. To test this hypothesis, realized spot rates are regressed on futures. If the expectations hypothesis holds, then: with the null hypothesis for efficiency is H 0 : α = 0 and β(m,k) = 1. First we take the lag lenght k=0. Let y t t−m be short notation for the exchange rate innovation s t −s t−m and p t t−m for the forward premium f t t−m −s t−m. Then the conventional expectations hypothesis regression, often denoted as the ‘Fama regression’, is as follows: where the slope coefficient is: s t denote the log of the spot exchange rate at time t f t t−m be the log of the futures exchange rate at time t−m with delivery for time t and maturity m. Following the expectations hypothesis, a futures rate is regarded as an efficient predictor of the spot exchange rate at the maturity date of the futures contract, t. To test this hypothesis, realized spot rates are regressed on futures. If the expectations hypothesis holds, then: with the null hypothesis for efficiency is H 0 : α = 0 and β(m,k) = 1. First we take the lag lenght k=0. Let y t t−m be short notation for the exchange rate innovation s t −s t−m and p t t−m for the forward premium f t t−m −s t−m. Then the conventional expectations hypothesis regression, often denoted as the ‘Fama regression’, is as follows: where the slope coefficient is: The Expectations Hypothesis and Futures Data

7 We observe : 68 different GBP/US$ futures contracts, with delivery between March 1990 and March 2007 38 different EUR/US$ futures contracts, with delivery between June 1998 and March 2007 68 different CHF/US$ futures contracts, with delivery between March 1990 and March 2007 We also pool the data set, which consists of 174 observations into one data set in order to increase the number of observations. Dickey-Fuller tests show that the futures premium and the change of exchange rates satisfy the stationarity condition. We use Seemingly Unrelated Regressions (SUR) to correct for the likely correlation of the error term across currencies. Such a correlation is almost inevitable when using bilateral exchange rates. For example, a strong dollar or a contagious currency crisis in a particular month would likely show up across many of the bilateral dollar exchange rates. We observe : 68 different GBP/US$ futures contracts, with delivery between March 1990 and March 2007 38 different EUR/US$ futures contracts, with delivery between June 1998 and March 2007 68 different CHF/US$ futures contracts, with delivery between March 1990 and March 2007 We also pool the data set, which consists of 174 observations into one data set in order to increase the number of observations. Dickey-Fuller tests show that the futures premium and the change of exchange rates satisfy the stationarity condition. We use Seemingly Unrelated Regressions (SUR) to correct for the likely correlation of the error term across currencies. Such a correlation is almost inevitable when using bilateral exchange rates. For example, a strong dollar or a contagious currency crisis in a particular month would likely show up across many of the bilateral dollar exchange rates. Data

8 The estimates for the slope coefficient β(m,0) and its moving average are plotted with respect to the maturity length m in days. We highlight the slope coefficients for the maturity horizons available for forward exchange rates covered by our observed forecast period, i.e. for m = {22, 43, 65}, by encircling these particular estimates. This highlights the extra information provided by the futures data.  the slope coefficient is decreasing with the length of maturity horizon m  the expectations hypothesis holds for shorter (less than 1 month) but not for longer maturities  we mostly confirm the forward premium puzzle of a negative slope coefficient. The estimates for the slope coefficient β(m,0) and its moving average are plotted with respect to the maturity length m in days. We highlight the slope coefficients for the maturity horizons available for forward exchange rates covered by our observed forecast period, i.e. for m = {22, 43, 65}, by encircling these particular estimates. This highlights the extra information provided by the futures data.  the slope coefficient is decreasing with the length of maturity horizon m  the expectations hypothesis holds for shorter (less than 1 month) but not for longer maturities  we mostly confirm the forward premium puzzle of a negative slope coefficient. Estimates

9 To summarize the information which is in the futures data at the daily level, we fit a line through the slope coefficients when plotted against the maturity horizon in days. The estimated constant is highly significant and positive. The Wald test shows that this constant is not significantly different from the value of one. This suggests that we would indeed not reject the expectations hypothesis for futures rates with a very short maturity.  We confirm that there exists a significant negative relationship between the maturity horizon of the futures contract and the estimated value for β(m,0).  If the time to maturity increases by one (working) day, the estimated slope coefficient decreases by a value of around 0.023  This implies that the futures premium puzzle only shows up for maturity horizons longer than 1 month To summarize the information which is in the futures data at the daily level, we fit a line through the slope coefficients when plotted against the maturity horizon in days. The estimated constant is highly significant and positive. The Wald test shows that this constant is not significantly different from the value of one. This suggests that we would indeed not reject the expectations hypothesis for futures rates with a very short maturity.  We confirm that there exists a significant negative relationship between the maturity horizon of the futures contract and the estimated value for β(m,0).  If the time to maturity increases by one (working) day, the estimated slope coefficient decreases by a value of around 0.023  This implies that the futures premium puzzle only shows up for maturity horizons longer than 1 month Estimates

10 By estimating the ‘outside regression’ (k>0) we investigate, whether the forward rate at time t−m is able to predict the change of exchange rates between the maturity date t and a date that lies k time periods to the past of the pricing date of that forward rate, t−m−k. Thus, the futures market at t−m incorporates the past innovations of the exchange rate. Outside Regressions Thus, the ‘outside regression’ differs from the conventional ‘Fama regression’ (k = 0) in the way that we subtract from both sides of the regression the realized spot exchange rate return between t−m and t−m−k. To the time t − m, when the futures rate is priced, this exchange rate return is already common knowledge. This is the ‘news part’ in the outside regression. Thus, the ‘outside regression’ differs from the conventional ‘Fama regression’ (k = 0) in the way that we subtract from both sides of the regression the realized spot exchange rate return between t−m and t−m−k. To the time t − m, when the futures rate is priced, this exchange rate return is already common knowledge. This is the ‘news part’ in the outside regression. The lag length k can be seen as the ’news advantage’ of the forward rate at t−m relative to the spot rate at t−m−k.

11 The futures data also allow us to do the opposite and move inside the maturity horizon, by taking the lag length k 0 and m>q>0. Inside Regressions This regression generates some interesting information since it asks whether forex returns during the later part of the maturity horizon are moving as predicted by the futures contract signed much earlier. Thus we can potentially deduce whether the futures contract has more to say regarding the earlier or the later day-to-day forex returns over the maturity period.

12 We run regression (1) for m=1,..., 65, k=−65,..., 65 (m+k>0) for each pair and for the pooled data set. Thus, we end up with 65 estimated slope coefficients for every value of k>0 and with m−q slope coefficients for every k=−q, since q<m. We run regression (1) for m=1,..., 65, k=−65,..., 65 (m+k>0) for each pair and for the pooled data set. Thus, we end up with 65 estimated slope coefficients for every value of k>0 and with m−q slope coefficients for every k=−q, since q<m. Outside and Inside Regressions  The slope coefficient rapidly increases towards 1 when the news advantage (k>0) increases. With a news advantage of only three days, the mean of the slope coefficients turns to a significantly positive value and converges to the value of one.  Close to k=0 there is quite a wide range of different slope values  β(m,q) rapidly converges towards zero as q gets larger.  The slope coefficient rapidly increases towards 1 when the news advantage (k>0) increases. With a news advantage of only three days, the mean of the slope coefficients turns to a significantly positive value and converges to the value of one.  Close to k=0 there is quite a wide range of different slope values  β(m,q) rapidly converges towards zero as q gets larger. R-squared is very low for the inside regression (k<0) and becomes substantial, even close to 1 when k rises.

13 β(m,k) is close to unity if the market has a news advantage beyond the horizon of a fortnight >> this cannot be taken as evidence that the forward premium puzzle has disappeared. Looking Forward in the ‘Outside’.. while (constant volatility) and (weak form efficiency assumption holds if the exchange rate innovations and premium from non-overlapping time intervals are uncorrelated)  When the lag length k>>, β(m,k)  1  But, this is not incompatible with β(m,0)<0, so that the premium puzzle is still present in the background. while (constant volatility) and (weak form efficiency assumption holds if the exchange rate innovations and premium from non-overlapping time intervals are uncorrelated)  When the lag length k>>, β(m,k)  1  But, this is not incompatible with β(m,0)<0, so that the premium puzzle is still present in the background.

14 Looking Forward in the ‘Inside’..  When q>>, β(m,k)  0  As is the case for the outside regression, this effect depends on the magnitude of the news dominance feature  the extra term in the numerator and denominator shows that for small values of q this slope estimate provides extra information  When q>>, β(m,k)  0  As is the case for the outside regression, this effect depends on the magnitude of the news dominance feature  the extra term in the numerator and denominator shows that for small values of q this slope estimate provides extra information

15  Our estimation results confirm negative slope coefficients when testing the expectations hypothesis for maturity horizons usually covered by forward exchange rate contracts at the monthly frequency.  However, we find that there exists a significant negative relationship between the slope coefficients and the maturity horizon of the futures contracts.  If the time to maturity m is small, the rejection of the expectations hypothesis is less decisive and slope coefficients hover around the predicted value of one.  For very long maturities the evidence reported in other research is also in line with the expectations hypothesis. Thus it appears that the market in the beginning follows the predictions of the expectations hypothesis, but reverses itself, only to come back to this once again after a period of years. This leads us to conclude that the typical form of the premium correlation when plotted against the maturity horizon is V-shaped.  Our estimation results confirm negative slope coefficients when testing the expectations hypothesis for maturity horizons usually covered by forward exchange rate contracts at the monthly frequency.  However, we find that there exists a significant negative relationship between the slope coefficients and the maturity horizon of the futures contracts.  If the time to maturity m is small, the rejection of the expectations hypothesis is less decisive and slope coefficients hover around the predicted value of one.  For very long maturities the evidence reported in other research is also in line with the expectations hypothesis. Thus it appears that the market in the beginning follows the predictions of the expectations hypothesis, but reverses itself, only to come back to this once again after a period of years. This leads us to conclude that the typical form of the premium correlation when plotted against the maturity horizon is V-shaped. UIP Testing - Conclusion

16 Since our objective in this paper is not to explain the failure of UIP, we proceed next with measuring the economic significance of this failure. Our metric for significance is the amount of money that can be made by exploiting deviations from UIP DATA Bid and ask interbank spot exchange rate (S t ) and 1-month forward exchange rate (F t ) for: - Developed economies: GBPUSD, EURUSD, USDCHF, USDJPY (smpl Sept 1990-May 2007) - Emerging economies: USDPLN, USDHUF, USDRON (smpl Jul 1996-May 2007) All quotes are in FCY/US Dollar. Frequency: Daily converted into non-overlapping monthly observations by sampling in the second working day of every month (to exclude the possibility of creating a moving average error process) Source: Reuters, Ecowin The quotes are indicative quotes for small trade sizes. Since our objective in this paper is not to explain the failure of UIP, we proceed next with measuring the economic significance of this failure. Our metric for significance is the amount of money that can be made by exploiting deviations from UIP DATA Bid and ask interbank spot exchange rate (S t ) and 1-month forward exchange rate (F t ) for: - Developed economies: GBPUSD, EURUSD, USDCHF, USDJPY (smpl Sept 1990-May 2007) - Emerging economies: USDPLN, USDHUF, USDRON (smpl Jul 1996-May 2007) All quotes are in FCY/US Dollar. Frequency: Daily converted into non-overlapping monthly observations by sampling in the second working day of every month (to exclude the possibility of creating a moving average error process) Source: Reuters, Ecowin The quotes are indicative quotes for small trade sizes. Currency Speculation Strategies

17 Statistical Tests of UIP We test Fama regression in prices terms (not log): For developed countries and Romania, β < 0. For Poland and Hungary, there is evidence that investors find it easier to forecast the direction of movement of these currencies We test Fama regression in prices terms (not log): For developed countries and Romania, β < 0. For Poland and Hungary, there is evidence that investors find it easier to forecast the direction of movement of these currencies

18 Two Currency Speculation Strategies 1. Carry Trade – Sell forward currencies that are at a forward premium and buy currencies that are at a forward discount. β<<0 suggests: – Sell dollars forward when Ft>St. x-no of $ sold fwd – Buy dollars forward when Ft<St. This strategy is equivalent to: – Borrow low interest rate currency; y-no of $ borrowed – Lend high interest rate currency; – Do not hedge the exchange rate risk. This strategy is also equivalent to using the current spot to forecast the future exchange rate. 2. BGT Strategy – Suggested by Backus, Gregory and Telmer (1993) – Use the above regression to predict the returns to selling currency forward 1. Carry Trade – Sell forward currencies that are at a forward premium and buy currencies that are at a forward discount. β<<0 suggests: – Sell dollars forward when Ft>St. x-no of $ sold fwd – Buy dollars forward when Ft<St. This strategy is equivalent to: – Borrow low interest rate currency; y-no of $ borrowed – Lend high interest rate currency; – Do not hedge the exchange rate risk. This strategy is also equivalent to using the current spot to forecast the future exchange rate. 2. BGT Strategy – Suggested by Backus, Gregory and Telmer (1993) – Use the above regression to predict the returns to selling currency forward

19 Carry Trade Carry Trade without Bid-Ask Spreads Agents follow the rule: Sell 1 Dollar forward when the Dollar is at a forward premium, F t >S t, and obtain the payoff: Carry Trade with Bid-Ask Spreads Agents adopt the decision rule: and obtain the payoff: Symbol Definition Applies to S a /F a Spot/Fwd Ask Foreign Currency/Dollar Exchange Rate Buying Dollars spot/forward S b /F b Spot/Fwd Bid Foreign Currency/Dollar Exchange Rate Selling Dollars spot/forward Carry Trade without Bid-Ask Spreads Agents follow the rule: Sell 1 Dollar forward when the Dollar is at a forward premium, F t >S t, and obtain the payoff: Carry Trade with Bid-Ask Spreads Agents adopt the decision rule: and obtain the payoff: Symbol Definition Applies to S a /F a Spot/Fwd Ask Foreign Currency/Dollar Exchange Rate Buying Dollars spot/forward S b /F b Spot/Fwd Bid Foreign Currency/Dollar Exchange Rate Selling Dollars spot/forward

20 BGT Strategy Use the BGT regression to forecast the excess returns from selling dollars forward, F t -S t+1 : Sell dollars forward when: Buy dollars forward when: where â t and b̂ t are the time t recursive estimates of a and b. Equivalence Suppose 1/S̄ t is a martingale. Then BGT regression is roughly equivalent to: Can re-arrange this equation to show that a=- α and b=1-β in standard UIP regression. >> β close to 2 implies b close to 3. Use the BGT regression to forecast the excess returns from selling dollars forward, F t -S t+1 : Sell dollars forward when: Buy dollars forward when: where â t and b̂ t are the time t recursive estimates of a and b. Equivalence Suppose 1/S̄ t is a martingale. Then BGT regression is roughly equivalent to: Can re-arrange this equation to show that a=- α and b=1-β in standard UIP regression. >> β close to 2 implies b close to 3.

21 Currency Speculation and Exchange Rate Forecasts Both currency speculation strategies rely implicitly on forecasts of future exchange rates. Carry trade (‘random walk’ forecasts): BGT: Both currency speculation strategies rely implicitly on forecasts of future exchange rates. Carry trade (‘random walk’ forecasts): BGT:

22 Returns to the Carry Trade Strategies We use Sharpe Ratio as a measurement of the return-risk ratio. There are large diversification gains from combining country strategies The Sharpe Ratios are considerably higher for the strategies in the emerging markets compared to the ones in the developed economies We use Sharpe Ratio as a measurement of the return-risk ratio. There are large diversification gains from combining country strategies The Sharpe Ratios are considerably higher for the strategies in the emerging markets compared to the ones in the developed economies

23 Returns to the BGT Strategies The BGT strategy yields smaller returns than the Carry Trade for the equally-weighted portfolio, but greater returns in the individual cases. There are some diversification gains from combining country strategies, but mostly close to the average. Romania yields again the highest Sharpe Ratio The BGT strategy yields smaller returns than the Carry Trade for the equally-weighted portfolio, but greater returns in the individual cases. There are some diversification gains from combining country strategies, but mostly close to the average. Romania yields again the highest Sharpe Ratio

24 Bid-Ask Spreads Have Large Impact on Excess Returns Bid-ask spreads have a sizable impact on the profitability of currency speculation Bid-ask spreads are smaller in developed countries than in emerging ones – If agent buys and sells one pound against the U.S. dollar in the spot market he loses on average S b -S a =0.0008 dollars. Bid-ask spreads have a sizable impact on the profitability of currency speculation Bid-ask spreads are smaller in developed countries than in emerging ones – If agent buys and sells one pound against the U.S. dollar in the spot market he loses on average S b -S a =0.0008 dollars. Since the spreads are of the same order of magnitude as the expected payoff associated with our two currency-speculation strategies, in the remainder of this presentation, we only consider strategies and payoffs that take bid-ask spreads into account

25 Realized Returns to Currency Speculation BGT strategies yields higher returns than the Carry Trades. Even though Sharpe ratios including transactions costs are high, the average payoffs to currency-speculation strategies are rather low. So to generate substantial profits speculators must wager very large sums of money. BGT strategies yields higher returns than the Carry Trades. Even though Sharpe ratios including transactions costs are high, the average payoffs to currency-speculation strategies are rather low. So to generate substantial profits speculators must wager very large sums of money.

26 Realized Returns to Currency Speculation We use the realized payoffs to compute the cumulative realized return measured in U.S. dollars to committing one dollar in the beginning of the sample to various currency-speculation strategies and reinvesting the proceeds at each point in time. The agent starts with one U.S. dollar in his bank account and bets that dollar in the currency strategy. From that point forward the agent bets the balance of his bank account on the currency strategy. Currency strategy payoffs are deposited or withdrawn from the agent’s account. Since the currency strategy is a zero-cost investment, the agent’s net balances stay in the bank and accumulate interest at the bid Libor rate published by the Federal Reserve. It turns out that the bank account balance never becomes negative in our sample. This result reflects the fact that strategy payoffs are small in absolute value. For Romania, the stock market’s index BET out-performs all strategies (BET SR=0.4863) We use the realized payoffs to compute the cumulative realized return measured in U.S. dollars to committing one dollar in the beginning of the sample to various currency-speculation strategies and reinvesting the proceeds at each point in time. The agent starts with one U.S. dollar in his bank account and bets that dollar in the currency strategy. From that point forward the agent bets the balance of his bank account on the currency strategy. Currency strategy payoffs are deposited or withdrawn from the agent’s account. Since the currency strategy is a zero-cost investment, the agent’s net balances stay in the bank and accumulate interest at the bid Libor rate published by the Federal Reserve. It turns out that the bank account balance never becomes negative in our sample. This result reflects the fact that strategy payoffs are small in absolute value. For Romania, the stock market’s index BET out-performs all strategies (BET SR=0.4863)

27 Why is the Sharpe Ratio so high? Risk Fat tails Price pressure (Burnside, 2006) Are Excess Returns Correlated with Risk Factors? We regress the payoffs on several risk factors and on macro variables (monetary policy can generate time- varying risk premium). Fama-French factors, consumption growth and M1 growth enter significantly into Carry Trade returns regression. Risk Fat tails Price pressure (Burnside, 2006) Are Excess Returns Correlated with Risk Factors? We regress the payoffs on several risk factors and on macro variables (monetary policy can generate time- varying risk premium). Fama-French factors, consumption growth and M1 growth enter significantly into Carry Trade returns regression.

28 …and in the case of RON?  inflation and NBR’s key policy rate entering significantly and with a positive sign in the carry- trade payoffs regression, but not the same for the BGT Strategy How might a tightening in monetary policy influence Carry Trades returns?  it leads to an immediate rise in short-term interest rates, and therefore to a widening interest- rate spreads  leads to an immediate appreciation of the high-yield market's currency  it leads to a decline in actual and expected inflation  the ccy's value gains further (a decline in inflation expectations boost the real return on assets)  it leads to a to more stable domestic GDP growth, investors should gradually demand less compensation in the form of a risk premium  inflation and NBR’s key policy rate entering significantly and with a positive sign in the carry- trade payoffs regression, but not the same for the BGT Strategy How might a tightening in monetary policy influence Carry Trades returns?  it leads to an immediate rise in short-term interest rates, and therefore to a widening interest- rate spreads  leads to an immediate appreciation of the high-yield market's currency  it leads to a decline in actual and expected inflation  the ccy's value gains further (a decline in inflation expectations boost the real return on assets)  it leads to a to more stable domestic GDP growth, investors should gradually demand less compensation in the form of a risk premium

29 Fat Tails Payoffs to speculation in individual currencies have fat tails (except BGT for USDCHF, USDEUR and USDHUF). These fat tails are reduced once currencies are combined into equally- weighted portfolio (for the Carry trade we cannot reject the normal distribution hypothesis). Fat Tails Payoffs to speculation in individual currencies have fat tails (except BGT for USDCHF, USDEUR and USDHUF). These fat tails are reduced once currencies are combined into equally- weighted portfolio (for the Carry trade we cannot reject the normal distribution hypothesis).

30 Conclusions We bring new evidence in support of the forward premium puzzle by using the futures contracts instead of the forward ones and then we quantify the economical significance of UIP failure Our results confirm negative slope coefficients when testing the expectations hypothesis for standard maturity horizons. We find a significant negative relationship between the slope coefficients and the maturity horizon of the futures contracts. If the time to maturity m is small, the rejection of the expectations hypothesis is less decisive and slope coefficients hover around the predicted value of one. We figured that the typical form of the premium correlation when plotted against the maturity horizon is V-shaped. We document that appropriate currency-speculation strategies, like Carry trades and BGT generate very large Sharpe ratios. In addition, the excess returns to these strategies are uncorrelated with standard risk factors. While the statistical failure of UIP is very sharp, the amount of money that can be made from this failure with our currency-speculation strategies seems relatively small Why don’t agents massively invest in these strategies and eliminate the high Sharpe ratios? We bring new evidence in support of the forward premium puzzle by using the futures contracts instead of the forward ones and then we quantify the economical significance of UIP failure Our results confirm negative slope coefficients when testing the expectations hypothesis for standard maturity horizons. We find a significant negative relationship between the slope coefficients and the maturity horizon of the futures contracts. If the time to maturity m is small, the rejection of the expectations hypothesis is less decisive and slope coefficients hover around the predicted value of one. We figured that the typical form of the premium correlation when plotted against the maturity horizon is V-shaped. We document that appropriate currency-speculation strategies, like Carry trades and BGT generate very large Sharpe ratios. In addition, the excess returns to these strategies are uncorrelated with standard risk factors. While the statistical failure of UIP is very sharp, the amount of money that can be made from this failure with our currency-speculation strategies seems relatively small Why don’t agents massively invest in these strategies and eliminate the high Sharpe ratios?

31 References [1]Alexius, A.(2001). ”Uncovered Interest Parity Revisited”, Review of International Economics 9, 505-517. [2]Baillie, R.T. and Bollerslev, T. (1989). ”Common Stochastic Trends in a System of Exchange Rates”, Journal of Finance 44, 167- 181. [3]Baillie, R.T. and Bollerslev, T. (2000). ”The Forward Premium Anomaly is not as bad as you think”, Journal of International Money and Finance 19, 471-488. [4]Bekaert, G. and Hodrick, R.J. (1993). ”On Biases in the Measurement of Foreign Exchange Risk Premiums”, Journal of International Money and Finance 12, 115-138. [5]Bilson, J.F.O. (1981). ”The ’Speculative Efficiency’ Hypothesis”, Journal of Business 54, 435-451. [6]Burnside, Craig, Martin Eichenbaum, Isaac Kleshchelski, and Sergio Rebelo. (2006) “The Returns to Currency Speculation in Emerging Markets”,.National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 12489. [7]Burnside, Craig, Martin Eichenbaum and Sergio Rebelo (2006a) “Currency Speculation: The Gains from Diversification,” mimeo, Northwestern University. [8]Burnside, Craig, Martin Eichenbaum and Sergio Rebelo (2006b) “Understanding the Forward Premium Puzzle: A Microstructure Approach,” mimeo, Northwestern University. [9]Chaboud, A.P. and Wright, J.H. (2005). ”Uncovered Interest Parity, it works, but not for long”, Journal of International Economics 66(2), 349-362. [10]Chang, C.W. and J.S.K. (1990). ”Forward and future prices: Evidence from the foreign exchange markets”, Journal of Finance 45, 1333-35. [11]Chinn, M.D. (2006). ”The (partial) Rehabilitation of the Interest Parity in the Floating Rate Era: Longer Horizons, Alternative Expectations, and Emerging Markets”, Journal of International Money and Finance 25, 7-21. [12]Chinn, D.C. and Meredith, G. (2004). ”Monetary Policy and Long Horizon Uncovered Interest Parity”, IMF Staff Papers 51(3), 409-430. [13]Clarida, R.H. and Taylor, M.P. (1997). ”The Term Structure of Forward Exchange Premiums and the Forecastability of Spot Exchange Rates: Correcting the Errors”, The Review of Economics and Statistics 79, 353-361. [14]Engel, C. (1996). ”The Forward Discount Anomaly and the Risk Premium: A Survey of Recent Evidence”, Journal of Empirical Finance 3, 123-192. [15]Evans, M.D.D. and Lewis, K. (1995). ”Do Long-Term Swings in the Dollar Affect Estimates of the Risk Premium?”, The Review of Financial Studies 8, 709-742. [16]Fama, E. (1970). ”Efficient Capital Markets: A Review of Theory and Empirical Work”, Journal of Finance 25, 383-417. [1]Alexius, A.(2001). ”Uncovered Interest Parity Revisited”, Review of International Economics 9, 505-517. [2]Baillie, R.T. and Bollerslev, T. (1989). ”Common Stochastic Trends in a System of Exchange Rates”, Journal of Finance 44, 167- 181. [3]Baillie, R.T. and Bollerslev, T. (2000). ”The Forward Premium Anomaly is not as bad as you think”, Journal of International Money and Finance 19, 471-488. [4]Bekaert, G. and Hodrick, R.J. (1993). ”On Biases in the Measurement of Foreign Exchange Risk Premiums”, Journal of International Money and Finance 12, 115-138. [5]Bilson, J.F.O. (1981). ”The ’Speculative Efficiency’ Hypothesis”, Journal of Business 54, 435-451. [6]Burnside, Craig, Martin Eichenbaum, Isaac Kleshchelski, and Sergio Rebelo. (2006) “The Returns to Currency Speculation in Emerging Markets”,.National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 12489. [7]Burnside, Craig, Martin Eichenbaum and Sergio Rebelo (2006a) “Currency Speculation: The Gains from Diversification,” mimeo, Northwestern University. [8]Burnside, Craig, Martin Eichenbaum and Sergio Rebelo (2006b) “Understanding the Forward Premium Puzzle: A Microstructure Approach,” mimeo, Northwestern University. [9]Chaboud, A.P. and Wright, J.H. (2005). ”Uncovered Interest Parity, it works, but not for long”, Journal of International Economics 66(2), 349-362. [10]Chang, C.W. and J.S.K. (1990). ”Forward and future prices: Evidence from the foreign exchange markets”, Journal of Finance 45, 1333-35. [11]Chinn, M.D. (2006). ”The (partial) Rehabilitation of the Interest Parity in the Floating Rate Era: Longer Horizons, Alternative Expectations, and Emerging Markets”, Journal of International Money and Finance 25, 7-21. [12]Chinn, D.C. and Meredith, G. (2004). ”Monetary Policy and Long Horizon Uncovered Interest Parity”, IMF Staff Papers 51(3), 409-430. [13]Clarida, R.H. and Taylor, M.P. (1997). ”The Term Structure of Forward Exchange Premiums and the Forecastability of Spot Exchange Rates: Correcting the Errors”, The Review of Economics and Statistics 79, 353-361. [14]Engel, C. (1996). ”The Forward Discount Anomaly and the Risk Premium: A Survey of Recent Evidence”, Journal of Empirical Finance 3, 123-192. [15]Evans, M.D.D. and Lewis, K. (1995). ”Do Long-Term Swings in the Dollar Affect Estimates of the Risk Premium?”, The Review of Financial Studies 8, 709-742. [16]Fama, E. (1970). ”Efficient Capital Markets: A Review of Theory and Empirical Work”, Journal of Finance 25, 383-417.

32 References [17]Fama, F.E. (1984). ”Forward and Spot Exchange Rates”, Journal of Monetary Economics 14, 319-338. [18]Fama, F.E. (2006). ”The Behavior of Interest Rates”, Review of Financial Studies 19, 359-379. [19]Fama, F.E. and Bliss, R.R. (1987). ”The Information in Long-Maturity Forward Rates”, American Economic Review 77, 680-92. [20]Frankel, J., Chinn, M. (1993). ”Exchange Rate Expectations and the Risk Premium: Test for a Cross Section of 17 Currencies”, Review of International Economics 1, 136-144. [21]Frenkel, J.A. (1977). ”The Forward Exchange Rate, Expectations and the Demand for Money: the German Hyperinflation”, American Economic Review 67, 653-670. [22]Froot, K.A. and Frankel, A. (1989). ”Forward Discount Bias: Is it an Exchange Risk Premium?”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics 104, 139-161. [23]Froot, K.A. and Frankel, A. (1990). ”Anomalies: Foreign Exchange”, Journal of Economic Perspectives 4, 179-92. [24]Hodrick, R.J. and Srivastava, S. (1986). ”The Covariation of Risk Premiums and Expected Future Spot Exchange Rates”, Journal of International Finance 5, 5-21. [25]Hsieh, D.A. (1984). ”Tests of Rational Expectations and no Risk Premium in Forward Exchange Markets”, Journal of International Economics 17, 173-84. [28]Hull, J. C. (2006). Options, Futures, and other Derivatives. Pearson Prentice Hall. [29]Lewis, K.K. (1995). ”Puzzles in International Financial Markets”, in Handbook of International Economics, Vol.III, edited by G. Grossman and K. Rogoff, 1913- 1971. [30]Mark, N.C. (1985). ”On Time Varying Risk Premia in the Foreig Exchange Market”, Journal of Monetary Economics 16, 3-18. [31]Mark, N.C., Wu, Y. and Hai, W. (1997). ”Understanding Spot and Forward Exchange Rate Regressions”, Journal of Applied Econometrics 12, 715-734. [32]Mark, N.C., Wu, Y. (1998). ”Rethinking Deviations from Uncovered Interest Parity: The Role of Covariance Risk and Noise”, The Economic Journal 108. [33]McCallum, B.T. (1994). ”A Reconsideration of the Uncovered Interest Parity Relationship”, Journal of Monetary Economics 33, 105-132. [34]Meese, R. A. and K. Rogoff (1983). ”Empirical exchange rate models of the seventies: Do they fit out-of-sample?”, Journal of International Economics 14, 324. [35]Meese, R., Singleton, K.J. (1982). ”On Unit Roots and the Empirical Modeling of Exchange Rates”, Journal of Finance 37, 1029- 1035. [36]Pope, P.F. and Peel, D. (1991). ”Forward Foreign Exchange Rates and Risk Premia-A Reappraisal”, Journal of International Money and Finance 10, 443-456. [17]Fama, F.E. (1984). ”Forward and Spot Exchange Rates”, Journal of Monetary Economics 14, 319-338. [18]Fama, F.E. (2006). ”The Behavior of Interest Rates”, Review of Financial Studies 19, 359-379. [19]Fama, F.E. and Bliss, R.R. (1987). ”The Information in Long-Maturity Forward Rates”, American Economic Review 77, 680-92. [20]Frankel, J., Chinn, M. (1993). ”Exchange Rate Expectations and the Risk Premium: Test for a Cross Section of 17 Currencies”, Review of International Economics 1, 136-144. [21]Frenkel, J.A. (1977). ”The Forward Exchange Rate, Expectations and the Demand for Money: the German Hyperinflation”, American Economic Review 67, 653-670. [22]Froot, K.A. and Frankel, A. (1989). ”Forward Discount Bias: Is it an Exchange Risk Premium?”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics 104, 139-161. [23]Froot, K.A. and Frankel, A. (1990). ”Anomalies: Foreign Exchange”, Journal of Economic Perspectives 4, 179-92. [24]Hodrick, R.J. and Srivastava, S. (1986). ”The Covariation of Risk Premiums and Expected Future Spot Exchange Rates”, Journal of International Finance 5, 5-21. [25]Hsieh, D.A. (1984). ”Tests of Rational Expectations and no Risk Premium in Forward Exchange Markets”, Journal of International Economics 17, 173-84. [28]Hull, J. C. (2006). Options, Futures, and other Derivatives. Pearson Prentice Hall. [29]Lewis, K.K. (1995). ”Puzzles in International Financial Markets”, in Handbook of International Economics, Vol.III, edited by G. Grossman and K. Rogoff, 1913- 1971. [30]Mark, N.C. (1985). ”On Time Varying Risk Premia in the Foreig Exchange Market”, Journal of Monetary Economics 16, 3-18. [31]Mark, N.C., Wu, Y. and Hai, W. (1997). ”Understanding Spot and Forward Exchange Rate Regressions”, Journal of Applied Econometrics 12, 715-734. [32]Mark, N.C., Wu, Y. (1998). ”Rethinking Deviations from Uncovered Interest Parity: The Role of Covariance Risk and Noise”, The Economic Journal 108. [33]McCallum, B.T. (1994). ”A Reconsideration of the Uncovered Interest Parity Relationship”, Journal of Monetary Economics 33, 105-132. [34]Meese, R. A. and K. Rogoff (1983). ”Empirical exchange rate models of the seventies: Do they fit out-of-sample?”, Journal of International Economics 14, 324. [35]Meese, R., Singleton, K.J. (1982). ”On Unit Roots and the Empirical Modeling of Exchange Rates”, Journal of Finance 37, 1029- 1035. [36]Pope, P.F. and Peel, D. (1991). ”Forward Foreign Exchange Rates and Risk Premia-A Reappraisal”, Journal of International Money and Finance 10, 443-456.

33 We use the Sharpe ratio as a statistic which aims to sum up the desirability of our risky investment strategies by dividing the average period excess return by the standard deviation of the return generating process Formulated in 1966 by Nobel Laureate Bill Sharpe to measure risk-adjusted performance for mutual funds, it undoubtedly has some value as a measure of strategy “quality”, but it also has several crucial limitations:  while return is a definite and an “observable” quantity, risk is not. Standard deviation can be calculated from any time series of return data, but its “meaning” will not be the same for all time series. In order to be a meaningful statistic at all the return time series must be generated from a process that is both stationary and parametric.  SR can have some perverse attributes  the standard deviation takes into account the distance of each return from the mean, positive or negative  large positive returns increase the perception of risk and are penalized  An improvement would be considering only the negative semi-standard deviation  a measure known as the Sortino ratio (Frank A. Sortino)  differentiate between harmful volatility from volatility in general and shows how much down-side risk is taken to earn the returns. We use the Sharpe ratio as a statistic which aims to sum up the desirability of our risky investment strategies by dividing the average period excess return by the standard deviation of the return generating process Formulated in 1966 by Nobel Laureate Bill Sharpe to measure risk-adjusted performance for mutual funds, it undoubtedly has some value as a measure of strategy “quality”, but it also has several crucial limitations:  while return is a definite and an “observable” quantity, risk is not. Standard deviation can be calculated from any time series of return data, but its “meaning” will not be the same for all time series. In order to be a meaningful statistic at all the return time series must be generated from a process that is both stationary and parametric.  SR can have some perverse attributes  the standard deviation takes into account the distance of each return from the mean, positive or negative  large positive returns increase the perception of risk and are penalized  An improvement would be considering only the negative semi-standard deviation  a measure known as the Sortino ratio (Frank A. Sortino)  differentiate between harmful volatility from volatility in general and shows how much down-side risk is taken to earn the returns. Appendix: Sharpe Ratio


Download ppt "Forward Premium Puzzle: Futures Contracts Evidence and Speculation Strategies Academy of Economic Studies Bucharest Doctoral School of Finance and Banking."

Similar presentations


Ads by Google