Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Presentation is loading. Please wait.

In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:

Similar presentations


Presentation on theme: "In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:"— Presentation transcript:

0 Interdependence and the Gains from Trade
3 Interdependence and the Gains from Trade Economics P R I N C I P L E S O F N. Gregory Mankiw Please ask your students in advance to bring calculators to class. This PowerPoint chapter includes simple in-class exercises which lead students to see for themselves the gains from trade arising from comparative advantage. This PowerPoint chapter covers the same topics as Chapter 3 in the textbook (comparative & absolute advantage, the gains from trade), but using a different example and a different approach that is likely to benefit your students. The textbook presents these topics using an example involving two individual producers (the farmer & rancher). After the example, the textbook states that its lessons apply to countries as well as individual producers. This PowerPoint presentation takes the opposite approach, illustrating the concepts with an example involving two countries, and then states that that the lessons apply to individuals as well as countries. Seeing the analysis both ways, and seeing a different example in class than in the textbook, will help students better learn these concepts. The example in this PowerPoint chapter builds on the PPF example introduced in the Chapter 2 PowerPoint. (It is not essential to cover the Chapter 2 PowerPoint before this one, though.) This PowerPoint omits “Should Tiger Woods Mow His Own Lawn?” It’s a great example of comparative advantage, but it does not introduce any new concepts, and students can easily understand it on their own. Premium PowerPoint Slides by Ron Cronovich

1 In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:
Why do people – and nations – choose to be economically interdependent?왜 사람들-그리고 나라들-은 경제적으로 상호의존적이게 되나? How can trade make everyone better off?어떻게 무역은 모든 사람들을 더 좋게 만들 수 있나? What is absolute advantage? 절대우위란? What is comparative advantage? 비교우위란? How are these concepts similar? 어떻게 유사하고 How are they different? 어떻게 다른가? 1

2 hair gel from Cleveland, OH
Interdependence상호의존 Every day you rely on many people from around the world, most of whom you’ve never met, to provide you with the goods and services you enjoy. 매일 당신은 세계 각지의 수많은 사람들에게 의존한다. 당신이 만나본 적도 없는 그 사람들이 당신에게 재화와 서비스를 제공하고 있다. hair gel from Cleveland, OH cell phone from Taiwan dress shirt from China coffee from Kenya 2

3 Interdependence One of the Ten Principles from Chapter 1: Trade can make everyone better off. We now learn why people – and nations – choose to be interdependent, and how they can gain from trade. 이제 우리는 왜 사람들-나라들-이 상호의존적인 길을 선택하고, 어떻게 교역을 통해 이익을 얻는지를 배울 것이다. INTERDEPENDENCE AND THE GAINS FROM TRADE

4 Our Example Two countries: the U.S. and Japan
Two countries: the U.S. and Japan Two goods: computers and wheat One resource: labor, measured in hours We will look at how much of both goods each country produces and consumes if the country chooses to be self-sufficient if it trades with the other country 자급자족할 때와 서로 무역할 때 두 나라가 컴퓨터와 밀을 얼마나 생산하고 소비하는지를 살펴보자. The lessons illustrated by this international trade example also apply to trade between two individual producers. Note that this chapter in the textbook does the reverse: It develops the lessons in the context of an example involving two individual producers, and then states that the lessons also apply to international trade. So, between this PowerPoint and the textbook chapter, students will see the same concepts and lessons developed in two different but entirely consistent approaches and examples. The example here is highly contrived and unrealistic in order to illustrate complex concepts as simply as possible. The example has some qualities that make it especially valuable: * The two goods are fundamentally different (one is agricultural, the other manufactured), which makes gains from trade based on comparative advantage very likely. An example using more similar goods, say laptop computers and MP3 players, would not be appropriate for this chapter because it would more likely give rise to inter-industry trade, and the gains would likely arise from a source other than comparative advantage (probably increasing returns to scale). * In the example here, it turns out that the U.S. has an absolute advantage in both goods, yet both countries gain from trade. Students see, therefore, that comparative advantage, not absolute advantage, is what’s necessary for trade to be mutually beneficial. * In the real world, one often sees gains from trade based on comparative advantage occurring between countries that are very different – such as between rich industrialized countries and poor developing countries. This example shows that trade based on comparative advantage can also occur between countries that are at similar levels of industrialization and income. (Of course, the U.S. and Japan are very different; but they are far more similar than are, say, the U.S. and Botswana.) INTERDEPENDENCE AND THE GAINS FROM TRADE 4

5 Production Possibilities in the U.S.
The U.S. has 50,000 hours of labor available for production, per month. 미국은 한 달에 50,000시간의 노동을 생산에 사용할 수 있다. Producing one computer requires 100 hours of labor. 컴퓨터 한대는 100시간의 노동을 필요로 하고 Producing one ton of wheat requires 10 hours of labor. 1톤의 밀은 10시간의 노동을 필요로 한다. If you just covered Chapter 2, point out to your students that the U.S. PPF here is the same as in the Chapter 2 PowerPoint. Warn students that, in a few moments, they will be asked to derive Japan’s PPF. They will need to follow the same steps that you are about to show for deriving the U.S. PPF. INTERDEPENDENCE AND THE GAINS FROM TRADE 5

6 The U.S. PPF 4,000 100 5,000 2,000 1,000 3,000 500 200 300 400 Computers Wheat (tons) The U.S. has enough labor to produce 500 computers, or 5000 tons of wheat, or any combination along the PPF. 미국은 500대의 컴퓨터나 5000톤의 밀, 또는 PPF상의 어떤 조합을 생산할 수 있다. Deriving the intercepts, or endpoints of the PPF: The U.S. has 50,000 labor hours. It takes 100 hours to produce a computer. If the U.S. uses all its labor to produce computers, then it will produce 50,000/100 = 500 computers. Hence, the horizontal intercept is (500 computers, 0 wheat). It takes 10 hours to produce a ton of wheat. If the U.S. uses all its labor to produce wheat, then it will produce 50,000/10 = 5000 tons of wheat. Hence, the vertical intercept is (0 computers, 5000 tons of wheat). The PPF is the straight line that connects the two endpoints. INTERDEPENDENCE AND THE GAINS FROM TRADE 6

7 The U.S. Without Trade 4,000 100 5,000 2,000 1,000 3,000 500 200 300 400 Computers Wheat (tons) Suppose the U.S. uses half its labor to produce each of the two goods. Then it will produce and consume 250 computers and 2500 tons of wheat. 노동력을 두 재화에 절반씩 투입한다면 미국은 250대의 컴퓨터와 2500톤의 밀을 생산, 소비할 것 Of course, the U.S. could choose a different point. The actual choice will depend on the preferences of society. (In the following chapter – on supply and demand – we will learn what determines how much of each good society produces.) Important note for students: Without trade, a country consumes what it produces. INTERDEPENDENCE AND THE GAINS FROM TRADE 7

8 A C T I V E L E A R N I N G 1 Derive Japan’s PPF
Use the following information to draw Japan’s PPF. 다음 정보를 활용하여 일본의 PPF를 그려보라 Japan has 30,000 hours of labor available for production, per month. 한 달에 생산에 투입 가능한 30,000시간의 노동을 가짐 Producing one computer requires 125 hours of labor. 컴퓨터 한대 생산에 125시간 필요 Producing one ton of wheat requires 25 hours of labor.밀 1톤 생산에 25시간 필요 Your graph should measure computers on the horizontal axis. 컾퓨터를 횡축에 표시 Using this information to draw Japan’s PPF requires a calculator (or the ability to do long division). If your students have the “gutted handout” of these slides, they can draw their PPF on the axes provided on the following slide. This activity should take only 3 minutes of class time. It’s good practice & review for students, and helps break up the lecture. 8

9 Japan’s PPF Japan has enough labor to produce 240 computers,
Computers Wheat (tons) 2,000 1,000 200 100 300 Japan has enough labor to produce 240 computers, or 1200 tons of wheat, or any combination along the PPF. Horizontal intercept: (30,000 labor-hours)/(125 hours per computer) = 240 computers. Vertical intercept: (30,000 labor-hours)/(25 hours per ton of wheat) = 1200 tons of wheat. INTERDEPENDENCE AND THE GAINS FROM TRADE 9

10 Japan Without Trade Computers Wheat (tons) 2,000 1,000 200 100 300 Suppose Japan uses half its labor to produce each good. Then it will produce and consume 120 computers and 600 tons of wheat. INTERDEPENDENCE AND THE GAINS FROM TRADE 10

11 Consumption With and Without Trade
Without trade, U.S. consumers get 250 computers and 2500 tons wheat. Japanese consumers get 120 computers and 600 tons wheat. We will compare consumption without trade to consumption with trade. First, we need to see how much of each good is produced and traded by the two countries. INTERDEPENDENCE AND THE GAINS FROM TRADE 11

12 A C T I V E L E A R N I N G 2 Production under trade
1. Suppose the U.S. produces 3400 tons of wheat. How many computers would the U.S. be able to produce with its remaining labor? Draw the point representing this combination of computers and wheat on the U.S. PPF. 2. Suppose Japan produces 240 computers. How many tons of wheat would Japan be able to produce with its remaining labor? Draw this point on Japan’s PPF. Give your students a few minutes to solve these problems before showing the answers on the next slides. This will break up the lecture, get the students involved, and give them practice with “word problems.” It is not necessary that all students finish both problems before moving on. It’s fine if most finish the first, and a few finish the second. However, the second problem is easy for most students. Note that most students will need a calculator to solve the first problem. 12

13 U.S. Production With Trade
Computers Wheat (tons) 4,000 100 5,000 2,000 1,000 3,000 500 200 300 400 Producing 3400 tons of wheat requires 34,000 labor hours. The remaining 16,000 labor hours are used to produce 160 computers. Point out to students that the red dot represents the combination (160 computers, 3400 tons of wheat). We will assume that this is the combination the U.S. produces in the scenario in which the U.S. trades. INTERDEPENDENCE AND THE GAINS FROM TRADE 13

14 Japan’s Production With Trade
Computers Wheat (tons) 2,000 1,000 200 100 300 Producing 240 computers requires all of Japan’s 30,000 labor hours. So, Japan would produce 0 tons of wheat. The red dot represents the combination (240 computers, 0 tons wheat). We will assume this is the combination that Japan produces. Point out that, just because Japan is not producing any wheat does not mean that Japan’s consumers must all go on the Atkins diet (which shuns bread and other foods made from wheat). When trade is allowed, Japan can trade some of its computers for wheat produced in another country. INTERDEPENDENCE AND THE GAINS FROM TRADE 14

15 Basic international trade terms
Exports: 수출 goods produced domestically and sold abroad To export means to sell domestically produced goods abroad. Imports: 수입 goods produced abroad and sold domestically To import means to purchase goods produced in other countries. These terms are so basic that many instructors skip this slide. There’s a subtle point that you might want to mention (if you’re anal like me), or that your students might ask about (especially if tourism is an important part of your local economy). Someone from Germany or South Korea visits Las Vegas and spends $200 on a pair of tickets to a show. How should we classify this and other expenditures by foreign tourists on lodging and entertainment while they are vacationing here? Answer: we count it in U.S. exports. It doesn’t matter that the service was consumed here. What matters is that it was produced here but sold to a foreign buyer. Hence, a more precise definition of exports would be goods and serviced produced here and purchased by foreign buyers. This stricter definition of exports doesn’t care whether the good or service was consumed in the buyer’s home country or in the exporting country. Similarly, a stricter and more precise definition of imports would include purchases by domestic residents of goods and services produced abroad – including entertainment and lodging services that tourists from the U.S. consume in the foreign countries they visit. INTERDEPENDENCE AND THE GAINS FROM TRADE 15

16 A C T I V E L E A R N I N G 3 Consumption under trade
Suppose the U.S. exports 700 tons of wheat to Japan, and imports 110 computers from Japan. (So, Japan imports 700 tons wheat and exports 110 computers.) How much of each good is consumed in the U.S.? Plot this combination on the U.S. PPF. How much of each good is consumed in Japan? Plot this combination on Japan’s PPF. Some students need help figuring out that consumption of a good is the difference between the amount produced and the amount exported. 16

17 U.S. Consumption With Trade
Computers Wheat (tons) wheat computers 3400 160 produced 4,000 100 5,000 2,000 1,000 3,000 500 200 300 400 110 + imported 700 – exported 2700 270 = amount consumed The red point again represents production. Trade un-tethers consumption from production. The light blue point represents consumption. Notice that the consumption point is above the PPF. Without trade, it would not be possible to consume this combination of the two goods! In a sense, international trade is like technological progress: it allows society to produce quantities of goods that would otherwise not be possible. INTERDEPENDENCE AND THE GAINS FROM TRADE 17

18 Japan’s Consumption With Trade
wheat computers Computers Wheat (tons) 2,000 1,000 200 100 300 240 produced 700 + imported 110 – exported 700 130 = amount consumed Again, the light blue point representing consumption is above the PPF. Without trade, it would not be possible to consume this combination of the goods. INTERDEPENDENCE AND THE GAINS FROM TRADE 18

19 Trade Makes Both Countries Better Off
U.S. consumption without trade consumption with trade gains from trade 20 270 250 computers 200 2,700 2,500 wheat gains from trade consumption with trade consumption without trade Japan These tables summarize the gains from trade for both countries. 10 130 120 computers 100 700 600 wheat INTERDEPENDENCE AND THE GAINS FROM TRADE 19

20 Where Do These Gains Come From?
Absolute advantage: the ability to produce a good using fewer inputs than another producer 절대우위: 다른 생산자보다 적은 투입으로 재화를 생산할 수 있는 능력 The U.S. has an absolute advantage in wheat: producing a ton of wheat uses 10 labor hours in the U.S. vs. 25 in Japan. 미국은 밀 생산에 절대우위가 있다: 미국은 밀 1톤 생산에 10단위의 노동을 사용(일본은 25단위) If each country has an absolute advantage in one good and specializes in that good, then both countries can gain from trade. 만약 각 나라가 한 재화 씩에 절대우위가 있어 그 재화에 특화한다면 두 나라는 모두 무역으로부터 이익을 얻을 수 있다. The last bullet point states that gains from trade will arise if each country has an absolute advantage in something. We will see next, though, that absolute advantage is not required for both countries to gain from trade. INTERDEPENDENCE AND THE GAINS FROM TRADE 20

21 Where Do These Gains Come From?
Which country has an absolute advantage in computers? 어떤 나라가 컴퓨터에 절대우위를 갖는가? Producing one computer requires labor hours in Japan, but only 100 in the U.S. 일본에서는 컴퓨터 한대 생산에 125노동시간이 필요하지만 미국에서는 100시간만 필요 The U.S. has an absolute advantage in both goods! 미국이 두 재화 모두에 절대우위를 가진다! So why does Japan specialize in computers? Why do both countries gain from trade? 그렇다면 일본은 왜 컴퓨터에 특화하며, 두 나라는 왜 모두 무역으로부터 이익을 얻는가? INTERDEPENDENCE AND THE GAINS FROM TRADE 21

22 Two Measures of the Cost of a Good
Two countries can gain from trade when each specializes in the good it produces at lowest cost. 두 나라는 각기 낮은 가격으로 생산할 수 있는 재화에 특화할 때 무역으로부터 이익을 얻을 수 있다. Absolute advantage measures the cost of a good in terms of the inputs required to produce it. 절대우위는 한 재화를 생산하는 데 필요한 투입요소의 양으로 계산된 그 재화의 비용으로 측정된다. Recall: Another measure of cost is opportunity cost. 또 하나의 비용 척도는 기회비용이다. In our example, the opportunity cost of a computer is the amount of wheat that could be produced using the labor needed to produce one computer. 우리의 예에서 컴퓨터 한 대의 기회비용은 컴퓨터 한대를 생산하는 데 필요한 노동을 사용하여 생산할 수 있는 밀의 양이다. INTERDEPENDENCE AND THE GAINS FROM TRADE 22

23 Opportunity Cost and Comparative Advantage
Comparative advantage: the ability to produce a good at a lower opportunity cost than another producer 비교우위: 다른 생산자보다 낮은 기회비용으로 한 재화를 생산할 수 있는 능력 Which country has the comparative advantage in computers? 컴퓨터에 비교우위를 갖는 나라는 어디? To answer this, must determine the opp. cost of a computer in each country. 이 물음에 답하기 위해서 각 나라에서 컴퓨터 한대의 기회비용이 얼마인지를 판단해야 한다. INTERDEPENDENCE AND THE GAINS FROM TRADE 23

24 Opportunity Cost and Comparative Advantage
The opp. cost of a computer is 컴퓨터 한대의 기회비용은 10 tons of wheat in the U.S., because producing one computer requires 100 labor hours, which instead could produce 10 tons of wheat. 미국에서는 밀 10톤 5 tons of wheat in Japan, because producing one computer requires 125 labor hours, which instead could produce 5 tons of wheat. 일본에서는 밀 5톤 So, Japan has a comparative advantage in computers. 일본이 컴퓨터에 비교우위를 갖는다. Lesson: Absolute advantage is not necessary for comparative advantage! 절대우위는 비교우위의 필요조건이 아니다. INTERDEPENDENCE AND THE GAINS FROM TRADE 24

25 Comparative Advantage and Trade
Gains from trade arise from comparative advantage (differences in opportunity costs). 무역의 이익은 비교우위(기회비용의 차이)에서 발생 When each country specializes in the good(s) in which it has a comparative advantage, total production in all countries is higher, the world’s “economic pie” is bigger, and all countries can gain from trade. 각 나라가 비교우위를 가진 재화에 특화 하면 전체 나라에서의 총 생산은 증가하여 세계의 “경제적 파이”가 커지므로 모든 나라들이 무역으로부터 이익을 얻는다. The same applies to individual producers (like the farmer and the rancher) specializing in different goods and trading with each other. 동일한 사실이 서로 다른 재화에 특화하여 거래하는 개별 생산자들(농부와 목장주) 사이에도 성립한다. INTERDEPENDENCE AND THE GAINS FROM TRADE 25

26 A C T I V E L E A R N I N G 4 Absolute & comparative advantage
Argentina and Brazil each have 10,000 hours of labor per month. In Argentina, producing one pound coffee requires 2 hours producing one bottle wine requires 4 hours In Brazil, producing one pound coffee requires 1 hour producing one bottle wine requires 5 hours Which country has an absolute advantage in the production of coffee? Which country has a comparative advantage in the production of wine? Allow a few minutes for students to work on this problem. Ask for volunteers to share their answers. Variation: Before asking for volunteers, instruct students to compare their answers with their neighbors. Not everyone will volunteer to explain their answer to the class, but everyone will at least get to explain his or her answer to a classmate. 26

27 A C T I V E L E A R N I N G 4 Answers
Brazil has an absolute advantage in coffee: Producing a pound of coffee requires only one labor-hour in Brazil, but two in Argentina. Argentina has a comparative advantage in wine: Argentina’s opp. cost of wine is two pounds of coffee, because the four labor-hours required to produce a bottle of wine could instead produce two pounds of coffee. Brazil’s opp. cost of wine is five pounds of coffee. 27

28 Unanswered Questions….
We made a lot of assumptions about the quantities of each good that each country produces, trades, and consumes, and the price at which the countries trade wheat for computers. In the real world, these quantities and prices would be determined by the preferences of consumers and the technology and resources in both countries. We will begin to study this in the next chapter. For now, though, our goal was merely to see how trade can make everyone better off. The 5th edition adds a brief explanation of the range of prices that will permit gains from trade, in the context of the farmer-rancher example. The second bullet point mentions technology and resources. In our example, the technology is how many labor-hours are required to produce each good. The resources are simply the quantity of labor-hours available in each country. In the following chapter (on supply & demand), students will begin their study of how prices and quantities are determined. INTERDEPENDENCE AND THE GAINS FROM TRADE 28

29 CHAPTER SUMMARY Interdependence and trade allow everyone to enjoy a greater quantity and variety of goods & services. Comparative advantage means being able to produce a good at a lower opportunity cost. Absolute advantage means being able to produce a good with fewer inputs. When people – or countries – specialize in the goods in which they have a comparative advantage, the economic “pie” grows and trade can make everyone better off. 29


Download ppt "In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:"

Similar presentations


Ads by Google